Robert Sarvis v. Charles Judd

Filing

PUBLISHED AUTHORED OPINION filed. Originating case number: 3:14-cv-00479-REP. [999858939]. [15-1162]

Download PDF
Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 Pg: 1 of 27 PUBLISHED UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE FOURTH CIRCUIT No. 15-1162 LIBERTARIAN PARTY OF VIRGINIA; WILLIAM HAMMER; JEFFREY CARSON; JAMES CARR; MARC HARROLD; WILLIAM REDPATH; WILLIAM CARR; BO CONRAD BROWN; PAUL F. JONES, Plaintiffs, and ROBERT C. SARVIS, v. Plaintiff − Appellant, JAMES B. ALCORN, in his individual and official capacities as member of the Virginia State Board of Elections; SINGLETON B. MCALLISTER, in her individual and official capacities as member of the Virginia State Board of Elections; CLARA BELLE WHEELER, in her individual and official capacities as member of the Virginia State Board of Elections, Defendants − Appellees. Appeal from the United States District Court for the Eastern District of Virginia, at Richmond. Robert E. Payne, Senior District Judge. (3:14-cv-00479-REP) Argued: May 10, 2016 Decided: June 20, 2016 Before WILKINSON and AGEE, Circuit Judges, and DAVIS, Senior Circuit Judge. Affirmed by published opinion. Judge Wilkinson wrote opinion in which Judge Agee and Senior Judge Davis joined. the Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 Pg: 2 of 27 ARGUED: David I. Schoen, DAVID I. SCHOEN, ATTORNEY AT LAW, Montgomery, Alabama, for Appellant. Stuart Alan Raphael, OFFICE OF THE ATTORNEY GENERAL OF VIRGINIA, Richmond, Virginia, for Appellees. ON BRIEF: Robert C. Sarvis, Alexandria, Virginia, Appellant Pro Se. Mark R. Herring, Attorney General of Virginia, Rhodes B. Ritenour, Deputy Attorney General, Anna T. Birkenheier, Assistant Attorney General, Matthew R. McGuire, Assistant Attorney General, Erin R. McNeill, Assistant Attorney General, Trevor S. Cox, Deputy Solicitor General, OFFICE OF THE ATTORNEY GENERAL OF VIRGINIA, Richmond, Virginia, for Appellees. 2 Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 Pg: 3 of 27 WILKINSON, Circuit Judge: Robert Sarvis, a political figure in the Libertarian Party of Virginia, brings a constitutional challenge to Virginia’s three-tiered ballot ordering law. The district court found no merit in Sarvis’s arguments and accordingly dismissed his challenge for failure to state a claim under Fed. R. Civ. P. 12(b)(6). We now affirm. I. Sarvis’s attack focuses chiefly upon the ballot ordering law found in Virginia Code § 24.2-613. That law describes the form of ballot to be used in Virginia elections. It provides that for elections to “federal, statewide, and General Assembly offices” a candidate “shall be identified by the name of his political party” or by the term “Independent.” Va. Code Ann. § 24.2-613. Of principal concern to this case, the law also orders the ballot for elections to these offices in three tiers. The first tier includes candidates from “parties” or “political parties,” which a related section of the Code defines as organizations of citizens that received at least 10 percent of the vote for any statewide office filled in either of the two preceding statewide general elections. Va. Code Ann. § 24.2-101. In addition, the Code provides that any organization seeking “party” or “political party” status must also have had a state central committee and an elected 3 state chairman present in Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 Virginia for Filed: 06/20/2016 months filing organization six for Pg: 4 of 27 prior to office. any Id. nominee The only from that organizations currently designated “parties” or “political parties” under the Code are the Republican Party and the Democratic Party. 1 The second political tier parties.” includes For an candidates organization from of “recognized citizens to be designated a “recognized political party” under the Code, that organization must have had a state central committee present in Virginia for six months prior to any nominee from that party filing for comprised office, of and voters the state residing in central each committee Virginia must be congressional district. Va. Code Ann. § 24.2-613. The organization must also have a duly elected state chairman and secretary as well as a party plan and bylaws. Id. The Libertarian Party of Virginia has been designated a “recognized political party” under the Code. Finally, “[i]ndependent the third candidates” tier not of the ballot associated with includes “political parties” or “recognized political parties.” Id. In tiers, addition Virginia’s to delineating ballot the ordering 1 election law also ballot’s specifies three how We note that as recently as the mid-1990s, the Virginia Reform Party satisfied the applicable requirements to be designated a “political party” and thus was part of the firsttier ballot listing on the 1996 general election ballot. Cf. J.A. 61, 95, and 97. 