OneBeacon Insurance Company v. Plant Insulation Company

Filing 76

ORDER DENYING APPEAL FROM CONFIRMATION OF REVISED PLAN OF REORGANIZATION. Signed by Judge Richard Seeborg on 8/18/14. (cl, COURT STAFF) (Filed on 8/18/2014)

Download PDF
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT 8 FOR THE NORTHERN DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA 9 SAN FRANCISCO DIVISION 11 For the Northern District of California United States District Court 10 12 15 16 ORDER DENYING APPEAL FROM CONFIRMATION OF REVSIED PLAN OF REORGANIZATION Appellants, v. 13 14 No. C 14-01200 RS ONEBEACON INSURANCE COMPANY, et al., PLANT INSULATION CO., et al., Appellees. ____________________________________/ 17 I. 18 INTRODUCTION 19 This appeal marks the latest chapter in the reorganization of Plant Insulation Company, a 20 Chapter 11 debtor formerly involved in the sale, installation, repair, and distribution of products 21 containing asbestos. The Ninth Circuit rejected Plant’s prior reorganization plan (the “Original 22 Plan”), holding the plan failed to comply with 11 U.S.C. § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III), a Bankruptcy Code 23 provision that seeks to ensure a reorganized debtor’s future operations are controlled by an asbestos 24 trust formed under § 524(g). The Plan Proponents then formulated and lodged an amended plan (the 25 “Revised Plan”), which was subsequently confirmed by the bankruptcy court.1 A contingent of 26 27 28 1 The Plan Proponents consist of Plant, the Official Committee of Unsecured Creditors, and the Futures Representative. 1 Plant’s insurers lodged this appeal of the confirmation order, arguing the Revised Plan still violates 2 § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III). For the following reasons, the appeal is denied. II. 3 BACKGROUND The factual background of Plant’s bankruptcy and Bayside’s formation is set out in the prior 4 5 order confirming the Original Plan. See In re Plant Insulation Co., 485 B.R. 203 (N.D. Cal. 2012) 6 (“Plant II”) aff’d, 544 F. App’x 669 (9th Cir. 2013) and rev’d, 734 F.3d 900 (9th Cir. 2013) cert. 7 denied, 134 S. Ct. 1901 (U.S. 2014). That history need not be repeated here. 8 A. Plan Mechanics 9 Before addressing the new features of the Revised Plan, which is substantially similar to the Original Plan, a general summary of the Plans’ structure is warranted.2 The Plan provides two 11 For the Northern District of California United States District Court 10 avenues for compensating existing and future asbestos injury claimants: (1) from a trust established 12 under § 524(g) (“the Trust”), and (2) by preserving claimants’ right to file tort actions against Plant 13 and insurers that refuse to settle such claims (the “Non-Settling Insurers”) by making cash 14 contributions to the Trust. The § 524(g) injunction operates to create strong incentives for Plant’s 15 remaining insurers to settle their potential liabilities by making cash contributions to the Trust, or 16 else continue to defend asbestos injury claims without any possibility of receiving reimbursement 17 from Plant if its underlying liability policies are ultimately determined to be exhausted. In exchange 18 for such settlement payments, the injunction completely releases so-called Settling Insurers from all 19 claims brought by all parties, including tort claims asserted by asbestos injury claimants, and claims 20 for equitable contribution that might otherwise be brought by Non-Settling Insurers. The Plan further provides partial payment for general unsecured creditors, including 21 22 insurers’ claims for reimbursement, by setting aside ten percent of all available funds (e.g., 23 insurance settlement proceeds) to the Unsecured Claims Reserve. All other available cash proceeds 24 are transferred to the Trust for reimbursement to asbestos injury claimants. Distributions to those 25 claimants will be made according to established “Trust Distribution Procedures,” which enable the 26 Trust’s administrators to determine the amount of compensable damages for each claimant as well 27 28 2 Absent specific mention of the Original Plan or the Revised Plan, any general reference in this order to “the Plan” is intended to describe both versions. 2 1 as the proportion of the Trust’s funds that may be paid out to each claimant without depleting 2 payments to future claimants. 3 Alternatively, under the Plan, asbestos injury claimants retain their right to pursue Plant and 4 Non-Settling Insurers by filing a tort action, subject to several conditions. First, a determination by 5 the Trust as to the validity or sum of compensable claims cannot provide a basis for liability in the 6 courts. Second, if a claimant obtains a judgment against Plant, he or she may file suit (or Direct 7 Action) against the Non-Settling Insurers to determine whether the claim is covered by insurance. 