Precision CPAP, Inc. et al v. Jackson Hospital et al
Filing
53
OPINION. An appropriate judgment will be entered. Signed by Honorable Myron H. Thompson on 3/8/2010. (cb, )
IN THE DISTRICT COURT OF THE UNITED STATES FOR THE MIDDLE DISTRICT OF ALABAMA, NORTHERN DIVISION
PRECISION CPAP, INC.; MEDICAL PLACE, INC.; PHASE III VANS, INC. d/b/a EAST MEDICAL EQUIPMENT AND EQUIPMENT AND SUPPLY; and MED-EX,
) ) ) ) ) ) ) Plaintiffs, ) ) v. ) ) JACKSON HOSPITAL; MED-SOUTH ) INC.; JMS HEALTH SERVICES, ) LLC, d/b/a JACKSON MED) SOUTH HOME HEALTH, LLC,; ) BAPTIST HEALTH, INC.; ) BAPTIST VENTURES-AMERICAN ) HOME PATIENT; ) ) Defendants. ) OPINION
CIVIL ACTION NO. 2:05cv1096-MHT (WO)
The plaintiffs, which are in the durable medical equipment (DME) business, bring this private antitrust suit against the defendants, which are hospitals,
corporations, and affiliates, claiming violations of §§ 1 and 2 of the Sherman Antitrust Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1 & 2,
as privately enforced through §§ 4 and 16 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 15 & 26, as well as violations of Alabama state antitrust law, 1975 Ala. Code § 6-5-60. The plaintiffs are as follows: Precision CPAP, Inc.;
Medical Place, Inc.; Phase III Vans, Inc., d/b/a/ East Medical Equipment and Supply; and Med-Ex. are as follows: The defendants
Jackson Hospital; Med-South, Inc.; JMS
Health Services, L.L.C., d/b/a Jackson Med-South Home Health, Patient, Patient. L.L.C.; Inc.; Baptist and Health, Inc.; American Home Home
Baptist
Ventures-American
Specifically, the plaintiffs allege that the
defendants have illegally excluded them from the DME market. Jurisdiction over the plaintiffs' federal claims is proper pursuant to 28 U.S.C. §§ 1331 (federal
question) and 15 U.S.C. § 4 (antitrust); supplemental jurisdiction over the state claims is proper under 28 U.S.C. § 1367. Now before the court is the defendants' motion to dismiss the plaintiffs' first amended complaint. Fed. R.
2
Civ. P. 12(b)(6).
For the reasons that follow, the
motion will be granted.
I. MOTION-TO-DISMISS STANDARD In considering a defendant's motion to dismiss, the court accepts the plaintiff's allegations as true, Hishon v. King & Spalding, 467 U.S. 69, 73 (1984), and construes the complaint in the plaintiff's favor, Duke v. Cleland, 5 F.3d 1399, 1402 (11th Cir. 1993). "The issue is not
whether a plaintiff will ultimately prevail but whether the claimant is entitled to offer evidence to support the claims." Scheuer v. Rhodes, 416 U.S. 232, 236 (1974).
To survive a dismissal motion, a complaint need not contain "detailed factual allegations," Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544, 555 (2007), but rather "only enough facts to state a claim to relief that is plausible on its face," id. at 570.
3
II. BACKGROUND The relevant facts as alleged by the plaintiffs are as follows. formerly The plaintiffs are corporations engaged or in the business of providing DME
engaged
(including beds, walkers, wheelchairs, and oxygen tanks) for the home-health Alabama. care of The patients vast in and around of the
Montgomery,
majority
plaintiffs' business results from the sale or lease of DME to patients who have been discharged from local hospitals and prescribed DME by their physicians. Defendant Jackson Hospital, in Montgomery, and
defendant Baptist Health, which operates two hospitals in Montgomery as well as a hospital in nearby Prattville, Alabama, are the primary source of hospital services for a majority of Montgomery-area residents. Until the late
1990s, the plaintiffs focused their DME marketing efforts on the staff at these hospitals and on patients awaiting discharge. When patients did not choose a DME provider,
they were assigned to a provider on a rotating basis.
4
In the late 1990s, Jackson Hospital and Baptist Health each decided to enter the DME market. Jackson
entered into a joint venture with defendant Med-South, Inc., a DME provider, to operate JMS Health Services. Similarly, Baptist Health entered into a joint venture with defendant to American Home Patient, Inc., a DME Home
provider, Patient. of DME
operate
Baptist
Ventures-American
Each joint venture created an in-house provider for the patients at Jackson's and Baptist's
respective hospitals.1 Once these joint ventures were formed, Jackson
Hospital began referring its patients with DME needs to JMS, and the hospitals operated by Baptist Health began referring Ventures. their The patients hospitals with DME needs their to Baptist of
ended
practice
assigning DME providers on a rotating basis to patients who do not choose a provider. Unless patients
1. The amended complaint does not allege that Jackson Hospital and Baptist Health cooperated in any way with each other, only that they both entered similar joint ventures with different DME providers. 5
specifically requested an outside DME provider, they were referred to the hospital's affiliated DME provider. The hospitals plaintiffs have allege that their and referrals that they from have
almost
vanished
suffered a loss of revenue as a result of the defendants' actions. Plaintiff Med-Ex sold the assets of its
business and alleges that the sale price of the assets was depressed as a result of the defendants' actions.
III. FEDERAL CLAIMS A. Antitrust Standing
As a threshold matter, the court must address whether the plaintiffs have standing to sue under the Sherman and Clayton Acts. Section 4 of the Clayton Act defines the
class of persons who may bring a private-damages action under antitrust laws. It states:
"Any person who shall be injured in his business or property by reason of anything forbidden in the antitrust laws may sue therefore in any district of the United States in the district in which the defendant resides or is found or has 6
an agent, without respect to the amount in controversy, and shall recover threefold the damages by him sustained, and the cost of suit, including a reasonable attorney's fee." 15 U.S.C. § 5. Despite this language, which could
conceivably "encompass every harm that can be attributed directly to the consequences of an antitrust violation," Assoc. Gen. Contractors of Cal., Inc. v. Cal. State Council of Carpenters, 459 U.S. 519, 529 (1983), the courts have interpreted this statute more narrowly. In
considering whether a party has standing to bring suit under the antitrust laws, a court should first determine "whether the plaintiff suffered `antitrust injury.'"