4 Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 Pg: 5 of 27 candidates are ordered within the three tiers. In the first two tiers, candidate order is set by lot. Importantly, this order is replicated for each office on the ballot, creating party order symmetry across the ballot as a whole. In the third tier, candidate order is alphabetical by surname. Id. 2 In July 2014, just a few months before the November 2014 elections, Sarvis and others members of the Libertarian Party of Virginia along with the Libertarian Party of Virginia itself and one independent defendants candidate certain members filed of a the complaint Virginia that named as State Board of Elections. The complaint alleged that the three-tiered ballot ordering law found in Virginia Code § 24.2-613 violated their constitutional rights under the First and Fourteenth Amendments. Sarvis and his co-plaintiffs sought relief from the law prior to the November 2014 elections. 3 2 Somewhat different rules govern the tiered ballot used for elections for the offices of President and Vice President of the United States. See Va. Code Ann. §§ 24.2-543, -613, -614. 3 The plaintiffs’ amended complaint before the district court also targeted Virginia Code § 24.2-506, a law establishing a signature requirement some prospective candidates must meet to be placed on the ballot in the first place. However, the plaintiffs later voluntarily dismissed this claim at oral argument before the district court. Sarvis’s appellate briefs reference the signature requirement, and it is thus unclear whether he is attempting to revive this claim on appeal. In any event, we will not consider this issue in light of the plaintiffs’ decision to dismiss it below. See Unioil, Inc. v. E.F. Hutton & Co., 809 F.2d 548, 555 (9th Cir. 1986) (“As a general rule, a plaintiff may not appeal a voluntary dismissal (Continued) 5 Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 Pg: 6 of 27 In September 2014, the plaintiffs and the Commonwealth both determined that the litigation would not be resolved prior to the November 2014 elections. But the parties and the district court agreed that, should Sarvis and his co-plaintiffs intend to seek elected office in the future, their case would remain ripe beyond the repetition November yet 2014 evading elections review under doctrine. the The capable plaintiffs of thus amended their complaint to reflect their interest in seeking relief from the ballot ordering law with regard to future elections, and the litigation continued on this basis. Sarvis in particular alleged that he would be “a candidate for national office in Virginia in the 2016 election.” J.A. 32. The amended complaint asked that the district court enjoin the law during the “2015 statewide elections and the 2016 and beyond general elections” and issue “an order directing the defendants to assign ballot positions to all ballot-qualified candidates and parties on a random basis without regard to party status.” J.A. 46. Shortly thereafter, Virginia filed a motion to dismiss under Rule 12(b)(6), claiming that the amended complaint failed to state a claim upon which relief could be granted. The because it is not an involuntary adverse judgment against him.”), overruling on other grounds recognized by In re Keegan Mgmt. Co., 78 F.3d 431, 435 (9th Cir. 1996). 6 Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 Pg: 7 of 27 district court granted Virginia’s motion to dismiss in January 2015. Sarvis v. Judd, 80 F. Supp. 3d 692, 695 (E.D. Va. 2015). The district court based its decision primarily on the framework established by the Supreme Court in Burdick v. Takushi, 504 U.S. 428 (1992), and Anderson v. Celebrezze, 460 U.S. 780 (1983). In those decisions, the Supreme Court held that courts should review First and Fourteenth Amendment-based challenges to state election laws challenged by law weighing imposes the on a severity person’s of the burden constitutional the rights against the importance of the state’s interests supporting that law. Burdick, 504 U.S. at 434; Anderson, 460 U.S. at 789. Sarvis and his co-plaintiffs, the Commonwealth of Virginia, and the district court all agreed that the burden imposed by the three-tiered ballot ordering law was not severe enough to warrant strict scrutiny. The district court gave two principal reasons for neutral in this that conclusion. it does First, not the entrench law is politically particular political parties in favorable positions on the election ballot. Sarvis, 80 F. Supp. 3d at 701-02. Second, the law does not exclude any prospective