8 Claimants are enjoined from enforcing any such judgment against the Settling Insurers, 9 (reorganized) Bayside, or the officers, directors, or shareholders of either Plant or Bayside. In addition, any such judgment against a Non-Settling Insurer obtained by an asbestos injury claimant 11 For the Northern District of California United States District Court 10 must be reduced by the amount previously recovered by the claimant from the Trust. By the same 12 token, a claimant who is fully compensated in such a Direct Action against a Non-Settling Insurer 13 may not seek to recover from the Fund. Finally, a claimant may not proceed with a Direct Action 14 unless he or she agrees in writing that the Non-Settling Insurer may offset from any recovery 15 otherwise available in a final judgment, the amount of equitable contributions (including for defense 16 costs) that would be available to the Non-Settling Insurer from other Settling Insurers, collection of 17 which is enjoined under the Plan. The foregoing deductions to Direct Action judgments are only 18 applicable if the Action goes to trial and leads to a final judgment. In other words, those deductions 19 are not available to the Non-Settling Insurers in asbestos-related cases that are dismissed without 20 any payment to the claimant or settled before judgment. 21 The Plan also requires the merger of Plant and Bayside, under the latter’s name. As part of 22 that transaction, the Trust will invest $2 million in the reorganized Bayside and receive 40 percent 23 of the common stock of the company in exchange, as well as a warrant to purchase an additional 11 24 percent of shares (thus totaling 51 percent of voting shares). Reorganized Bayside is to assume 25 Plant’s responsibilities to its insurers under the latter’s liability policies, post-merger. 26 B. The Ninth Circuit Opinion 27 A contingent of Non-Settling Insurers appealed this court’s order affirming the Original 28 Plan, challenging various of its aspects as violating the U.S. Constitution, the Bankruptcy Code, California law, and rules of equity. While rejecting most of the Insurers’ arguments, the Ninth 3 1 Circuit concluded that the Original Plan had one fatal flaw: it failed to comply with § 2 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III), which specifies that the trust must “own, or by the exercise of rights granted 3 under such plan would be entitled to own if specified contingencies occur, a majority of the voting 4 shares” of the reorganized debtor. The parties refer to this provision as the “control requirement.” 5 The Original Plan provided that the Trust could gain 51% ownership of Bayside in two of the shares of Bayside, bringing its ownership to 51%. Importantly, the warrant was tied to the 8 pro rata share price of the Trust’s initial $2 million investment in 40% of the company. 9 Accordingly, to exercise its warrant under the Original Plan, the Trust would have been required to 10 pay an additional $1,122,559. Second, the Original Plan required Bayside to provide the Trust with 11 For the Northern District of California different ways. First, the Trust could invoke its outstanding warrant to purchase an additional 11% 7 United States District Court 6 a $250,000 promissory note secured by additional shares in the company. If Bayside defaulted on 12 the note, the Trust would receive enough additional shares to bring the Trust into majority 13 ownership of the company. 14 The parties disputed whether either contingency satisfied the requirement that the Trust be 15 entitled to own, “if specified contingencies occur,” a majority of the voting shares of Bayside. See 16 11 § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III). Because the statute does not explicitly limit the sort or nature of the 17 contingencies that would satisfy the control requirement, the prior confirmation order concluded that 18 any contingency suffices, so long as some circumstances are provided in the plan that would, 19 through the exercise of rights granted therein, allow the trust to gain majority control of the 20 reorganized debtor. See Plant II, 485 B.R. at 226-27. The Ninth Circuit disagreed, finding that such 21 an interpretation would allow for scenarios where the trust would retain merely an illusory form of 22 prospective “control” of the reorganized debtor: 23 24 If “specified contingencies” could include any contingency—such as a meteor hitting the Empire State Building—then the subsection has no content because the plan drafters could write it out of existence at will. 25 In re Plant Insulation Co., 734 F.3d 900, 915 (9th Cir. 2013) (“Plant III”) cert. denied, 134 S. Ct. 26 1901 (U.S. 2014). 