Loren Data Corporation v. GXS Incorporated
Filing
UNPUBLISHED AUTHORED OPINION filed. Originating case number: 8:10-cv-03474-DKC. Copies to all parties and the district court/agency. [999010012].. [11-2062]
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
Filed: 12/26/2012
Pg: 1 of 26
UNPUBLISHED
UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
FOR THE FOURTH CIRCUIT
No. 11-2062
LOREN DATA CORPORATION,
Plaintiff - Appellant,
v.
GXS, INC.,
Defendant - Appellee.
Appeal from the United States District Court for the District of
Maryland, at Greenbelt.
Deborah K. Chasanow, Chief District
Judge. (8:10-cv-03474-DKC)
Argued:
September 20, 2012
Decided:
December 26, 2012
Before NIEMEYER and KEENAN, Circuit Judges, and Michael F.
URBANSKI, United States District Judge for the Western District
of Virginia, sitting by designation.
Affirmed by unpublished opinion. Judge Urbanski wrote
opinion, in which Judge Niemeyer and Judge Keenan joined.
the
ARGUED: Glenn B. Manishin, TROUTMAN SANDERS, LLP, Washington,
D.C., for Appellant.
Robert A. Schwinger, CHADBOURNE & PARKE,
LLP, New York, New York, for Appellee.
ON BRIEF: David H.
Evans, CHADBOURNE & PARKE, LLP, Washington, D.C.; Benjamin D.
Bleiberg, CHADBOURNE & PARKE, LLP, New York, New York, for
Appellee.
Unpublished opinions are not binding precedent in this circuit.
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
Filed: 12/26/2012
Pg: 2 of 26
URBANSKI, District Judge:
Loren
complaint
Data
against
GXS,
Corporation
Inc.
(“Loren
(“GXS”)
Data”)
alleging
filed
a
violations
of
Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Antitrust Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1,
2, the Maryland antitrust statute, as well as common law claims
of tortious interference and breach of contract.
The district
court granted GXS’s motion to dismiss Loren Data’s antitrust
claims.
Because the district court correctly recognized that
Loren Data failed to allege a plausible conspiracy in restraint
of trade in violation of Section 1 of the Sherman Act or facts
sufficient to state a plausible Section 2 claim, we affirm.
I.
Loren Data and GXS are engaged in the Electronic Data
Interchange industry.
Electronic Data Interchange (“EDI”) is
the transfer and exchange of business data from one computer
system to another using a standard digital format.
EDI messages
are generated, sent, and received by business computing systems
for parties engaged in commercial trading, and often include the
transmission
of
purchase orders.
business
information
such
as
invoices
and
EDI messages travel over secure, private data
networks called Value Added Networks (“Networks”).
Loren Data operate such Networks.
Both GXS and
Loren Data alleges that the
GXS Network is the market leader, and this case concerns GXS’s
2
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
Filed: 12/26/2012
Pg: 3 of 26
refusal to allow Loren Data to connect to the GXS Network in the
manner sought by Loren Data.
Networks
referred
to
interconnect
transfer
in
the
(“peer
business
industry
information
as
interconnect”)
and
a
two
ways,
non-settlement
a
in
peer
commercial
mailbox.
When data is transmitted over a peer interconnect, each Network
bears its own costs associated with the transfer of data, and
neither Network charges the other for the data transmission.
In
contrast, Networks communicating via a commercial mailbox charge
each other based on the volume of data transferred.
Loren Data
alleges that a peer interconnect is the industry standard and
that
a
commercial
expensive.
mailbox
is
cumbersome,
inefficient,
and
While Loren Data has had access to the GXS Network
by means of a commercial mailbox, it charges a violation of the
antitrust
laws
because
GXS
has
refused
to
grant
it
a
peer
interconnect.
Loren
Data’s
efforts
to
from GXS span the last decade.
obtain
a
peer
interconnect
The amended complaint alleges
that Loren Data began negotiations with GXS to secure a peer
interconnect
in
November
2000.
While
negotiations
were
underway, GXS made a commercial mailbox available to Loren Data
as an interim solution.
In August 2001, GXS declined Loren
Data’s request for a peer interconnect and notified Loren Data
that it would terminate the commercial mailbox if $30,000.00 in
3
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
Filed: 12/26/2012
Pg: 4 of 26
overdue fees owed by Loren Data were not paid.
did
not
pay
mailbox.
the
overdue
fees,
GXS
terminated
When Loren Data
the
commercial
Loren Data approached GXS again in 2002 to establish a
peer interconnect, but that request too was denied.