candidate from the ballot altogether. Id. at 702-03. Turning to the question of Virginia’s interests, the district court noted three justifications offered by Virginia for the ballot ordering law: avoiding voter confusion, creating party-order symmetry, and favoring 7 parties with demonstrated Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 Pg: 8 of 27 public support. Id. at 703. Before assessing the merits of these justifications, Virginia had however, described the the district nature court and determined purpose of the that three justifications with sufficient precision. Disagreeing with the plaintiffs, factual the district development of court the case held that neither nor more additional concrete empirical support for Virginia’s justifications was necessary before it could properly rule on Virginia’s motion to dismiss. Id. at 70306. The district court then reviewed Virginia’s three justifications and determined that each was important. Id. at 706-08. Finally, Virginia’s in weighing interests, the the plaintiffs’ district court burdens ruled against that the interests put forward by Virginia outweighed any minor burdens the ballot ordering law imposed on Sarvis and his co-plaintiffs. The district dismiss the court amended accordingly complaint. granted Virginia’s Id. 708-09. at motion Sarvis to alone appeals that order. II. Sarvis’s main argument on appeal is that Virginia’s threetiered ballot ordering law advantages candidates from what he calls “major parties” and disadvantages candidates like him that hail from what he calls “minor parties.” According to Sarvis, this conferral of advantages 8 and disadvantages violates Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 Pg: 9 of 27 expressive and associational rights, the right to cast a vote for a candidate of one’s choice, and the right to stand for election, all of which are protected by the First Amendment. In addition, Sarvis contends that the ballot ordering law’s unequal treatment of candidates runs afoul of the Fourteenth Amendment’s Equal Protection Clause. Appellant’s Opening Br. 12-13. Sarvis what the premises district his court constitutional termed the challenge “windfall largely vote” on theory. Sarvis, 80 F. Supp. 3d at 699. According to this theory, in any given election, some voters will vote for candidates appearing at the top of the ballot because of those candidates’ prominent ballot positions. Sarvis argues that Virginia’s ballot ordering law, in conjunction with this capricious voter bias, places an improper burden on candidates from minor parties. Before the district court, however, Sarvis stated that his expert would not testify about the exact extent of the bias in Sarvis’s specific situation. Id. at 700 n.1. Although he concedes that the burden imposed by the threetiered ballot ordering law is not subject to strict scrutiny, Sarvis contends that the district court’s Anderson/Burdick analysis nevertheless underestimated the magnitude of the burden imposed by the law. At the same time, he argues that the court’s analysis over-credited the interests Virginia offered to support the law. 9 Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 Pg: 10 of 27 Finally, in addition to disagreeing with the substance of the district court’s analysis of the burdens imposed and interests furthered by the ballot ordering law, Sarvis argues that the district court erred in rejecting his claims at the motion to dismiss stage. He states that the district court should have allowed discovery so as to better ascertain how the ballot ordering law burdens candidates who are not listed in the ballot’s first tier, and how it does or does not actually further the interests Virginia offers in support of the law. III. We begin with the uncontroversial proposition that the legislature in each state of our federal system possesses the presumptive authority to regulate elections within that state’s sovereign territory. This authority stems directly from the Constitution. With regard to congressional elections, Article I Section 4 Clause 1 of the Constitution provides: “The Times, Places and Manner Representatives, of shall holding be Elections prescribed in for each Senators State by and the Legislature thereof; but the Congress may at any time by Law make or alter such Regulations, except as to the Places of chusing Senators.” Article II Section 1 Clause 2 accords similar treatment to presidential elections: “Each State shall appoint, in such Manner as the Legislature thereof may direct, a Number of Electors,” who will then choose the President. And a state’s 10 Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 Pg: 11 of 27 authority to regulate elections for its own offices is simply a