Todorov v. DCH Healthcare Auth., 921 F.2d 1438, 1449 (11th Cir. 1991). Antitrust injury is "injury of the
type the antitrust laws were intended to prevent and that flows from that which makes defendants' acts unlawful." Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477, 489 (1977). Specifically, "[t]he injury should reflect
the anticompetitive effects either of the violation or of
7
anticompetitive acts made possible by the violation." Id. Second, is "the an court should determine of whether the
plaintiff laws."
efficient
enforcer
the
antitrust
Todorov, 921 F.2d at 1449.
This requires an
examination of factors including: "1) the existence of a causal connection between the antitrust violation and the alleged injury; 2) the nature of plaintiff's alleged injury; 3) the directness or indirectness of the asserted injury and the related inquiry of whether the damages are speculative; 4) the potential for duplicative recovery or complex apportionment of damages; and, finally, 5) the existence of a more direct victim of the alleged anticompetitive conduct." Austin v. Blue Cross & Blue Shield of Alabama, 903 F.2d 1385, 1388 (11th Cir. 1990). To determine antitrust
standing, "a court must review the allegations contained in the complaint." Id. at 1387.
The plaintiffs allege that the hospitals and their captive DME providers combined to restrict access to the market for DME sales and rentals to patients discharged from their hospitals. Specifically, the hospitals ceased 8
the rotational assignment of patients to the plaintiffs and other DME providers; denied the plaintiffs access to the hospital staff and patients; and instructed case workers on staff to refer patients to the captive DME providers. The plaintiffs allege that, as a result, in
most cases patients know of only one choice of DME provider. According to the plaintiffs, this has led to
an increase in the captive DME providers' market power to the point where they can cut services and raise prices without any corresponding drop in usage or revenues. The defendants are contend that to the plaintiffs' antitrust
allegations standing. plaintiffs
insufficient
establish
In particular, the defendants argue that the lack antitrust standing because they are
unable to show that prices have actually risen for DME not covered by Medicare or that the quality has eroded for DME covered by Medicare. According to the
defendants, the plaintiffs did not suffer an antitrust
9
injury and, even if they had, the plaintiffs would not be the most efficient enforcers of the antitrust laws.
1.
Antitrust Injury The defendants rely on the reasoning in Todorov to
support their contention that the plaintiffs did not suffer an antitrust injury. There, the Eleventh Circuit
Court of Appeals held that a doctor lacked antitrust standing to sue a hospital for failure to grant
privileges in the radiology department. Todorov was a practicing neurologist who relied on CT scans to diagnose his patients. 1442. Todorov, 921 F.2d at
He referred many of his patients to DCH Healthcare DCH would receive a fee
Authority for the procedure.
from patients' insurance companies for the CT scan, even though Todorov usually examined the film himself. To
obtain some of the profits from the procedure, Todorov applied for privileges at DCH to administer and
officially interpret CT scans.
DCH, however, denied his
10
application. Todorov brought suit against defendants for conspiracy under Section 1 of 2 the of Sherman the Act and Act.
monopolization
under
Section
Sherman
Specifically, he alleged that radiologists controlled the market and were reaping supercompetitive profits. The court held that Todorov's alleged injury was not the "type the antitrust laws were intended to prevent and that flows from that which makes the defendants' acts unlawful." Id. at 1453. Todorov "applied for privileges
in the radiology department so that he could reap the profits that the radiologists received" from the inflated prices that patients were charged. Id. at 1452. Thus,
his primary objective in bringing suit was to benefit from supercompetitive prices rather than create
competition for consumers.
This was not a cognizable
antitrust injury because "[t]he antitrust laws were not enacted to permit one person to profit from the
anticompetitive behavior of another person." 1454.
Id. at
11
Contrary to the defendants' contention, this case is distinguishable from Todorov. Whereas Todorov failed to
allege any injury to competition from DCH's denial of access to radiologist in this privileges, that the the plaintiffs' were
allegations
case,
hospitals
channeling patient choice to their captive DME providers, are sufficient to show the necessary injury to
competition.
See Advanced Health-Care Servs, Inc. v.
Radford Cmty Hosp., 910 F.2d 139, 149 (4th Cir. 1990). In addition, the failure of the plaintiffs to allege an actual increase in prices or an actual deterioration in the quality of DME does not defeat the claim of an antitrust injury. In making a determination of whether a plaintiff has alleged antitrust injury, "a court must consider the effect on competition and not simply the effect on the ultimate consumer." Key Enterprise of
Delaware, Inc. v. Venice Hospital, 919 F.2d 1550, 1559 (11th Cir. 1990), vacated as moot en banc, 9 F.3d 893
12
(11th Cir. 1993).2
If the allegations of the plaintiffs
are proven true, competition has been injured because competing DME vendors no longer have access to the
discharged-hospital patients who require DME. Finally, this court disagrees with the defendants' contention that the plaintiffs, through this action, seek only to increase their profits and therefore have not alleged a cognizable antitrust injury. Unlike Todorov,
the plaintiffs' damages in this case are not premised on their ability to profit while patients "paid an
artificially inflated price."
Todorov, 921 F.2d at 1454.
Instead, the plaintiffs seek to ameliorate the potential for an increase in price and erosion in the quality of DME by reintroducing competition into the DME market for discharged-hospital patients. While an increase in the
2. The defendants correctly assert that Key Enterprises has no precedential authority since it was vacated on mootness grounds. However, a court can find the reasoning in vacated cases to be of persuasive value. See e.g., United States v. Johnson, 399 F.3d 1297, 1298 n.1 (2005) (concluding that a vacated opinion can have persuasive value). 13
plaintiffs' successful
profit suit, it
will does
be
a
likely come at
byproduct the
of
a
not
continued
detriment of consumers and competition.