In August 2003, Loren Data again approached GXS about
a peer interconnect, this time because a potential customer,
Covisint, required routing to commercial trading partners on the
GXS Network.
Although Loren Data had, by this time, settled its
outstanding accounts with GXS, GXS declined to provide a peer
interconnect, again offering a commercial mailbox.
fact
that
Loren
Data
could
only
offer
Covisint
Despite the
a
commercial
mailbox connection to the GXS Network, Covisint contracted with
Loren Data. 1
Matters came to a head in 2010.
In a letter dated
September 3, 2010, GXS addressed the terms under which it was
willing to do business with Loren Data.
1
This letter, attached
While the commercial mailbox relationship between Loren
Data and GXS has been the norm over the last decade, there have
been exceptions.
From 2005 to 2009, GXS allowed Loren Data a
peer interconnect for traffic pursuant to an outsourcing
contract between Loren Data and IBM. In 2009, Loren Data signed
a transit agreement with Inovis, Inc. which gave Loren Data
indirect access to the GXS Network through the InovisWorks
Network.
Loren Data alleges that GXS indicated that it would
not renew or extend the InovisWorks transit agreement upon its
expiration in May 2011.
4
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
Filed: 12/26/2012
Pg: 5 of 26
as an exhibit to the amended complaint, forms the core of Loren
Data’s Sherman Act Section 1 conspiracy allegation.
In the September 3, 2010 letter, GXS explained that it
could
not
offer
Loren
Data
anything
more
than
a
commercial
mailbox because it believed Loren Data’s business model to be
incompatible
with
its
own.
GXS
characterized
business model as a “service bureau.”
Loren
Data’s
As a “service bureau,”
GXS asserted that Loren Data was focused exclusively on selling
a connection to the GXS Network and did not provide the value
associated with other Networks, which GXS contended are focused
on growing the overall EDI market.
GXS
interconnect
problems.
model
also
to
expressed
Loren
Data
concern
would
that
result
providing
in
service
a
peer
quality
GXS stated that the core of Loren Data’s business
involves
message
“daisy
chaining.”
GXS
distinguished
daisy chaining from the “one-hop” approach employed by GXS in
which “messages traverse one network and stop.”
In contrast,
daisy chaining allows a message to hop from Network to Network.
According to GXS, “[a] proliferation of daisy chaining increases
GXS[’s]
risks
in
its
ability
to
manage
availability, and overall service quality.”
2010
letter
stated
that
GXS’s
current
latency,
The September 3,
Network
agreements expressly prohibit daisy chaining.
5
service
interconnect
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
Filed: 12/26/2012
Pg: 6 of 26
The amended complaint alleges that both GXS and Loren
Data have peer interconnect agreements with all of the 36 other
EDI
Networks.
interconnect
Regardless,
access
to
the
Loren
Data
alleges
GXS
Network
is
that
peer
essential
to
competition because that Network controls over 50 percent of the
market.
Although
Loren
Data
alleges
a
concerted
refusal
to
deal, the amended complaint states that “[c]urrently about 55%
of Loren Data’s business travels on GXS [Networks].”
II.
Loren
Data
filed
a
complaint
on
December
13,
2010
alleging that GXS’s refusal to provide it a peer interconnect to
the GXS Network violated Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act,
the Maryland antitrust statute, and the common law.
GXS moved
to
of
dismiss
the
complaint
Procedure 12(b)(6).
pursuant
to
Federal
Rule
Civil
In response to GXS’s motion to dismiss,
Loren Data filed an amended complaint, which incorporated the
original complaint, introduced supplemental facts, and attached
the September 3, 2010 letter, which it believed evidenced the
agreement to restrain trade.
On August 9, 2011, the district court dismissed the
action.
The district court reasoned that Loren Data failed to
allege specific facts in support of a Section 1 conspiracy, and,
in fact, the facts alleged suggest the absence of an agreement
6
Appeal: 11-2062
in
Doc: 39
restraint
Filed: 12/26/2012
of
trade.
As
Pg: 7 of 26
to
the
Section
2
monopolization
claim, the district court held that Loren Data did not properly
allege
a
alleged
plausible
refusal
conduct.
The
essential
to
deal
district
facilities
constituted
court
also
claim
or
unlawful
held
that
the
exclusionary
that
Loren
Data’s
attempted monopolization claim did not sufficiently allege the
specific
intent
to
monopolize
or
a
dangerous
probability
of
successful monopolization.
Loren Data filed two post-judgment motions that the
district court construed as motions to alter judgment pursuant
to Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 59(e).