basic incident of our federal system. The Constitution nowhere confers – at least not as an initial matter – authority on the federal government to regulate elections for state offices. These constitutional provisions are the product of the Framers’ extensive debate concerning the roles that the state and federal governments would play in regulating elections. See, e.g., The Federalist No. 59 (Alexander Hamilton) (arguing for federal control Federalist No. over 7 congressional (Cato) (arguing elections); for state The Anti- control over congressional elections). It is no surprise that the precise compromise election. that For the Framers instance, the struck differs Framers chose for to each type “invest[] of the States with responsibility for the mechanics of congressional elections, but only so far as Congress declines to pre-empt state legislative choices.” Arizona v. Inter Tribal Council of Arizona, Inc., 133 S. Ct. 2247, 2253 (2013) (quoting Foster v. Love, 522 U.S. 67, 69 (1997)). With regard to presidential elections, however, the Framers adopted a different approach: the Electoral College. They then gave state legislatures the authority to decide the manner through which the electors from each state would be appointed. McPherson v. Blacker, 146 U.S. 1, 35 (1892). 11 Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 Pg: 12 of 27 Of course, the Reconstruction Amendments along with later amendments such as those providing for the election of Senators “by the people” (1913) and prohibiting denial of the right to vote “on account of sex” (1920) materially altered the division of labor established by the Framers for the regulation of elections. U.S. Const. amends. XVII, XIX. And various federal statutes, most notably the Voting Rights Act of 1965, passed pursuant to those amendments have made still further alterations. Most of these steps were deeply necessary and long overdue. Through continued to them preserve all, for however, state the Constitution legislatures the has presumptive authority to regulate both the larger and smaller aspects of the federal and state elections occurring within that state’s boundaries. Indeed, the Supreme Court has consistently recognized this enduring tenet of our constitutional order, noting that the states possess a “broad power to prescribe the Times, Places and Manner of holding Elections for Senators and Representatives, which power is matched by state control over the election process for state offices.” Clingman v. Beaver, 544 U.S. 581, 586 (2005) (quoting Tashjian v. Republican Party of Conn., 479 U.S. 208, Canvassing 217 (1986)); Bd., 531 U.S. see 70, also 76 12 Bush (2000) v. (per Palm Beach curiam) Cty. (noting Appeal: 15-1162 state Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 legislatures’ broad Pg: 13 of 27 power over the appointment of presidential electors). This arrangement is not only long-standing – it also makes a certain sense. All other things being equal, it is generally better for states to administer elections. It is true that smaller units of government can act oppressively toward minority citizens within their borders and against unpopular points of view. But local administration also allows for greater individual input and accountability; a distant bureaucracy is in danger of Alexander control appearing Hamilton, over out who of reach vigorously congressional and out supported elections, of touch. greater acknowledged the Even federal point: allowing “local administrations” to regulate elections “in the first instance” may, “in ordinary cases,” be “more convenient and more satisfactory.” The Federalist No. 59. All of this is to say that a lot of thought stretching over centuries has gone into our electoral system as it now generally operates. The text and history of the Constitution, well established Supreme Court precedent, and the structural principles inherent in our federal system counsel respect for the Virginia General Assembly’s power to administer elections in Virginia. IV. A. 13 Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 Mindful Filed: 06/20/2016 of state regulate elections, alleged burdens Pg: 14 of 27 legislatures’ we turn imposed by first longstanding to an authority examination Virginia’s of three-tiered to the ballot ordering law. State voting, election regulations associational and often expressive “implicate rights substantial protected by the First and Fourteenth Amendments.” Pisano v. Strach, 743 F.3d 927, 932 (4th Cir. 2014) (citation omitted). “The First Amendment, as incorporated against the states by the Fourteenth Amendment, protects the rights of individuals to associate for the advancement of political beliefs and ideas.” S.C. Green Party