2.
Efficient Enforcer of the Antitrust Laws The second issue that must be addressed to determine
the plaintiffs' antitrust standing is whether they would be "efficient enforcer[s] of the antitrust laws."
Todorov, 921 F.2d at 1449.
As stated, there is a non-
exhaustive list of five factors that should be assessed in determining whether a plaintiff is an efficient
enforcer of the antitrust laws. addressing plaintiffs any would particular not be
The defendants, without contend that of the the
factor, efficient
enforcers
antitrust laws. factors in turn.
The court will address each of the
The first factor this court must address is "the existence of a causal connection between the antitrust violation and the alleged injury." Austin, 903 F.2d at
14
1388.
In
this
case,
the
plaintiffs
allege
that
violations of the Sherman Act have caused a loss of business and create the potential for an increase in price and an erosion in the quality of DME. This court
finds that the allegations are sufficient to show a causal connection between the asserted antitrust
violation and the alleged injury. Areeda et al., Antitrust Law ¶
See 2A Phillip E. 338 (hereinafter,
"Areeda") ("It is ... enough that the antitrust violation contributes significantly to the plaintiff's injury, even if other factors amounted in the aggregate to a more substantial cause."). According to the second factor, this court must look to "the nature of plaintiff's alleged injury," Austin, 903 F.2d at 1388, "including the status of the plaintiff as consumer or competitor in the relevant market,"
Potters Medical Ctr. v. City Hosp. Ass'n, 800 F.2d 568, 575 (6th Cir. 1986), to determine whether plaintiff is an efficient enforcer of the antitrust laws. The plaintiffs
15
in
the
instant
case
are
clearly
competitors
in
the
relevant market as they allegedly lost profits as a result of the this defendants' second factor exclusionary supports a practices. finding of
Therefore,
antitrust standing. The third through fifth factors raise more difficult issues. In a case that is most analogous to the present
case and that addresses these three factors, Park Ave. Radiology Assocs., P.C. v. Methodist, 198 F.3d 246, 1999 WL 1045098 (6th Cir. 1999) (table),3 plaintiffs, providers 3. Park Avenue, although unpublished, obviously still can have persuasive value. Based on the similarities between Park Avenue and the present case, this court will look to the Sixth Circuit's treatment of the antitrust standing issue (particularly the issue of whether the plaintiffs were efficient enforcers of the antitrust law) as a guide to resolution of the question of standing in this case. To support their argument that there was antitrust standing, the plaintiffs looked to two cases that addressed whether a competitor DME provider had antitrust standing to bring suit. See Key Enterprises, 919 F.2d at 1559-60; Advanced Health-Care Services, Inc. v. Radford Community Hospital, 910 F.2d 139, 149 (4th Cir. 1990). However, in neither of the cases did the court address the second prong of the antitrust-standing determination: whether the plaintiff would be an efficient enforcer of the antitrust laws. (continued...) 16
of outpatient-radiologist services for patients referred to them by primary-care physicians, appealed from a
dismissal of their claims for lack of antitrust standing. The physicians with staff privileges at the Methodist Hospitals were members of Metrocare, Inc., a company that negotiated with third-party payors of managed health care programs on behalf of its member physicians. Metrocare
was a member of Health Choice, Inc., which operated a preferred-provider organization. Plaintiffs alleged that Health Choice contracted with employers and insurance companies to make Methodist Health's hospital services and Metrocare physician services available at a
discounted rate to beneficiaries in the relevant groups. After making entering into of the contract, to Metrocare plaintiffs. stopped This
referrals
patients
3. (...continued) Todorov, which was decided after these two cases, requires that this court look to whether plaintiffs would be efficient enforcers of the antitrust laws in order to determine whether they have antitrust standing. Therefore, this court will look to Park Avenue because it provides more relevant guidance on this issue. 17
resulted in a loss of business to the plaintiffs. Addressing indirectness of the the third factor ("the directness the or
asserted
injury
and
related
inquiry of whether the damages are speculative," Austin, 903 F.2d at 1388), the Park Avenue court held that the injury to plaintiff radiologists was indirect because "their claimed lost profits [were] derivative of the alleged harm inflicted on third parties--the health care consumers and their third-party providers," that is, insurance companies and employers. 1045089, at *5-*6. Park Avenue, 1999 WL
The court also held that the damages
were speculative because the number of lost referrals was difficult to measure. Id. at *6.
Analogously, in the instant case, the injury of lost profits to the plaintiffs is indirect and derivative of the alleged harm inflicted on the discharged patients. In addition, the damages are speculative because it would be difficult for the plaintiffs to measure the number of lost referrals resulting from the hospitals' allegedly
18
exclusionary
conduct.
This
factor
therefore
weighs
against affording the plaintiffs antitrust standing. Addressing the fourth factor, the Park Avenue court explained that "the potential for duplicative recovery or complex apportionment of damages exist if Plaintiffs were allowed to go forward inasmuch as the parties directly harmed would also have a cause of action." Id, at *7.
Here, in the instant case, if the plaintiffs were allowed to go forward with the suit, there is a risk that of are
duplicative
recovery
because
the
patients
directly harmed by the exclusionary conduct could also bring suits against the hospitals and the captive DME providers. In addition, if plaintiffs were awarded
damages, this court would face the difficult prospect of identifying damages and apportioning them among directly victimized plaintiffs. This factor patients and the indirectly affected
See Associated General, 459 U.S. at 545. therefore weighs against affording the
plaintiffs antitrust standing.