Loren
Data
sought
clarification
as
to
In those motions,
whether
the
case
was
dismissed with or without prejudice and reconsideration of the
dismissal.
The court denied the motions and ordered that the
case be dismissed with prejudice.
This appeal followed. 2
III.
An
order
reviewed de novo.
granting
dismissal
under
Rule
12(b)(6)
is
See E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co. v. Kolon
2
Loren Data did not appeal the district court’s rulings as
to its Maryland common law claims and those portions of its
Maryland antitrust claims that do not parallel its Sherman Act
claims.
As such, these claims are not addressed herein.
Likewise, there is no need to undertake separate analysis of the
parallel Maryland antitrust claims, as resolution of those
claims is subsumed in the Sherman Act analysis.
7
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
Filed: 12/26/2012
Pg: 8 of 26
Indus., 637 F.3d 435, 440 (4th Cir. 2011).
The Supreme Court
in
U.S.
Bell
Atlantic
Corp.
v.
Twombly,
550
544
(2007),
articulated a two-pronged approach to assessing the sufficiency
Ashcroft v. Iqbal, 556 U.S. 662, 679 (2009).
of a complaint.
First, the complaint must allege facts sufficient to support the
legal conclusions in the complaint, as Federal Rule of Civil
Procedure 8 requires “more than labels and conclusions,” and
admonishes against “a formulaic recitation of the elements of a
Twombly, 550 U.S. at 555.
cause.”
Second, “[t]o survive a
motion to dismiss, a complaint must contain sufficient factual
matter, accepted as true, to ‘state a claim to relief that is
plausible
on
its
Iqbal,
face.’”
(quoting Twombly, 550 U.S. at 557).
556
U.S.
at
678
Plausibility requires that
the factual allegations “be enough to raise a right to relief
above the speculative level . . . on the assumption that all the
allegations in the complaint are true.”
Twombly, 550 U.S. at
555; see, e.g., Robertson v. Sea Pines Real Estate Companies,
Inc., 679 F.3d 278, 288 (4th Cir. 2012).
In
trade,
the
Twombly
context
teaches
that
of
an
a
court
conclusory allegations of conspiracy.
the
court
conclusory
must
factual
determine
whether
allegations
suggestion of conspiracy.”
give
agreement
may
not
restrain
simply
550 U.S. at 555.
the
credit
Rather,
well-pleaded,
rise
Id. at 565-66.
8
to
to
a
non-
“plausible
As the district
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
Filed: 12/26/2012
Pg: 9 of 26
court correctly concluded, the factual allegations in this case
fail to reach that level.
IV.
A.
Count I of Loren Data's amended complaint alleges a
violation of Section 1 of the Sherman Act.
Section 1 of the
Sherman Act states that: “Every contract, combination in the
form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade
or commerce among the several states, or with foreign nations,
is declared to be illegal.”
Section
1
violation,
a
15 U.S.C. § 1.
plaintiff
must
To establish a
prove,
and
therefore
plead, “(1) a contract, combination, or conspiracy; (2) that
imposed
an
unreasonable
restraint
of
Dickson
trade.”
v.
Microsoft Corp., 309 F.3d 193, 202 (4th Cir. 2002).
“Not every instance of cooperation between two people
is a potential ‘contract, combination . . . or conspiracy, in
restraint
League,
of
130
trade.’”
S. Ct.
2201,
Am.
Needle,
2208
Inc.
(2010).
v.
The
Nat’l
term
Football
“contract,
combination . . . or conspiracy” in Section 1 applies only to
concerted
action,
and
not
unilateral
activity.
Id.
(citing Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 467 U.S.
752, 761 (1984)).
The Sherman Act proscribes concerted action
because it is “fraught with anticompetitive risk” and “deprives
9
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
Filed: 12/26/2012
Pg: 10 of 26
the marketplace of the independent centers of decision-making
that competition assumes and demands.”
Robertson, 679 F.3d at
284
The
(internal
citations
omitted).
purpose
of
the
distinction “between concerted and independent action [is] to
deter
anticompetitive
conduct
and
compensate
its
victims,
without chilling vigorous competition through ordinary business
Id.
operations.”
More particularly, concerted activity is prohibited by
Section 1 when “multiple parties join their resources, rights,
and economic power together in order to achieve an outcome that,
but
for
concert,
would
naturally
be
frustrated
by
competing interests (by way of profit maximizing choices).”
their
Va.