27 28 The Ninth Circuit’s interpretation of the control requirement grew out of several observations about § 524(g)’s text, design, and history. First, the court emphasized that the language of § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III) uses the “key phrase ‘voting shares.’” Id. “This is significant,” 4 1 the court noted, “because it signals that this section is about control over the reorganized debtor’s 2 future operations.” Id. The court also found support in the design of § 524(g) as a whole: 7 [T]he design of § 524(g) reveals that this subsection is a key piece governing the relationship of the trust to the reorganized debtor. It is one of only four requirements that § 524(g) places on the trust. The other three require the trust: (1) to assume the liabilities of the debtor for asbestos actions; (2) to be at least partially funded by equity in the debtor; and (3) to use trust assets or income to pay asbestos claimants. Read together, these requirements are part of a scheme that ensures that, after the bankruptcy, the trust stands in for the debtor with regard to asbestos claims and the debtor continues to operate its business for the benefit of the trust. 8 Id. at 916. This design is “thwarted,” the court concluded, “if a plan can make control of the debtor 9 effectively impossible.” Id. 3 4 5 6 The court’s reading of § 524(g) was also informed by the statute’s history. Enacted in 1994, 11 For the Northern District of California United States District Court 10 § 524(g) was modeled after the approach taken in the “celebrated” Johns-Manville bankruptcy case. 12 734 F.3d at 915 (citing Kane v. Johns–Manville Corp., 843 F.2d 636 (2d Cir. 1988)). The Johns- 13 Manville “approach” refers to the realization that, “given the lengthy latency period of asbestos- 14 related diseases, companies facing asbestos risk have no way finally to resolve or even effectively 15 estimate their exposure.” 734 F.3d 905-06. If such companies collapse and liquidate, “untold 16 numbers of future claimants will be left without recovery.” Id. Meanwhile, present claimants want 17 to be paid quickly and efficiently. “The Johns–Manville approach, now codified in § 524(g), seeks 18 to use the broad equitable power of the bankruptcy court to resolve the dilemma in a way that is fair 19 for both present and future asbestos claimants.” Id. This history, the court found, “suggests that [§ 20 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III)] is not to be lightly discarded.” Id. at 916. 21 In light of the statute’s text, history, and design, the Ninth Circuit set out the following 22 standard for determining when a plan, by virtue of its “specified contingencies,” satisfies § 23 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III): 24 25 26 27 “[S]pecified contingencies” . . . refers to contingencies regulated by the bankruptcy court to ensure that control is either a realistic possibility or a backstop to trust insufficiency. The plan can still “specify” what contingencies suffice, but those contingencies cannot be “shams” that allow control facially, but not in practice. To the extent Congress has provided an exception to the general rule that the trust should control the reorganized debtor, the overarching goal—that asbestos claimants get paid to the full possible extent—informs that exception. 28 5 1 Id. at 916. Applying this framework to the Original Plan, the court concluded that neither of the 2 proposed contingencies satisfied the statute. Notably, as to the 11% warrant, the court held that “[a] 3 mere right of the plan to purchase shares ordinarily will not suffice.”3 Id. The court observed that if 4 a trust is struggling to pay claims in the first place, it cannot be expected to purchase control of the 5 reorganized debtor. “[S]uch a right leaves the trust in scarcely a better position than a third party . . . 6 . This is especially true where, as here, the price the Trust would have to pay is fixed at roughly four 7 times the current value of the equity.” Id. The court offered some contrasting examples, remarking 8 that it was “easy to imagine” what contingencies might satisfy the statute: Most straightforwardly, a contingency that promised to transfer control to the trust in the event that it proved insufficient would clearly comply with this provision. A buyout right could be satisfactory, if that right placed the trust at an advantage such that it could use that right to claim value. Either of these would be consistent with the purpose of this section: to ensure the reorganized debtor continues to operate for the benefit of asbestos claimants. 