19
Addressing the fifth and final factor ("the existence of a more direct victim of the alleged anticompetitive conduct," Austin, 903 F.2d at 1388), the Park Avenue court identified the healthcare consumers and third-party insurers as the direct victims of the alleged antitrust violations. patients Id. at *6-*7. the direct Similarly, in this case, the victims of the allegedly
are
exclusionary conduct that limits their choice of DME providers and could have the potential of increasing the price and eroding the quality of DME. Thus, three of the five factors identified in Austin (including the indirectness of the asserted injury and the speculative nature of the damages; the potential for duplicative recovery or complex apportionment of damages; and the existence of a more direct victim of the
anticompetitive
conduct)
weigh
against
judicial
enforcement of the plaintiffs' antitrust claim. However, as discussed above, the factors identified in Austin should not be considered exhaustive.
20
Prominent antitrust commentators Phillip Areeda and Herbert Hovenkamp have identified additional factors that are relevant to this case. These commentators argue that
competitor antitrust standing serves antitrust policy when "(a) the rival is in a position to detect a
violation earlier than consumers are; or (b) the rival's injury is large, while the injuries of individual
consumers are likely to be very small or the consumers have collective action problems making their suit
cumbersome or less likely."
2A Areeda ¶ 348.
Addressing first whether the plaintiffs are in a position to detect a violation earlier than the patients, the plaintiffs allege that patients rarely have a
preferred DME provider.
As a result, the system of
hospital-staff referral to the captive DME providers combined with the denial to competing DME providers of access to hospitals to market their services results in a situation in which patients, "with very few exceptions, know of only one choice for durable medical equipment."
21
Plaintiffs' First Amended Complaint, at ¶ 24 (doc. no. 21). Without knowledge of alternatives, patients will
not be able to detect the evidence of an antitrust violation, including higher prices and an erosion in the quality of services. The Park Avenue court addressed a similar issue and explained that the role of third-party payors (employers and insurance companies) was an important element not addressed in the radiologists' argument that they were the most efficient enforcers of antitrust law. In
particular, the court surmised that, "if Plaintiffs are providing a superior and more cost efficient product as they allege, then the third-party providers ... will direct their members to Plaintiffs, and those patients who may not have any third party coverage will do the same in a competitive market." 1045098, at *5. For those covered by insurance, such as Medicare, the holding in Park Avenue is persuasive that the third-party Park Avenue, 1999 WL
22
payor would be as well positioned as rivals to detect an antitrust violation. However, for those not covered by
insurance, it is not clear how the method of detection identified in Park Avenue would operate. In cases
involving uninsured patients who do not have knowledge of DME prior to their entry into the hospital and to whom non-captive DME providers are unable to market their services in the hospital, there is no third-party payor to direct patients to the most cost-efficient DME
provider. Thus, uninsured patients are poorly positioned relative to rival DME providers to detect an antitrust violation. In addition, even if the captive DME providers
ultimately raised the prices or allowed their services to erode, the harm to individual patients is likely to be very small in comparison to the plaintiffs' loss of profits resulting from the defendants' anticompetitive conduct. As a result, the likelihood that patients will
23
bring suit to ameliorate the allegedly anticompetitive conduct is minimal. While it is a close call, this court finds that the plaintiffs are efficient enforcers of the antitrust law. The plaintiffs are much better positioned than consumers to detect an antitrust violation earlier. In addition,
consumers would suffer from collective-action problems in bringing a suit because of the relatively small injury experienced by individual consumers by the rise in price or decline in the quality of DME. On the basis of the finding that the plaintiffs are efficient enforcers of the antitrust laws combined with the finding above that the plaintiffs have demonstrated antitrust injury, this court concludes that the
plaintiffs have antitrust standing to sue for damages under the Sherman and Clayton Acts. This court now
addresses whether the plaintiffs have stated claims under §§ 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act for which relief can be granted.
24
B.
Sherman Act § 1
Under § 1 of the Sherman Act, "[e]very contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or
conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, is declared to be illegal." 15 U.S.C. § 1.4 "Although the Sherman Act,
by its terms, prohibits every agreement `in restraint of trade,'" the Supreme Court "has long recognized that Congress intended to outlaw only unreasonable
restraints." (1997). The
State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3, 10 plaintiffs bring a claim of coercive
reciprocity and concerted refusal to deal under § 1 of the Sherman Act.
4. Although the Sherman Act itself does not provide a private right of action, the Clayton Act permits private parties to seek damages or injunctive relief for antitrust violations. 15 U.S.C. §§ 15, 26. 25
1.
Coercive Reciprocity Count I of the plaintiffs' amended complaint alleges
restraint of trade in violation of § 1 of the Sherman Act; more specifically, the plaintiffs allege that the defendants have engaged in an illegal restraint of trade by contracting, combining, or conspiring to use their control of hospital services to coerce patients into buying or renting DME from their joint-venture
affiliates.
The plaintiffs term their claim "coercive
reciprocity," or "the practice of using economic leverage in one market coercively to secure competitive advantage in another." Plaintiff's Opposition to Motion to Dismiss
(doc. no. 33) at 3 (citing Intergraph Corp. v. Intel Corp., 195 F.3d 1346, 1360 (Fed. Cir. 1999)). Courts have recognized that reciprocal dealing can constitute an illegal restraint of trade under § 1. Typically, reciprocal dealing involves two parties who "face each other as both buyer and seller. One party offers to buy the other party's goods, but only if the
26
second party buys other goods from the first party." Spartan Grain & Mill Co. v. Ayers, 581 F.2d 419, 424 (5th Cir. 1978).5 Reciprocal Spartan Grain dealing & Mill, is 581 not, F.2d by at itself, 423. illegal. Rather,
reciprocal-dealing arrangements illegally restrain trade only when they are coercive--that is, only when a
defendant uses its market power, or leverage, over one product to induce the purchase or sale of a second product, a transaction that would not otherwise take place in a competitive market. "In each case one side of It
a transaction has special power in the market place.