Vermiculite, Ltd. v. Historic Green Springs, Inc., 307 F.3d 277,
282 (4th Cir. 2002).
Thus, Section 1 does not include “the
entire body of private contract,” and a business generally has
“the right to deal or not deal with whomever it likes, as long
Laurel Sand & Gravel, Inc. v. CSX
as it does so independently.”
Transp., Inc., 924 F.2d 539, 542 (4th Cir. 1991).
To
adequately
plead
a
Section
1
conspiracy,
the
complaint must allege a factual basis plausibly suggesting that
concerted
trade.
activity
See
Twombly,
led
550
to
an
U.S.
at
agreement
556.
to
restrain
Specifically,
when
concerted conduct is a matter of inference, a plaintiff must
include evidence that places the parallel conduct in “context
10
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
Filed: 12/26/2012
Pg: 11 of 26
that raises a suggestion of a preceding agreement” as “distinct
from
identical,
independent
action.”
Id.
at
549,
556; see also Robertson, 679 F.3d at 289.
“Conspiracies
effort
to
escape
circumstantial
place.”
evidence
of
in
often
detection,
evidence
Robertson,
allegations
are
this
to
679
case
conspiracy.
tacit
thus
that
at
an
of
Loren
in
an
resort
to
agreement
289-90.
suggestive
Rather,
unwritten
necessitating
suggest
F.3d
or
There
such
Data
are
took
no
circumstantial
relies
on
the
reference in the September 3, 2010 letter to the prohibition on
daisy chaining in the GXS Network interconnect agreements to
meet Section 1’s concerted action requirement.
the
daisy
chaining
ban
contained
in
the
Loren Data reads
GXS
interconnect
agreements as evidence of collusion between GXS and each of the
other 36 Networks to boycott Loren Data.
Merely pleading or pointing to an express contract is
not enough to show that an actual conspiracy to restrain trade
is afoot, however.
A reviewing court must “take account of the
absence of a plausible motive to enter into the alleged . . .
conspiracy.”
Matsushita Electric Indus. Co., Ltd. v. Zenith
Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 595 (1986).
“[C]ourts should not
permit factfinders to infer conspiracies when such inferences
are implausible, because the effect of such practices is often
to deter procompetitive conduct.”
11
Id. at 593 (citing Monsanto
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
Filed: 12/26/2012
Pg: 12 of 26
Co. v. Spray-Rite Service Corp., 465 U.S. 752, 762-64 (1984).
If the alleged co-conspirators “had no rational economic motive
to
conspire,
and
if
their
conduct
is
consistent
with
other,
equally plausible explanations, the conduct does not give rise
to an inference of conspiracy.”
Matsushita, 475 U.S. at 596-97
(citing First Nat’l Bank of Ariz. v. Cities Serv. Co., 391 U.S.
253,
278-80
(1968).
possibility
that
The
the
evidence
must
alleged
tend
to
exclude
co-conspirators
the
acted
independently, and the alleged conspiracy must make practical,
economic
sense.
Matsushita,
475
U.S.
at
597-98
(citing Monsanto, 465 U.S. at 764).
Here, the allegations do not meet this standard.
The
September 3, 2010 letter does not provide any indication that
other
Networks
have
acquiesced
or
joined
in
any
kind
of
conspiracy to boycott Loren Data, much less taken any action
against Loren Data.
The letter merely suggests that GXS was
unwilling to contract with Loren Data on the terms it sought and
provides no evidence that others agreed to boycott Loren Data.
Indeed, it is difficult, if not impossible, to reconcile Loren
Data’s allegation that the September 3, 2010 letter is direct
evidence
of
a
conspiracy
against
Loren
examination of the terms of that letter.
entirety,
the
business
model
letter
raises
explains
that
service
Loren
quality
12
Data
with
a
full
When read in its
Data’s
concerns
daisy
for
chain
the
GXS
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
Network.
Filed: 12/26/2012
Pg: 13 of 26
To address the service quality problems posed by daisy
chaining, GXS proposed a new commercial relationship with Loren
Data.
As
such,
the
September
3,
2010
letter
is
hardly
suggestive of an unlawful conspiracy or an agreement to boycott
Loren Data.
Rather, it simply explains the terms on which GXS
was willing to contract with Loren Data.
Moreover, as the district court recognized, the facts
alleged by Loren Data contradict any inference of conspiracy.
Loren Data simultaneously alleges: (1) that GXS contracted with
all other Networks to exclude Loren Data from obtaining a peer
interconnect with GXS; yet (2) Loren Data was able to obtain
peer
interconnects
Networks.
with
all
of
these
allegedly
boycotting
The fact that Loren Data was able to interconnect
with all of these other Networks negates any suggestion that
these Networks conspired with GXS to boycott Loren Data.