9 11 For the Northern District of California United States District Court 10 12 13 Id. at 916 n. 9. In sum, the Ninth Circuit in Plant III made clear that while a trust is not required to own a 14 15 controlling portion of the reorganized debtor, the plan must at least enable the trust to obtain and 16 exercise control in a way that “would meaningfully benefit the Trust.” Id. at 917. If a contingency 17 is illusory or burdensome, it will not ensure that the debtor continues to operate for the benefit of 18 asbestos claimants. 19 C. The Revised Plan 20 Shortly following remand, the Plan Proponents proffered an amended plan that, in their 21 view, passes muster under the Ninth Circuit’s reading of the statute. The Revised Plan makes five 22 changes regarding the Trust’s ownership of Bayside. First, the warrant exercise price is 23 significantly lower and provides actual “benefit” to the Trust. Under the Revised Plan, the Trust 24 receives a warrant entitling it to purchase 11% of Bayside (bringing the Trust’s ownership to 51%) 25 for merely $1. The Original Plan, by contrast, required the Trust shell out $1,122,559 to exercise 26 the warrant. 27 28 3 The court also found that the note-default condition failed to comply with the statute, but because that condition is not at issue in the Revised Plan, it need not be discussed further. 6 Second, the Revised Plan expressly authorizes the Trust to sell its shares to any party, 1 2 subject to the Right of First Offer described below. The Original Plan did not expressly authorize 3 the Trust to sell its shares to anyone other than Bayside or shareholders Shahram Ameli and Ali 4 Badakhshan, who also serve as Bayside’s managers. Third, the Revised Plan includes a Right of First Offer (“ROFO”) that requires the Trust 5 6 follow certain procedures prior to selling its Bayside shares. If the Trust wishes to sell any of the 7 shares, it must first offer them to Bayside, Ameli, and Badakhshan (the “ROFO holders”). If any 8 one ROFO holder agrees to purchase the shares, and if the buyer and seller cannot subsequently 9 agree on a price, the shares are to be sold at a price determined by “baseball” arbitration.4 If any ROFO holder elects to purchase the shares, the Trust is further obligated to finance the full amount 11 For the Northern District of California United States District Court 10 of the purchase price through a fully amortized five-year loan at an interest rate of 3.75%. The loan 12 must be secured by the shares purchased, and if the shares are bought by Bayside, such shares must 13 be guaranteed by Ameli and Badakhshan. Fourth, the Revised Plan provides the Trust with certain “put” rights, under which the Trust 14 15 can require Bayside to repurchase those shares held by the Trust. If this right is exercised, and if the 16 parties cannot agree on a sale price, the shares are valued via baseball arbitration as described above. 17 Fifth, the Revised Plan does away with certain “call rights” from the Original Plan that benefitted 18 Bayside and its managers. Specifically, under the Original Plan, Bayside, Ameli, and Badakhshan 19 had the right to repurchase, at a predetermined price, any Bayside shares held by the Trust. Under 20 the Revised Plan, by contrast, the Trust cannot be forced to sell its shares to Bayside, Ameli, 21 Badakhshan, or anyone else. The Proponents moved to confirm the Revised Plan. The Non-Settling Insurers objected, 22 23 asserting two primary arguments: (1) that the plan still did not satisfy the control requirement of § 24 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III) and (2) that the plan did not satisfy the “feasibility” requirement of § 25 1129(a)(11).5 After the parties conducted additional limited discovery, the bankruptcy court held a 26 27 28 4 In “baseball” arbitration, the buyer and seller each hire their own appraiser, who prepares a separate valuation report. The arbitrator then selects the report that she determines to be the more reasonable estimate of value, and adopts that value as the purchase price for the shares. See Bankruptcy Court Memorandum Re: Confirmation of Revised Plan Following Remand, No. 0931347, ECF No. 2721 (Bankr. N.D. Cal. February 24, 2014) (“Plant IV”). 5 The Insurers do not contest on appeal whether the Revised Plan is feasible under § 1129(a)(11). 7 1 two-day evidentiary hearing on the Proponents’ motion to confirm the Revised Plan. On February 2 24, 2014, the court issued findings of fact and conclusions of law overruling the objections. See 3 Plant IV. The Revised Plan was confirmed shortly thereafter. This appeal followed. 4 5 III. LEGAL STANDARD When reviewing a bankruptcy court decision, the district court “functions as an appellate Properties, Ltd., L.P., 268 F.3d 743, 755 (9th Cir. 2001). While the bankruptcy court’s conclusions 8 of law are reviewed de novo, see In re Thorpe Insulation Co., 677 F.3d 869, 879 (9th Cir. 2012), the 9 standard of review for its factual findings depend on whether the underlying proceeding is “core” or 10 “non-core.” When the bankruptcy court is engaged in a “core proceeding,” its decision is final and 11 For the Northern District of California court” and “applies the same standards of review as a federal court of appeals.” In re Crystal 7 United States District Court 6 its factual findings are reviewed for clear error. In re Harris, 590 F.3d 730, 736 (9th Cir. 2009). 