uses this power to force those with whom it deals to make concessions in another market." 581 F.2d at 425. Spartan Grain & Mill,
5. In Bonner v. Prichard, 661 F.2d 1206, 1209 (11th Cir. 1981) (en banc), the Eleventh Circuit Court of Appeals adopted as binding precedent all of the decisions of the former Fifth Circuit handed down prior to the close of business on September 30, 1981. 27
Here,
the
plaintiffs
allege
that
the
defendant
hospitals use their market power over hospital services to coerce patients into dealing exclusively with the hospitals' respective affiliated DME provider. patients who receive hospital services at That is, Jackson
Hospital are coerced into buying or renting DME from JMS, and patients who receive hospital services at Baptist hospitals are coerced into buying or renting DME from Baptist Ventures, even though those patients would buy or rent from the plaintiffs in a competitive market. As support for their argument, the plaintiffs rely on the holding in the vacated Eleventh Circuit opinion, Key Enterprise . In that case, the defendant hospital
pressured home-health-care nurses to refer patients to the hospital's DME provider. home-health-care nurses were 919 F.2d at 1561-63. not employees of The the
hospital and relied on access to patients to remain in business. The court determined that the act of the
hospital constituted coercive reciprocity as it involved
28
a
buyer
(the
hospital)
conditioning
the
purchase
of
services from the sellers (home-health-care nurses) on the sellers' marketing of the buyers' service. Here, the plaintiffs argue that the defendants
"coerce, pressure, or otherwise unduly influence the patients, doctors, nursing homes and home health care agents to select or recommend only the captive DME
companies to the exclusion of Plaintiffs."
Plaintiff's The only
First Amended Complaint, at ¶ 37 (doc. no. 21).
factual allegation that the plaintiffs make to support this conclusory statement is that the hospitals have instructed "case workers and staff to steer patients to the captive DME companies." allegation reciprocity is not Id. at ¶ 24. to support 550 This factual a coerciveat 570
sufficient See
claim.
Twombly,
U.S.
(requiring at the pleading stage factual allegations that plausibly suggest a violation of the antitrust laws). Unlike the independent home-health-care nurses in Key Enterprise who felt that their access to the hospital was
29
conditioned on patient referrals to the DME provider, the plaintiffs in this case make no allegations that the hospitals similarly coerced hospital staff or case
workers into referring the hospital's DME providers to patients; in particular, there is no allegation that the hospital staff's continued employment, pay, or benefits at the hospital or access to the hospital were in any way conditioned on them referring patients to their
hospital's DME providers.
Moreover and perhaps most
importantly, there is nothing the complaint to suggest that the hospitals and their staff otherwise had a buyerseller or other comparable commercial relationship. See
Spartan Grain & Mill, 581 F.2d at 423 ("A reciprocal dealing arrangement exists when two parties face each other as both buyer and seller."). In the absence of any
such factual allegations in the complaint of coercion arising out of a buyer-seller relationship or something comparable, the plaintiffs' coercive-reciprocity claim
30
fails to state a claim upon which relief can be granted. See Fed. R. Civ. P. 12(b)(6).
2.
Concerted Refusal to Deal Count II of the amended complaint alleges that the
defendants have acted in concert in refusing to deal with the plaintiffs by failing to provide access to the
discharged patients in violation of § 1 of the Sherman Act. The plaintiffs in their brief opposing the
dismissal motion have clarified that it is the concerted actions of the hospitals and their respective captive DME providers that is at issue; they do not allege that the four hospitals engaged in any illegal concerted actions among themselves. The plaintiffs have made sufficient allegations of agreements between the three hospitals and their captive DME provider to state a claim that they were acting in concert. However, the more difficult question is whether the allegation in the complaint that the hospitals and
31
captive DME providers refused to deal with the plaintiffs states a claim under § 1 of the Sherman Act for which relief can be granted. not. The plaintiffs allege that the hospitals unilaterally ceased the DME rotational assignment that existed prior to the entry into the market of their DME providers. In This court concludes that it does
addition, the plaintiffs allege that, since the hospitals entered into the joint ventures, they have refused to provide the plaintiffs with access to the hospitals so that they can market their DME. that these acts constituted a The plaintiffs contend refusal to deal in
violation of the Sherman Act. The plaintiffs rely on two Supreme Court cases to support their refusal-to-deal claim. In Lorain Journal
Co. v. United States, 342 U.S. 143 (1951), the Court held that a newspaper publisher that enjoyed a substantial monopoly in the in mass dissemination Ohio, engaged of in news and
advertising
Lorain,
unlawful
32
exclusionary conduct when it refused to accept any local advertisements from any entity that advertised on a radio station run by the Elyria-Lorain Broadcasting Company. As a result, numerous advertisers refrained from
advertising on the radio. newspaper publisher's
The Court explained that the "not only reduced the
actions
number of customers available to [the radio station] in the field of local Lorain advertising and strengthened the Journal's monopoly in that field, but more
significantly tended to destroy and eliminate [the radio station] altogether." Id. at 149.
The newspaper publisher argued that it had a right "to select its customers and to refuse to accept
advertisement from whomever it pleases." The Court agreed that that there was was not such a
Id. at 155. right, but In
explained
the
right
unqualified.
particular, the Court explained that the publisher could not exercise that right in a manner contrary to the
33
Sherman Act.
Id.
The Court therefore held that the
publisher's action violated the Sherman Act. In the second case cited by the plaintiffs, Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 U.S. 585 (1985), the Court added greater In specificity Skiing, to two the ski
refusal-to-deal
standard.
Aspen
companies, Ski Co. (which operated three ski mountains) and Highland (which operated a fourth ski mountain), offered an all-Aspen ski ticket, in which customers could ski on any of the four mountains. The revenues from
sales were divided between the companies based on usage of the mountains. This arrangement lasted for 15 years,
when Ski Co. proposed a fixed-revenue-sharing arrangement that it knew Highland would not accept. Highland rejected the offer. As expected,
Ski Co. discontinued the
all-Aspen ski ticket and instead offered ski tickets limited to the three mountains that it operated. In addition to the discontinuance of the all-Aspen ski ticket, Ski Co. also refused to sell any lift tickets
34
to Highland either at the tour operator's discount or at retail. Id. at 593. Highlands then developed the
"Adventure Pack," which consisted of a three-day ski pass at Highlands and three vouchers equal to the price of a daily lift ticket at a Ski Co. mountain. to accept the vouchers. Ski Co. refused
Unable to offer a package that
included access to the Ski Co. mountains, Highlands' share of the market for downhill skiing services declined dramatically. The Court reiterated that "[t]he high value that we have placed on the right to refuse to deal with other firms does not mean that the right is unqualified." at 601. Id.