v. S.C. State Election Comm’n, 612 F.3d 752, 755-56 (4th Cir. 2010). For example, it is “beyond debate that freedom to engage in association for the advancement of beliefs and ideas is an inseparable aspect of the ‘liberty’ assured by the Due Process Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment, which embraces freedom of speech.” Anderson, 460 U.S. at 787 (quoting NAACP v. Alabama, 357 classifications Protection U.S. also Clause 449, violate of the 460 (1958)). rights protected Fourteenth “[I]nvidious” by Amendment. the Equal Williams v. Rhodes, 393 U.S. 23, 30 (1968). These rights, however, are not absolute. All “inevitably election affect[] laws, – at including least 14 to perfectly some valid degree ones, – the Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 individual’s Filed: 06/20/2016 right to vote Pg: 15 of 27 and his right to associate with others for political ends.” Anderson, 460 U.S. at 788. In order to distinguish uniquely unconstitutional validity is from unquestioned, Anderson/Burdick those the we decisional laws whose majority employ the framework. burdens of laws Supreme We are whose Court’s “consider the character and magnitude of the asserted injury to the rights protected by the plaintiff seeks First to and Fourteenth vindicate”; Amendments “identify the evaluate and that the precise interests put forward by the State as justifications for the burden imposed”; and “determine the legitimacy and strength of each of those interests” and “the extent to which those interests make it necessary to burden the plaintiff’s rights.” Anderson, 460 U.S. at 789. This balancing test requires “hard judgments” – it does not dictate “automatic” results. Id. at 789-90. The nature of our inquiry is “flexible” and “depends upon the extent to which a challenged regulation burdens First and Fourteenth Amendment rights.” Burdick, 504 U.S. at 434. Laws imposing only “modest” burdens are usually justified by a state’s “important regulatory interests.” S.C. Green Party, 612 F.3d at 759. Laws imposing “severe” burdens, on the other hand, “must be compelling ‘narrowly drawn importance.’” to advance Burdick, 15 504 a state U.S. at interest 434 of (citation Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 Pg: 16 of 27 omitted). They are thus subject to “strict scrutiny.” McLaughlin v. N.C. Bd. of Elections, 65 F.3d 1215, 1221 (4th Cir. 1995). However, the class limited. of Subjecting laws too facing many this laws to higher strict scrutiny scrutiny is would unnecessarily “tie the hands of States seeking to assure that elections are operated equitably and efficiently.” Burdick, 504 U.S. at 433. Here, Virginia’s three-tiered ballot ordering law imposes only the most modest burdens on Sarvis’s free speech, associational, and equal protection rights. The law is facially neutral and nondiscriminatory – neither Sarvis’s Libertarian Party nor any other party faces a disproportionate burden. All parties are subject automatically to the elevated to same the top requirements. of the ballot. None are Virginia’s ballot ordering law thus allows any political organization - of any persuasion – an evenhanded chance at achieving political party status and a first-tier ballot position. Va. Code Ann. §§ 24.2-101, -613. Sarvis political complains party that status the is bar for nonetheless achieving too first-tier high, but he exaggerates the difficulty of this goal. An organization may obtain first-tier political party status if any of its candidates for any office receives 10 percent of the vote in either of the two preceding statewide general elections. And, in 16 Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 Pg: 17 of 27 any case, his complaint is inapposite because he may be present on the ballot in all events. Sarvis did appear on the ballot in the past, and he may do so again in the future. What is denied, therefore, preferred is not method ballot of access, ballot but ordering. rather But access mere to a ballot order denies neither the right to vote, nor the right to appear on the ballot, nor the right to form or associate in a political organization. Comparing this relaxed regime with statutes upheld in other cases demonstrates that Virginia’s ballot ordering law imposes only a minimal burden on First and Fourteenth Amendment rights. For example, in Munro v. Socialist Workers Party, the Supreme Court considered the constitutionality of a Washington state law requiring that “a minor-party candidate for partisan office receive at least 1% of all votes cast for that office in the State’s primary election” in order even to appear on the general election ballot at all. 479 U.S. 189, 190 (1986). The Court upheld the law, because Washington “ha[d] not