These
facts do not support an allegation of a Section 1 conspiracy;
rather, they are consistent with unilateral conduct by GXS to
protect its Network from the service quality perils it perceived
to be associated with daisy chaining.
Given
the
fact
that
Loren
Data
was
able
to
interconnect freely with so many other Networks, the letter of
September
3,
2010
concerted action.
cannot
plausibly
be
read
as
evidence
of
Rather, it reflects GXS’s unilateral business
judgment as to the parameters under which it was willing to deal
13
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
Filed: 12/26/2012
Pg: 14 of 26
with Loren Data, an entity it viewed as having an incompatible
business model.
Monsanto, 465 U.S. at 761 (“A manufacturer of
course generally has a right to deal, or refuse to deal, with
whomever it likes, as long as it does so independently . . . .
And a distributor is free to acquiesce in the manufacturer's
demand
in
alleged
order
in
the
to
avoid
amended
termination.”).
complaint,
the
Given
conspiracy
the
facts
posited
Loren Data simply makes no practical or economic sense.
by
As
such, the district court correctly concluded that the Sherman
Act Section 1 claim fails as a matter of law.
V.
Counts II and III of Loren Data’s amended complaint
allege violations of Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C.
§ 2,
which
monopolize,
make
or
it
illegal
combine
or
to
“monopolize,
conspire
with
any
or
other
attempt
to
person
or
persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among
the
several
States,
or
with
foreign
nations.”
Loren
Data
challenges the district court’s decision to dismiss both its
monopolization and attempted monopolization claims.
A.
To
state
a
monopolization
claim
under
Section
2,
two
elements must be demonstrated: (1) the possession of monopoly
14
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
Filed: 12/26/2012
Pg: 15 of 26
power in the relevant market 3 and (2) the willful acquisition or
maintenance
of
that
power
as
distinguished
from
growth
or
development as a consequence of a superior product, business
acumen, or historic accident.
384
U.S.
Offices
563,
570-571
of
Curtis
(“Trinko”).
The
V.
United States v. Grinnell Corp.,
(1966);
Trinko,
Supreme
Verizon
LLP,
Court
540
in
Commc’ns
U.S.
Trinko
Inc.
398,
407
noted
v.
Law
(2004)
that
the
possession of monopoly power is only unlawful when it is coupled
with anticompetitive conduct.
540 U.S. at 407.
To violate
Section 2 of the Sherman Act, a defendant must engage in conduct
“to foreclose competition, gain a competitive advantage, or to
destroy a competitor.”
E.I. DuPont de Nemours, 637 F.3d at 450
(citing Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., Inc., 504
U.S.
451,
482-83
(1992)).
The
3
anticompetitive
conduct
Monopoly power is defined as “the power to control prices
or exclude competition.”
United States v. E.I. du Pont de
Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 391 (1956).
“Proof of a relevant
market is the threshold for a Sherman Act § 2 claim.
The
plaintiff must establish the geographic and product market that
was monopolized.” Consul, Ltd. v. Transco Energy Co., 805 F.2d
490, 493 (4th Cir. 1986). The district court questioned whether
Loren Data’s “inconclusive statements as to geographic market
are adequate to state a claim,” Loren Data Corp. v. GXS, Inc.,
No. DKC 10-3474, 2011 WL 3511003, at *6 (D. Md. Aug. 9, 2011),
but noted that it need not reach that issue “because Loren
Data’s claim has other failings.”
Id. at *7.
As to the
relevant product market alleged by Loren Data, the EDI industry,
the district court concluded that “it cannot be said that Loren
Data has failed to plead a relevant product market in terms
sufficient to state a claim.” Id.
15
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
Filed: 12/26/2012
Pg: 16 of 26
requirement reflects the essence of an antitrust violation, that
of
harm
to
competitor.
Commc’ns,
competition,
rather
than
to
an
individual
Spanish Broad. Sys. of Fla., Inc. v. Clear Channel
Inc.,
376
F.3d
1065,
1075
(11th
Cir.
2004).
The
Supreme Court has explained that “[e]ven an act of pure malice
by one business competitor against another does not, without
Brooke
more, state a claim under the federal antitrust laws.”
Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209,
225 (1993).
is
“The [Act] directs itself not against conduct which
competitive,
even
severely
so,
but
against
unfairly tends to destroy competition itself.”