A firm's refusal to deal is unlawful "[i]f [it]
has been attempting to exclude rivals on some basis other than efficiency." omitted). Id. at 605 (internal quotation marks
The Court identified two indicators that Ski
Co. was attempting to exclude rivals on a basis other than efficiency. First, Ski Co. "elected to make an
important change in a pattern of distribution that had
35
originated in a competitive market and had persisted for several years." Id. at 603. Such a change was contrary
to consumer demand, as "skiers demonstrably preferred four mountains to three." decided to forgo daily Id. at 606. ticket sales Second, Ski Co. from vouchers
obtained by Skiers contained in Highlands' Adventure Pack. "Ski From this conduct, it was proper to infer that Co. elected to forgo these short-run benefits
because it was more interested in reducing competition in the Aspen market over the long run by harming its smaller competitors." Id. at 608.
In the present case, the plaintiffs, relying on the reasoning in Aspen Skiing, argue that the defendants can point to no increased efficiency resulting from refusing to deal with the plaintiffs. However, the plaintiffs
ignore the subsequent modification of the refusal-to-deal standard in Verizon Communications, Inc. v. Trinko, 540 U.S. 398 (2004), where the Court broadened the right of firms to refuse to deal with rivals.
36
In Trinko, the Court explained that "[c]ompelling ... firms to share the source of their advantage is in some tension with the underlying purpose of antitrust law, since it may lessen the incentive for the monopolist, the rival, or both to invest in those economically The Court was
beneficially activities."
Id. at 407-08.
concerned about the fact that "[e]nforced sharing also requires antitrust courts to act as central planners, identifying the proper price, quantity, and other terms of dealing--a role for which they are ill suited." at 408. Id.
Therefore, the Court held that, "as a general
matter, the Sherman Act does not restrict the longrecognized right of a trader or manufacturer engaged in an entirely private business, freely to exercise his own independent discretion as to parties with whom it will deal." omitted). Id. (citation and internal quotation marks
The Court explained that only under certain will a refusal to deal with rivals
circumstances
constitute an antitrust violation under the Sherman Act.
37
The Court identified Aspen Skiing as being "at or near the outer boundary of [antitrust] liability." at 409. Id.
This Aspen Skiing exception applies only if:
"(a) the defendant engaged in a prior course of dealing with its rival; and (b) the unilateral termination of a voluntary (and thus presumably profitable) course of dealing suggested a willingness to forsake short-term profits to achieve an anticompetitive end." Id.
(emphasis added). In the present case, there allegedly was a prior course of dealing between the plaintiffs and defendant hospitals as demonstrated by the rotational system.
However, the unilateral termination of a voluntary course of dealing by the hospitals in this case does not suggest a willingness to forsake short-term profits. The
hospitals terminated the course of dealing after entering into a joint venture with their respective DME providers, and there is nothing in the plaintiffs' complaint,
outside of conclusory allegations, plausibly suggesting
38
that the decision to cease the rotational system and exclude competitor DME providers from access to the
hospital was for any purpose other than increasing both the short-term and long-term profits of their DME
providers.
This case is thus distinguishable from Aspen
Skiing in which Ski Co. decided to forgo short-term profits in the form of redeeamable vouchers provided by its competitor. In light of the clear direction from the Supreme Court not to extend the refusal-to-deal exception beyond Aspen Skiing, the plaintiffs' concerted-refusal-to-deal claim fails to state a claim upon which relief can be granted. See Fed. R. Civ. P. 12(b)(6).
C.
Sherman Act § 2
The plaintiffs assert four claims under § 2 of the Sherman Act. Under § 2, it is unlawful to "monopolize,
or attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire with any other person or persons, to monopolize any part of the
39
trade or commerce among the several States." § 2.
15 U.S.C.
Section 2 "covers behavior by a single business as
well as coordinated action taken by several businesses." Spanish Broad. Sys. of Florida, Inc. v. Clear Channel Communications, Inc., 376 F.3d 1065, 1074 (11th Cir. 2004). A violation of § 2 "requires harm to competition
that must occur within a relevant ... market, with a specific set of geographical boundaries and a narrow delineation of the products at issue." Id. Therefore,
this court must first identify the relevant market in this case.
1.
Relevant Market A relevant market consists of both a product market
and a geographic market.
Brown Shoe Co. v. United The parties agree that and Prattville,
States, 370 U.S. 294, 324 (1962). the geographic market is
Montgomery
Alabama.
The dispute concerns the definition of the
product market.
40
"The
outer
boundaries
of
a
product
market
are
determined by the reasonable interchangeability of use or the cross-elasticity of demand between the product itself and substitutes for it." T. Harris Young & Assocs., Inc.
v. Marquette Elecs., Inc., 931 F.2d 816, 824 (11th Cir. 1991). Within broader product markets, "well-defined
submarkets may exist which, in themselves constitute product markets for antitrust purposes." Id. The
boundaries of a submarket are determined by "examining such practical indicia as industry or public recognition of the submarket as a separate economic entity, the product's production peculiar characteristics distinct and uses, unique
facilities,
customers,
distinct
prices, sensitivity to price changes, and specialized vendors." The Id. plaintiffs allege that the relevant product
market in this case includes two submarkets that consist of the sale and rental of DME for patients discharged from Jackson Hospital and the Baptist Health hospitals,
41
respectively. plaintiffs'
The definition
defendants of the
contend relevant
that market
the is
implausible and the market should instead be understood more broadly to consist of the sale and rental of DME to all outlets in the geographic market. Based on an examination of the practical indicia for determining a relevant market, the court finds that the plaintiffs have identified the relevant product submarket as the rental and sale of DME in hospitals. However, the
plaintiffs' argument that the submarket is disaggregated as between the two sets of hospitals, such that two product submarkets exist within the one geographic
market, lacks merit. The complaint alleges that the market is bounded by a distinct method of distribution to a distinct segment of customers. In particular, it is a method of
distribution whereby hospital patients are prescribed DME while in the hospital, and those DME needs are arranged through staff at the hospital.