12 When the bankruptcy court adjudicates a “non-core” matter, it only has the power to make 13 “proposed findings of fact and law” that a district court must review de novo. Id. at 736–37. 14 Because confirmation of a § 524(g) reorganization plan is a “core” proceeding, see Plant III, 734 15 F.3d at 908, the bankruptcy court’s findings of fact are reviewed for clear error. 16 17 IV. DISCUSSION Focusing on a single provision of the Bankruptcy Code, this appeal argues that the Revised 18 Plan still does not satisfy the statute’s requirement that the trust “own, or by the exercise of rights 19 granted under such plan would be entitled to own if specified contingencies occur, a majority of the 20 voting shares” of the reorganized debtor. See 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III). Appellants contend the Revised 21 Plan runs afoul of this requirement in two respects. First, it requires the Trust to make a costly 22 initial investment in Bayside. In light of that investment, Appellants argue, the actual cost of control 23 is extremely high. In Appellants’ view, the Revised Plan cannot place any price on majority 24 ownership, much less one that far exceeds the value of the underlying equity. Second, Appellants 25 argue the ROFO prevents the Trust from selling its shares in Bayside “for appropriate value,” and 26 makes it “most likely” that Bayside or its principals will repurchase the stock on advantageous terms 27 if the Trust, having exercised the warrant, chooses to sell the stock. (App. at 7:11). 28 8 1 A. Invoking the Warrant to Take Control 2 Appellants’ first argument focuses on framing: what does it really “cost” the Trust to obtain 3 control of Bayside, and does such cost preclude the Revised Plan from satisfying the control 4 requirement? Under the Revised Plan, the Trust can exercise its 11% warrant for a mere $1— 5 thereby all but erasing the $1,122,559 required by the Original Plan. In Appellants’ view, though, it 6 is pointless to view the warrant price in isolation. Instead, they urge, the court must consider the 7 “true” price of majority ownership: $2,000,001, which accounts for the Trust’s initial investment 8 ($2,000,000 for 40% equity) and its warrant ($1 for an additional 11%). If the cost of majority 9 ownership is framed accordingly, there is no dispute that the Trust must pay an over-market price to acquire eventual control of Bayside.6 The Plan Proponents, however, see it differently. In their 11 For the Northern District of California United States District Court 10 view, for purposes of assessing whether the control requirement has been satisfied, it is irrelevant 12 what the Trust paid for its first 40% of Bayside. Before addressing the merits of Appellant’s first argument, a brief detour is warranted to 13 14 explain how the Ninth Circuit in Plant III addressed a different provision of § 524(g). In their 15 challenge to the Original Plan, the Insurers argued that by requiring the Trust to pay $2 million for 16 40% of Bayside, the Plan failed to satisfy § 524(g)’s requirement that the trust be “funded in whole 17 or in part” by the securities of the reorganized debtor. See § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(II). Appellants had 18 argued that by removing $2,000,000 in cash from the Trust in exchange for $500,000 worth of 19 equity, the Trust is actually “de-funded” by Bayside. The Ninth Circuit disagreed. While the court 20 acknowledged the Trust paid more than market value for the shares acquired at confirmation, it held 21 that it was not necessary under the statute’s funding requirement that the Trust receive any net value 22 from the debtor through that transfer. See 734 F.3d at 914 (“[A]ll that this particular subsection 23 must accomplish is to ensure that the Trust receives a stake, of some value, in the reorganized 24 debtor.”). The court further rejected Appellants’ suggestion that the bankruptcy court be required to 25 conduct an inquiry focused on whether the Trust obtained a “fair deal” in the transaction to acquire 26 those securities, finding that such a requirement could be found elsewhere in the statute, like the 27 requirements of good faith (11 U.S.C. § 1129(a)(3)) or the requirement that the court ensure the 28 6 In its prior order confirming the Original Plan, the bankruptcy court concluded that 40% equity in Bayside was worth approximately $500,000. 