Inc. v. McQuillan, 506 U.S. 447, 458 (1993).
conduct
Spectrum Sports
“That is, it must
harm the competitive process and thereby harm consumers.
to
one
or
more
which
competitors
will
In
contrast,
harm
not
suffice.”
United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 70-71
(D.C. Cir. 2001) (en banc) (emphasis in original).
Loren Data alleges that GXS’s anticompetitive behavior
is evidenced by its refusal to provide it a peer interconnect
and this refusal is a denial of access to an essential facility.
i.
The Sherman Act “does not restrict the long recognized
right
of
private
[a]
trader
business,
or
freely
manufacturer
to
engaged
exercise
16
his
in
own
an
entirely
independent
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
Filed: 12/26/2012
Pg: 17 of 26
discretion as to parties with whom he will deal.”
United States
v.
Nevertheless,
Colgate
&
Co.,
250
U.S.
300,
307
(1919).
“[t]he high value that we have placed on the right to refuse to
deal
with
other
unqualified.”
firms
does
not
mean
that
the
right
is
Trinko, 540 U.S. at 408 (citing Aspen Skiing Co.
v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 U.S. 585, 601 (1985)).
In Trinko, the Court observed that exceptions to the
right to refuse to deal should be recognized with caution due to
the “uncertain virtue of forced sharing and the difficulty of
indentifying and remedying anticompetitive conduct by a single
Id.
firm.”
Specifically, the Court noted that Aspen Skiing
represented an exception to this rule and is situated “at or
near the outer boundary of § 2 liability.”
Id.
The Aspen
Skiing exception applies when “[t]he unilateral termination of a
voluntary
(and
thus
presumably
profitable)
course
of
dealing
suggested a willingness to forsake short-term profits to achieve
an anticompetitive end.”
Id.
Loren Data’s attempt to analogize this case to Aspen
Skiing is unpersuasive.
Data.
GXS has not refused to deal with Loren
Indeed, in the September 3, 2010 letter, GXS proposed
terms for a commercial relationship with Loren Data.
There is
no suggestion, and the amended complaint does not allege, that
this offer of a new commercial agreement was some sort of sham
17
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
Filed: 12/26/2012
Pg: 18 of 26
or that GXS would renege on its proposal; rather, Loren Data was
not satisfied with its terms.
Loren
Data
counters
that
a
commercial
mailbox
arrangement is not a viable alternative to a peer interconnect.
But simply because GXS does not offer Loren Data the terms and
conditions it desires does not mean that GXS has violated the
antitrust
laws.
Indeed,
GXS
provides
legitimate
justifications for the terms it offers Loren Data.
Sand
&
Gravel,
924
F.2d
at
544
(noting
that
business
Cf. Laurel
anticompetitive
exclusionary conduct may be shown if “there was no legitimate
business reason for its conduct.”).
its
September
3,
2010
letter,
Plainly, as GXS explains in
there
are
ample
business
justifications for its decision not to deal with Loren Data on
the terms Loren Data wants.
Nor does the alleged failure of GXS to contract with
Loren Data on those terms work to deprive the market of vigorous
competition.
Network,
large
GXS
granted
peer
or
small,
and
interconnects
the
district
to
every
court
other
correctly
concluded that “GXS is not likely to gain monopoly control over
the industry if it refuses to deal with only one of 36 available
VAN networks.”
Loren Data Corp., 2011 WL 3511003, at *11.
Not
only does GXS interconnect with the 36 other Networks, Loren
Data was able to do so as well.
was
not
able
to
obtain
a
Further, even though Loren Data
peer
18
interconnect
with
GXS,
its
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
allegations
traveled
Filed: 12/26/2012
acknowledge
on
the
GXS
that
Pg: 19 of 26
more
than
Network.
half
Simply
of
put,
its
Loren
business
Data’s
allegations that it is able to access 36 other Networks and that
more than half of its business traversed the GXS Network negates
any plausible inference of anticompetitive exclusionary conduct
by GXS.
Loren Data argues that smaller EDI consumers are harmed
by GXS’s exclusionary conduct because accessing the GXS Network
through
another
Network
is
more
expensive.
But
Loren
Data
offers no facts to support its conclusory assertion that smaller
EDI consumers have been denied access or are otherwise unable to
obtain EDI services because of cost.
In short, Loren Data has
failed
of
to
allege
a
plausible
claim
exclusionary
conduct
directed to competition as a whole.
ii.
Loren Data also alleges that the GXS Network is an
essential
facility,
Section 2.
the
denial
of
access
to
which
violates
The Supreme Court has not adopted the essential
facilities doctrine.