42
Several courts have found a method of distribution to be a relevant submarket for antitrust purposes. See
e.g., Henry v. Chloride, 809 F.2d 1334, 1342 (8th Cir. 1087) (batteries sold by route salespersons are a
distinct submarket from batteries sold from warehouses or stores); Greyhound Computer Corp., Inc. v. Int'l Bus. Mach. Corp., 559 F.2d 488, 494 (9th Cir. 1977) (lease of computers a distinct submarket from the sale of
computers); Columbia Broad. Sys., Inc. v. F.T.C., 414 F.2d 974, 979 (7th Cir. 1969) (records sold through record clubs are a distinct submarket); F.T.C. v.
Staples, Inc., 970 F.Supp. 1066, 1080 (D.D.C. 1997) (sale of consumable a office supplies through from office the supply of
superstores consumable Eastern
distinct
submarket
sale
office
supplies v.
through Masel
other Co.,
outlets); Inc., 502
Dental
Corp.
Isaac
F.Supp. 1354, 1361 (E.D. Pa. 1980) (sale of facebows wholesale retail). a distinct market from sale of facebows
43
This court finds this case law persuasive and finds that the method of distribution of DME to hospital
patients is the relevant product submarket for antitrust purposes. The indicia that the sale and rental of DME in
hospitals constitute a relevant submarket include the plaintiffs' allegations that there is industry
recognition that the sale and rental of DME to hospitals is a distinct market. providers service a In addition, the hospital DME distinct class of discharged
patients, and there is allegedly less sensitivity of consumer demand to changes in the price or quality of the DME to discharged patients in hospitals. However, the court cannot agree with the plaintiffs' suggestion that the sale and rental of DME in the two sets of hospitals represent two separate and distinct submarkets. submarket by The plaintiffs seek not only to define the the method of distribution, which as
described above is recognized in the case law, but also on the basis of the position or location of the
44
consumers.
In particular, they argue that the two sets
of hospitals constitute two separate submarkets because the hospitals that have are two separate to sets two of discharged DME
patients providers.
referred
different
This court has not found any cases in which
the relevant product market is defined on the basis of the position or location of consumers. The one case cited by plaintiffs is inapposite. The
Ninth Circuit Court of Appeals in Greyhound Computer Corp. held that the leasing of computers constitutes a distinct submarket of separate from other methods sale of of
distribution computers.
computers,
including
the
559 F.2d at 494.
The court did address
whether leases and sales served different customer needs; however, this was in the context of an examination of one of the indicia for determining the existence of a leasing submarket. The court ultimately defined the submarket in
terms of the leasing method of distribution, not in terms
45
of the class or group of consumers to whom computers were leased. The only case that this court has been able to find that is somewhat analogous holds that submarkets cannot be defined in terms of the location or position of the consumers. In Rohlfing v. Manor Care, Inc., 172 F.R.D.
330 (N.D. Ill. 1997), the plaintiffs alleged that the relevant market consisted of "the sale of pharmaceutical products to residents Id. at 345. of Manor Care nursing home
facilities."
The court explained that "it
is improper to define a market simply by identifying a group of customers who have purchased a given product; rather the market consists of the those array of
`interchangeable'
products
that
consumers
confronted when making their product selection, plus those products which could quickly be supplied as
interchangeable alternatives." Id. The court recognized that it was particularly inappropriate to define the market on the basis of a particular set of consumers in
46
that case because Manor Care residents who are unhappy with the pharmaceutical service supplied by their nursing home could simply transfer to a different nursing home that does not utilize that service. This court finds the Id. at 346. in Rohlfing
reasoning
persuasive.
It is inappropriate to define the product
submarket on the basis of a particular set of patients because the market is defined by the interchangeability of the use of the product itself, not the users of the product. Patients in hospitals are in a sense a captured
audience; nonetheless, if they are dissatisfied with the DME supplied by their hospital, they could either express their preference for an alternative DME provider to the hospital staff or transfer to another hospital that does not utilize that DME provider. This ability of hospital
patients to access DME from other sources demonstrates that the relevant market, at the very least, includes both of the DME providers that are involved in joint ventures with the respective sets of hospitals.
47
In sum, this court concludes that the relevant market for purposes of determining whether defendants have
violated § 2 of the Sherman Act is the distribution of DME through hospitals in Montgomery and Prattville,
Alabama.
2.
Shared Monopoly On the basis of this definition of the relevant
market, the court concludes that the plaintiffs' four asserted claims under § 2 of the Sherman Act should be dismissed. As discussed above, in order to prove a
violation of § 2 of the Sherman Act, the plaintiffs must demonstrate entities activity. either in that a single entity in or multiple
acting
concert
engaged
monopolizing
The plaintiffs have not alleged a violation of
§ 2 by a "single hospital" or concerted activity by the two hospital distributors of DME. The relevant of market DME, consists of two and hospital Baptist
distributors
Jackson
Med-South
48
Ventures-American Home Patient.6
Plaintiffs have not
alleged any agreement or concerted activity between the two distributors. The only allegation is that of
parallel conduct derived from the fact that the hospitals entered into the joint ventures with their respective DME providers during the same broadly defined time period (the late 1990s). The Supreme Court has clearly held,
that, "[w]hile a showing of parallel business behavior is admissible circumstantial evidence from which the fact finder may infer agreement, it falls short of
6. Because there are two hospital distributors in the relevant market, this case is distinguishable from the cases relied upon by that plaintiffs that involved claims of monopolization of DME markets under § 2 of the Sherman Act. In Key Enterprise, the claim of monopolization was brought against a single hospital, with monopoly power in the relevant market, and its affiliated DME supplier. 919 F.2d at 1552. In Advanced Health-Care Services, the claim of monopolization was brought against three separate hospitals and their affiliated DME suppliers in three different geographic markets in which the hospitals had monopoly power. 910 F.2d at 141-43. Finally, in M&M Medical Supplies and Services, Inc., v. Pleasant Valley Hospital, Inc., the claim of monopolization was brought against a single hospital, with monopoly power in the relevant market, and its affiliated DME supplier. 981 F.2d 160, 162 (4th Cir. 1993). 49
conclusively
establishing
agreement
or
itself
constituting a Sherman Act offense."