9 1 injunction is “fair and equitable” (11 U.S.C. § 524(g)(4)(B)(ii)). Id. The court further noted that, 2 “as the bankruptcy court recognized, the Trust is getting a valuable asset from the debtor that dwarfs 3 anything Bayside could provide—over one hundred million dollars in insurance settlement 4 proceeds.” Id. at 914-915. In the present appeal, the Insurers object to the investment requirement on different statutory 5 6 grounds, arguing the overall price of $2,000,001 cannot possibly satisfy the Ninth Circuit’s 7 interpretation of the control requirement found in § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III). In Appellants’ view, the 8 Ninth Circuit made clear that “the Trust should not be required to purchase this control; control is a 9 statutory right.” (App. at 17:7-8) (emphasis in original). Such a reading, however, is not consistent with the language of the Bankruptcy Code. While there is a “general rule” that the asbestos trust 11 For the Northern District of California United States District Court 10 control the reorganized debtor, a plan can still pass muster under the statute if it contains 12 “contingencies regulated by the bankruptcy court to ensure that control [of the debtor] is either a 13 realistic possibility or a backstop to trust insufficiency.” 734 F.3d at 916; 11 U.S.C. § 14 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III). As the bankruptcy court observed, these “specified contingencies” only come 15 into play when the trust does not acquire a majority of the debtor’s voting shares upon confirmation. 16 Because the trust is always required to own some securities of the debtor upon confirmation, see 734 17 F.3d at 914 (the “funding” requirement found in § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(II) ensures “that the Trust 18 receives a stake, of some value, in the reorganized debtor”), the phrase “specified contingencies” 19 plainly cannot refer to the terms upon which the trust acquired those shares in the first place.7 20 Rather, as the contingency model is an “exception” to the general rule of outright control upon 21 confirmation, see id. at 916, “specified contingencies” must refer to the terms upon which the trust 22 has the right to acquire additional shares after confirmation. Accordingly, the bankruptcy court was 23 correct to conclude that under the plain meaning of the statute, the specified contingency in the 24 Revised Plan is the payment of $1. 25 Specified contingencies “cannot be ‘shams’ that allow control facially, but not in practice.” 26 Id. Unlike the Original Plan, which required the Trust to exercise a $1,122,559 warrant in order to 27 28 7 As the Ninth Circuit pointed out in its discussion of the funding requirement, there are other statutory mechanisms for ensuring the fairness of a plan requiring that the trust invest in the reorganized debtor. See 734 F.3d at 914. In so doing, the court did not mention § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III). 10 1 secure control of Bayside, there is no question that the Revised Plan allows control both facially and 2 “in practice.” See id. Although “[a] mere right of the plan to purchase shares ordinarily will not 3 suffice,” the proposed plan no longer creates a situation where the warrant “leaves the trust in 4 scarcely a better position than a third party.” See id. Indeed, the opposite is true. Whereas the 5 Original Plan required the Trust to pay an over-market price to exercise the warrant, the Revised 6 Plan places the Trust in a much better position than a third party seeking to acquire some portion of 7 the debtor. Indeed, it is difficult to imagine a scenario where, by exercise of some right granted 8 under the plan, it would be easier for the Trust to acquire post-confirmation control of Bayside.8 The $1 warrant satisfies the statute. By providing a specified contingency under which the 9 Trust can take post-confirmation control of Bayside for a nominal sum, the Revised Plan ensures 11 For the Northern District of California United States District Court 10 that control is far from illusory. Indeed, it is even more than a just a “realistic possibility.” See 734 12 F.3d at 916. Following confirmation, the Trust faces virtually no impediment to its taking control of 13 Bayside at its discretion. 14 B. The ROFO 15 Appellants further argue that the ROFO, a new feature of the Revised Plan, violates the 16 control requirement by restricting the Trust’s ability to sell, and thereby “claim value” in, its 17 Bayside shares. See 734 F.3d at 916 n. 9 (“A buyout right could be satisfactory, if that right placed 18 the trust at an advantage such that it could use that right to claim value.”). “[T]he Trust cannot 19 ‘claim value’ or ‘backstop’ the insufficiency of its assets,” Appellants contend, “with stock that it 20 cannot sell.” (App. at 18:23-24). 