Trinko, 540 U.S. at 411 (“We have never
recognized such a doctrine . . . and we find no need either to
recognize
it
or
repudiate
it
here.”).
Nevertheless,
considered such a claim in Laurel Sand & Gravel.
544.
19
we
924 F.2d at
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
Filed: 12/26/2012
Pg: 20 of 26
Under such a theory, a refusal by a monopolist to deal
“may be unlawful because a monopolist’s control of an essential
facility (sometimes called a ‘bottleneck’) can extend monopoly
power from one stage of production to another, and from one
market into another.
Thus, the antitrust laws have imposed on
firms controlling an essential facility the obligation to make
the
facility
available
on
non-discriminatory
MCI
terms.”
Commc’ns Corp. v. Am. Tel. & Tel. Co., 708 F.2d 1081, 1132 (7th
Cir.),
cert.
denied,
464
U.S.
891
(1983).
“[T]he
central
concern in an essential facilities claim is whether market power
in one market is being used to create or further a monopoly in
Advanced Health-Care Servs., Inc. v. Radford
another market.”
Cmty. Hosp., 910 F.2d 139, 150 (4th Cir. 1990).
In order to proceed on an essential facilities claim,
four elements must be proven: “(1) control by the monopolist of
the
essential
seeking
access
facility;
to
(2)
the
practically
inability
or
of
the
reasonably
competitor
duplicate
the
facility; (3) the denial of the facility to the competitor; and
(4)
the
facility.”
feasibility
of
the
monopolist
to
provide
the
Laurel Sand & Gravel, 924 F.2d at 544 (citing MCI
Commc’ns Corp., 708 F.2d at 1132).
The owner of an essential
facility is not obligated to make it available under whatever
terms the competitor wishes; the owner need only offer access
under
reasonable
terms.
Id.
20
Moreover,
terms
are
not
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
unreasonable
profits.
Filed: 12/26/2012
simply
because
Pg: 21 of 26
they
will
reduce
a
competitor's
Id.
The
amended
complaint
does
that GXS is an essential facility.
plausibly
essential.
maintain
that
Although
a
peer
Loren
not
sufficiently
allege
First, Loren Data cannot
interconnect
Data
complains
with
that
GXS
GXS
is
has
repeatedly denied it a peer interconnect, it alleges that more
than half of its EDI business travels over the GXS Network.
Moreover,
Loren
Data
has
established
peer
interconnects
with
three dozen other Networks.
The fact that the majority of Loren
Data’s
the
business
traversed
GXS
Network
without
a
peer
interconnect demonstrates the fallacy of the claim that a peer
interconnect is essential to competition.
Second, there is no
indication that the new commercial agreement offered to Loren
Data by GXS in the September 3, 2010 letter is an unreasonable
alternative to the terms Loren Data seeks.
Loren Data’s history
with Covisint further illustrates this point.
Covisint required
Loren Data to have access to the GXS Network as part of its
prospective contract agreement.
Even though Loren Data was able
to connect to the GXS Network only through a commercial mailbox,
Covisint still decided to contract with Loren Data.
While a
peer interconnect with GXS may suit Loren Data better, it is
plainly not essential.
21
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
Filed: 12/26/2012
Pg: 22 of 26
At its core, Loren Data’s amended complaint does not
plausibly allege the denial of access to an essential facility.
Loren Data has functioned for a decade without unfettered peer
interconnect
essential.
access
to
the
GXS
Network
it
now
claims
is
Even were access to the GXS Network essential for
Loren Data to compete, GXS offered Loren Data access to its
Network on terms acceptable to GXS as set forth in the September
3, 2010 letter.
For both of these reasons, this case does not
present a plausible essential facilities claim.
B.
Loren Data also argues that the district court erred
in dismissing its attempted monopolization claim.
claim
for
attempted
monopolization,
a
To state a
plaintiff
must
demonstrate: (1) a specific intent to monopolize the relevant
market; (2) predatory or anticompetitive acts in furtherance of
the
intent;
success.
and
(3)
a
dangerous
probability
Spectrum Sports, Inc., 506 U.S. at 456.
of
The district
court held that Loren Data failed to allege facts demonstrating
a specific intent to monopolize or a dangerous probability that
GXS would succeed in establishing a monopoly.
We agree.
Loren Data has not sufficiently alleged that GXS had a
specific intent to monopolize.