"While a showing of
parallel `business behavior is admissible circumstantial evidence from which the fact finder may infer agreement,' it falls short of `conclusively establish[ing] agreement or ... itself constitut[ing] a Sherman Act offense.'" Twombly, 550 U.S. at 553 (quoting Theatre Enterprises, Inc. v. Paramount Film Distributing Corp., 346 U.S. 537, 540-41 (1954)). Allegations of parallel conduct, without more, are not sufficient to survive a motion to dismiss. Twombly, 550 U.S. at 556-57. The complaint vaguely alleges that defendants have engaged in a series of unlawful and wrongful activities and communications that constitute monopolization,
attempted monopolization, and conspiracy to monopolize. In the absence of any allegations of concerted activity between the hospitals' two DME providers, the only theory that could possibly support these claims would be one based on shared monopoly.
50
Under a theory of shared monopoly, "a group of firms that collectively possess monopoly power can be found liable for joint monopolization." ABA Section of
Antitrust Law, Antitrust Law Developments (5th ed. 2002), at 312. The former Fifth Circuit Court of Appeals,
consistent with other courts that have addressed the issue, has rejected any claim of violation of § 2 of the Sherman Act predicated on a theory of shared monopoly. See American Tel. and Tel. Co. v. Delta Communications Corp., 579 F.2d 972 (5th Cir. 1978), adopting opinion, 408 F.Supp. 1075 (S.D. Miss. 1976) (rejecting a claim that networks constituting an oligopoly can violate § 2 of the Sherman Act and explaining that "[t]he Sherman Act neither mentions nor regulates oligopolies.");7 see also Kramer v. Pollock-Krasner Foundation, 890 F.Supp. 250, 256 (S.D.N.Y. 1995) (rejecting a shared monopoly claim and explaining that "the offense of monopolization under Section 2 refers to market dominance by a `single
7.
See supra note 5. 51
firm.'"); Sun Dun, Inc. v. Coca-Cola Co., 740 F.Supp. 381, 391 (D. Md. 1990) ("An examination of the history of the Sherman Act did reveals not that Congress' concept of or
`monopoly'
include
`shared
monopolies'
`oligopolies' at all, but rather the complete domination of a market by a single economic entity."); H.L. Hayden Co. v. Siemens Medical Systems, Inc., 672 F.Supp. 724, 741 (S.D.N.Y. 1987) ("Two competitors could conspire to oligopolize ... but it would not constitute an offense under a literal reading of section 2 [of the Sherman Act]."); Consolidated Terminal Systems, Inc. v. ITT World Communications, Inc., 535 F.Supp. 225, 228-29 (S.D.N.Y. 1982) ("An oligopoly or a shared monopoly, does not in itself violate § 2 of the Sherman Act."). Not only must the monopolization and attempted
monopolization claim fail as a result of this court's rejection of a theory of shared monopoly, but so must any claim of conspiracy to monopolize. The court in Sun Dun,
52
addressing a conspiracy to monopolize claim in a similar context, persuasively held that "[w]hen ... two or more competitors conspire to create a market environment in which competition and market entry is improperly restricted, but in which market power continues to be shared among these otherwise unrelated entities, ... there is no conspiracy to monopolize claim stated under Section 2, and the claim must therefore be dismissed." 740 F.Supp. at 392. In other words, a conspiracy to
monopolize claim requires either actions by a single firm or concerted activity by multiple firms. been alleged in the complaint. In sum, the plaintiffs' Count Count Count V VI IV Count claim of of III of claim of Neither has
monopolization, monopolization, monopolize, and
attempted to to
claim claim
conspiracy conspiracy
monopolize based on the so-called essential facility doctrine all fail to state a claim upon which relief can be granted. See Fed. R. Civ. P. 12(b)(6). Each of these
claims requires either allegations of concerted activity 53
or sufficient monopoly power by a single firm that are not set forth in the complaint.
IV.
STATE CLAIMS
In Count VII, the plaintiffs assert violations of Alabama Antitrust Law. They state that their state
claims and their governing law are the same as their federal claims and their governing law. See Ex parte
Rice, 67 So.2d 825, 829 (1953) (per curiam) ("The federal statutes ... prescribe the terms of unlawful monopolies and restraints of trade as they should also be
administered in Alabama."); see also Avery Freight Lines, Inc. v. Alabama Pub. Serv. Comm'n, 104 So.2d 705, 709 (1958) ("In construing the terms and provisions of
Alabama statutes derived from federal statutes, such terms and provisions will usually be considered as having the meaning given by the federal courts."). Therefore,
the plaintiffs' state claims fail for the same reasons that their federal ones do.
54
V. CONCLUSION For the foregoing reasons, the defendants' motion to dismiss will be granted on the plaintiffs' federal and state claims. An appropriate judgment will be entered. DONE, this the 8th day of March, 2010. /s/ Myron H. Thompson UNITED STATES DISTRICT JUDGE
Disclaimer: Justia Dockets & Filings provides public litigation records from the federal appellate and district courts. These filings and docket sheets should not be considered findings of fact or liability, nor do they necessarily reflect the view of Justia.
Why Is My Information Online?