substantially burdened the ‘availability of political opportunity.’” Id. at 199 (citation omitted). Other cases have found that a complete prohibition on write-in voting imposed only “very limited” burdens on constitutional rights, Burdick, 504 U.S. at 437, and that a law barring candidates from appearing on the ballot as candidates of more than one political party “does not severely 17 Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 Pg: 18 of 27 burden” associational rights. Timmons v. Twin Cities Area New Party, 520 U.S. 351, 359 (1997). Indeed, the Court has even held that a state may prohibit independent candidates from appearing on the ballot if they “had a registered affiliation with a qualified political party” during the previous year. Storer v. Brown, 415 U.S. 724, 726-28 (1974). Viewed in the light of these regulations, Sarvis’s squabbles with his particular position on the ballot appear almost inconsequential. The ballot ordering law does not deny anyone the ability to vote for him, nor his ability to appear on the Virginia ballot with his preferred party affiliation. Sarvis himself recognizes the limits of the ballot ordering law’s burdens, as he concedes that this case “does not rise to a level of strict scrutiny.” J.A. 183-84. He nonetheless maintains that the law “creates a serious consequential burden,” because “[c]andidates in inferior ballot positions have a strong likelihood of getting fewer votes than they would otherwise” under the theory of windfall voting. Appellant’s Opening Br. 3. The theory likely to is that choose uninformed candidates or listed undecided higher on voters the are more ballot. In Sarvis’s view, Virginia’s ballot ordering law thus grants an advantage to candidates from major political parties, and determining the magnitude of this advantage requires that the 18 Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 Pg: 19 of 27 case “go forward on the merits for the development of a full factual record.” Appellant’s Opening Br. 13. Sarvis’s demand for discovery, however, misapprehends the nature of a motion to dismiss. Here, the district court properly recognized that “[t]o survive a Rule 12(b)(6) motion to dismiss, a complaint must ‘provide enough facts to state a claim that is plausible on its face,’” Sarvis, 80 F. Supp. 3d at 696 (quoting Robinson v. Am. Honda Motor Co., 551 F.3d 218, 222 (4th Cir. 2009)), and that to reach facial plausibility, Sarvis must “plead[] factual reasonable content inference that that allows the the defendant court is to liable draw the for the misconduct alleged.” Id. (quoting Ashcroft v. Iqbal, 556 U.S. 662, 678 (2009)). The problem for Sarvis is that even if there is a windfall vote, his complaint would still fail to raise the “reasonable inference” that constitutionally Virginia’s significant ballot burdens. ordering The fact law creates remains that, “windfall” or not, the Virginia ballot ordering law still does not “restrict access to the ballot or deny any voters the right to vote for candidates of their choice.” Sonneman v. State, 969 P.2d 632, 638 (Alaska 1998). The law instead “merely allocates the benefit of positional bias, which places a lesser burden on the right to vote.” Id. And contrary to Sarvis’s cursory equal protection argument, Appellant’s 19 Opening Br. 12-13, it makes Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 Pg: 20 of 27 this allocation in a neutral, nondiscriminatory manner. Compare Graves v. McElderry, 946 F. Supp. 1569, 1582 (W.D. Okla. 1996) (holding that an Oklahoma law placing Democratic Party candidates in the highest ballot positions violated the Equal Protection Clause), with Bd. of Election Comm’rs of Chicago v. Libertarian Party of Ill., 591 F.2d 22, 25-27 (7th Cir. 1979) (holding that an Illinois county’s facially neutral two-tiered ballot ordering system did not violate the Equal Protection Clause). It remains far from clear, moreover, that federal courts possess the power to rule that some voters’ choices are less constitutionally meaningful than the choices of other supposedly more informed or committed voters. This whole windfall vote theory casts aspersions upon citizens who expressed their civic right to participate in an election and made a choice of their own free will. Who are we to demean their decision? “There is ‘no constitutional right to a wholly rational election, based solely on candidates’ a reasoned consideration positions, considerations.’” Schaefer and v. free of the from Lamone, No. issues other and the ‘irrational’ 1:06-cv-00896-BEL, 2006 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 96855, at *13 (D. Md. Nov. 30, 2006) (quoting Clough v. Guzzi, 416 F. Supp. 1057, 1067 (D. Mass. 1976), aff’d, 248 