Indeed, Loren Data alleges just
the opposite - that GXS grants peer interconnects to every other
22
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
Filed: 12/26/2012
Pg: 23 of 26
Network, both large and small – which is entirely inconsistent
with an intent to monopolize.
dangerous
probability
of
Nor does Loren Data allege a
successful
monopolization
by
GXS.
Loren Data characterizes two acquisitions by GXS over a ten year
period
as
an
aggressive
campaign
to
monopolize.
Loren
Data
cites M & M Medical Supplies & Service, Inc. v. Pleasant Valley
Hospital,
Inc.,
981
F.2d
160,
168
(4th
Cir.
1992),
for
the
proposition that a rising market share is sufficient to show a
dangerous
in
M
&
probability
M
Medical,
of
we
achieving
held
monopoly
that
“[o]ther
power.
factors
However,
must
be
considered, such as ease of entry, which heralds slight chance
of
success
[of
achieving
monopoly
power],
or
exclusionary
conduct without the justification of efficiency, which enhances
the likelihood of success [of achieving monopoly power].”
Id.
Loren Data’s complaint and amended complaint are devoid of any
factual allegation suggesting that GXS’s rising market share was
coupled with any exclusionary conduct.
Data’s
theory
is
its
allegation
that
Inconsistent with Loren
GXS
established
peer
interconnects with 36 other Networks, conduct which is hardly
suggestive of an attempt to monopolize the EDI market.
In sum,
the fact that GXS has contracted with every other Network in the
market suggests that its refusal to deal with Loren Data on the
terms Loren Data desires will not have any negative effects on
competition as a whole.
23
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
Filed: 12/26/2012
Pg: 24 of 26
VI.
Finally,
Loren
Data
argues
that
the
erred in denying its post-judgment motions.
district
court
Loren Data filed a
“motion for clarification” asking the district court to issue a
revised or supplemental order stating whether its claims were
dismissed with or without prejudice.
Before this motion was
ruled on, Loren Data filed another motion asking the district
court to reconsider its order granting GXS’s motion to dismiss.
The district court construed both of these motions as motions to
alter
judgment
pursuant
to
Federal
Rule
of
Civil
Procedure
59(e).
The reconsideration of a judgment after its entry is
an extraordinary remedy which should be used sparingly.
Pac.
Ins. Co. v. Am. Nat’l Ins. Co., 148 F.3d 396 (4th Cir. 1998).
We
review
the
denial
of
a
Rule
59(e)
deferential abuse of discretion standard.
motion
under
the
Ingle ex rel. Estate
of Ingle v. Yelton, 439 F.3d 191, 197 (4th Cir. 2006).
Rule
59(e) provides that a court may alter or amend the judgment if
the movant shows (1) an intervening change in the controlling
law,
(2)
new
evidence
that
was
not
available
at
trial,
or
(3) that there has been a clear error of law or a manifest
injustice.
Id.; see e.g., Robinson v. Wix Filtration Corp. LLC,
599 F.3d 403 (4th Cir. 2010).
It is the moving party’s burden
24
Appeal: 11-2062
to
Doc: 39
establish
Filed: 12/26/2012
one
of
these
Pg: 25 of 26
three
grounds
in
order
to
obtain
relief under Rule 59(e).
The district court did not abuse its discretion in
denying Loren Data’s motions.
As there was no suggestion of a
change in intervening law or new facts, Loren Data was left to
argue that a clear error of law or manifest injustice occurred.
As the foregoing analysis of Loren Data’s claims makes plain,
the dismissal of Loren Data’s antitrust claims was neither.
Nor
was it a clear error of law for the district court to dismiss
the
case
without
first
making
a
specific
finding
that
an
additional opportunity to amend the complaint would be futile.
In ruling on the post-judgment motions, the district court made
it abundantly clear that any amendment to the complaint would be
futile for two reasons.
the
complaint
would
be
once
futile.
First, Loren Data had already amended
before,
Second,
suggesting
Loren
that
Data
further
provided
amendment
nothing
of
additional substance to the district court to demonstrate that a
dismissal without prejudice would be fruitful.
Plainly, the
district court did not abuse its discretion in denying Loren
Data’s post-judgment motions.
25
Appeal: 11-2062
Doc: 39
Filed: 12/26/2012
Pg: 26 of 26
VII.
For these reasons, the judgment of the district court
is affirmed.
AFFIRMED
26
Disclaimer: Justia Dockets & Filings provides public litigation records from the federal appellate and district courts. These filings and docket sheets should not be considered findings of fact or liability, nor do they necessarily reflect the view of Justia.
Why Is My Information Online?