F. App’x 484 (4th Cir. 2007). As noted, Sarvis says that his expert would not testify as to the exact degree of 20 Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 Pg: 21 of 27 positional bias caused by Virginia’s law, but this admission is unnecessary to our analysis. “[A]ccess to a preferred position on the ballot so that one has an equal chance of attracting the windfall vote is not a constitutional concern.” New Alliance Party v. N.Y. State Bd. of Elections, 861 F. Supp. 282, 295 (S.D.N.Y. 1994). Even without Sarvis’s admission, the windfall vote theory cognizable would thus fail constitutional to raise burden on an inference First or of any Fourteenth Amendment rights. Given that the Virginia ballot ordering law does not restrict candidate access to the ballot or deny voters the right to vote for the candidate of their choice, or otherwise require strict scrutiny, we have no need to conduct the kind of empirical analysis into burdens that would essentially displace the authority of state legislatures with the views of expert witnesses. That is not to say, however, that our analysis is at an end. In order to be sure that the district court did not improperly dismiss Sarvis’s complaint, we need to make certain that important state interests support Virginia’s ballot ordering law. B. Virginia’s three-tiered ballot ordering law is supported by “important regulatory interests.” Timmons, 520 U.S. at 358. In particular, the law may assist the voting process by reducing 21 Appeal: 15-1162 voter Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 confusion and Pg: 22 of 27 preserving party-order symmetry across different offices on the ballot. Additionally, the law may also reduce multi-party factionalism and promote political stability. Sarvis again insists that we may not weigh these interests without discovery. Appellant’s Opening Br. 20. But “elaborate, empirical verification of [] weightiness” is not required. Timmons, 520 U.S. at 364. To hold otherwise would “invariably lead to endless court battles” over the quality of the state’s evidence, Munro, 479 U.S. at 195, and to a corresponding loss of certainty over the rules by which we select our whole government. We therefore do not “require that a state justify” reasonable and nondiscriminatory rules “in this manner.” Wood v. Meadows, strict 207 F.3d scrutiny 708, does 716 not (4th apply, Cir. we 2000). ask only In cases that the where state “articulate[]” its asserted interests. Id. at 717. This is not a high bar, and Virginia has cleared it here. Reasoned, credible argument supports its stated interests. First, Virginia’s three-tiered ballot ordering law serves the important state interest of reducing voter confusion and speeding the voting process. While Sarvis’s complaint is vague about how his preferred ballot listing would actually operate, J.A. 46, it is clear that he wishes to move ballot ordering among parties and candidates to a more purely random system. Virginia’s system, by contrast, emphasizes voter familiarity and 22 Appeal: 15-1162 more Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 predictable order. Pg: 23 of 27 Listing candidates by party allows voters to more quickly find their preferred choice for a given office, especially when party loyalties influence many voters’ decisions. And in an environment where many voters not only hold party loyalties but also tend to be loyal to one of only a few major parties, candidates it from again those aids parties the process to on first voting ballot. Sarvis’s the list request for a court decree commanding Virginia to randomly order its ballot betrays not only a flawed conception of federal judicial power. It is also suspect as a practical matter. Random ordering risks requiring voters to decipher lengthy multi- office, multi-candidate ballots in order to find their preferred candidates. “Election officials have good reason to adopt a ballot format that minimizes” this sort of “confusion.” Bd. of Election Comm’rs of Chicago, 591 F.2d at 25. For each extra minute that a voter spends deciphering his ballot in the voting booth, dozens or more voters may spend another minute in line. This all adds up. Long election lines may frustrate voters attempting to exercise their right to vote. Hour long lines at some polling locations have led many to complain that election officials had discouraged their exercise of the franchise. See, e.g., Fernanda Santos, In Arizona, Voters Demand: Why the Lines?, N.Y. Times, 23 Appeal: 15-1162 March Doc: 53 25, 2016, Filed: 06/20/2016 at A13. Pg: 24 of 27 Reducing the risk of this sort of disincentive is undoubtedly an important state interest. Second, and relatedly, Virginia’s ballot ordering law also has the advantage of maintaining party-order symmetry across many offices on the ballot. Within the first two ballot tiers, party order is determined by lot. Va. Code Ann. § 24.2-613. The names of all party-affiliated candidates for particular offices then appear “in the order determined for their parties.” Id. This is so for all “federal, statewide, and General Assembly offices.” Id. The effect of all this is to create “a symmetrical pattern on the ballot.” New Alliance Party, 861 F. Supp. at 297. The ballot law ensures that if a party’s candidate for United States Senator is listed second, for example, then candidates from that party will be second in lists for other offices as well. This again advances the state’s interest in “efficient procedures for the election of public officials.” S.C. Green Party, 612 F.3d at 759. It makes the ballot more easily decipherable, especially for voters looking for candidates affiliated with a given party. Finally, the ballot ordering law may also favor Virginia’s “strong interest in the stability of [its] political system[].” Timmons, 520 U.S. at 366. “Maintaining a stable political system is, unquestionably, a compelling state interest.” Eu v. S.F. Cty. Democratic Cent. Comm., 489 U.S. 214, 226 (1989). While 24 Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 Pg: 25 of 27 minor parties have long been an important feature of political protest and legitimate American for states democratic to life, correlate it is ballot also entirely placement with demonstrated levels of public support. Indeed, there are many who believe that “the emergence of a strong and stable two-party system in this country has contributed enormously to sound and effective government.” Davis v. Bandemer, 478 U.S. 109, 144-45 (1986) (O’Connor, J., concurring). The Constitution therefore unsurprisingly “permits [a state legislature] to decide that political stability is best served through a healthy two-party system,” Timmons, 520 U.S. at 367, as opposed to shifting coalitions of multiple party entities. Of course, state latitude in this regard is not unlimited. While a state system legislature from may minor not “completely parties’ or insulate independent the two-party candidates’ competition and influence,” it may “enact reasonable election regulations that may, in practice, favor the traditional twoparty system,” and “temper the destabilizing effects of partysplintering and excessive factionalism.” Id. Structuring ballot order to prefer parties already strong enough to reach first-tier party status under the Virginia Code may further this stabilizing goal. In Sarvis’s view, after all, a windfall vote of some magnitude is inevitable. Assuming this is true, some party or candidate will benefit. Some party or 25 Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 Pg: 26 of 27 candidate has to be listed first. But Virginia’s ballot ordering law ensures entity with acknowledge that at little that least the actual the two beneficiary public major will support. parties may not Of be some course, possess a we self- interest in preserving their preferred status, but we will not leap from that fact to the conclusion that a requirement of demonstrated public support is somehow inimical to the public good. Reinforcing through facially neutral and nondiscriminatory methods affiliations already democratically expressed by large portions of the public simply does not offend the Constitution. V. Having identified the asserted state interests furthered by Virginia’s three-tiered ballot ordering law, we must at last weigh them against the law’s burdens on the plaintiff’s First and Fourteenth Amendment rights. Burdick, 504 U.S. at 434. Here our job is easy – this case is one of the “usual[]” variety in which the “State’s important regulatory interests . . . justify reasonable, nondiscriminatory restrictions.” Timmons, 520 U.S. at 358 (citation and internal quotation marks omitted). The three-tiered ballot ordering law imposes little burden on Sarvis’s several constitutional important rights, interests and Virginia supporting the articulates law. In these circumstances, we have “no basis for finding a state statutory scheme unconstitutional.” Wood, 26 207 F.3d at 717. We leave Appeal: 15-1162 Doc: 53 Filed: 06/20/2016 Pg: 27 of 27 further resolution of this controversy to a different and better set of arbiters: the people, and through them, the political branches. AFFIRMED 27

Disclaimer: Justia Dockets & Filings provides public litigation records from the federal appellate and district courts. These filings and docket sheets should not be considered findings of fact or liability, nor do they necessarily reflect the view of Justia.


Why Is My Information Online?