21 The Insurers overstate the severity of the transfer restraints imposed by the ROFO. If the 22 Trust wishes to sell any of its Bayside shares, it must first offer the shares to Bayside, Ameli, and 23 Badakhshan. If any ROFO holder elects to buy but the parties cannot agree on a price, the shares 24 8 25 26 27 28 As the bankruptcy court observed, this contingency is arguably less burdensome than one of the hypothetical contingencies posed by the Ninth Circuit in Plant III. Recall the court’s remark that it is “easy to imagine” what contingencies might satisfy the control requirement: “Most straightforwardly, a contingency that promised to transfer control to the trust in the event that it proved insufficient would clearly comply with this provision.” 734 F.3d at 916, n. 9. This dicta indicates a control-upon-trust-insufficiency contingency would satisfy the statute regardless of the terms under which the trust would acquire securities of the debtor upon confirmation. Assuming that sort of contingency would require some showing by the trust that it is unable to pay asbestos claims as contemplated by the plan, such a requirement would likely be more burdensome than the one proposed in the Revised Plan, under which the Trust need only pay a single dollar to gain majority control of the debtor’s voting shares. 11 1 are priced using a valuation method that is, according to a finding by the bankruptcy court, 2 reasonable. See Plant IV Memo at 22. If the ROFO holders never agree to purchase in the first 3 place, the Trust can then sell its shares to third parties. So while the ROFO precludes the Trust from 4 taking its Bayside shares directly to the market, it cannot be said that the Trust “cannot sell” its 5 Bayside shares. While the Ninth Circuit emphasized that a buyout right must place the trust in a position to 6 7 “claim value,” nothing in Plant III indicates a § 524(g) trust must retain an unbridled right to sell its 8 shares of the reorganized debtor however it sees fit. Nor does the text of the statute contain such a 9 requirement. The Ninth Circuit made clear that § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III) is about “control over the reorganized debtor’s future operations.” 734 F.3d at 915. As the bankruptcy court observed, 11 For the Northern District of California United States District Court 10 control over such operations is derived “from holding a majority of voting shares, not from selling 12 those shares.” Plant IV, Memo at 18; see also 734 F.3d at 915 (statute’s purpose signaled by use of 13 “key” phrase “voting shares”). Accordingly, the bankruptcy court was correct to conclude that § 14 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III) does not bar a reorganization plan from imposing reasonable restraints on a 15 trust’s ability to transfer shares.9 16 Nor did the bankruptcy court err in assessing the reasonableness of the restrictions imposed 17 by the ROFO. During the two-day evidentiary hearing on the Revised Plan, the court heard expert 18 testimony from the Proponents and the Insurers regarding, among other things, the likely effect of 19 the ROFO on the Trust’s ability to sell its Bayside shares for fair value. Afterwards, the bankruptcy 20 court issued a thorough Memorandum Opinion holding that the ROFO’s restrictions are indeed 21 reasonable. 22 The court’s conclusion was grounded in several findings. For one, the court found that by 23 using baseball arbitration, which by its nature encourages reasonable offers from both parties, the 24 ROFO provides a reasonable means of valuing Bayside’s shares. Although the Insurers’ experts 25 offered testimony to the contrary, the court found that testimony to be “wholly unpersuasive.” Plant 26 IV, Memo at 22. One of the Insurers’ experts testified that the ROFO’s arbitration valuation 27 procedure was unreliable for numerous reasons, including that market transactions are “always more 28 9 For their part, Appellees contend that any restraint on transferability, including an outright bar on a trust’s ability to sell shares, is permissible under the statute. Because the Revised Plan does not include such a restriction, this order need not decide whether it would be permissible to do so. 12 1 accurate than arbitration” and that “baseball arbitration is not the type commonly used in valuing 2 companies.” Id. at 17 (paraphrasing expert Neil Beaton). The court reasoned that the ROFO’s 3 valuation should not be measured only against a market transaction, however, “because the very 4 nature of the restraints on transfer permitted in closely held corporations is to bar open-market 5 transactions that could frustrate legitimate interests of other shareholders.” Id. at 22. 6 Indeed, as the court observed, and as one of the Insurers’ experts acknowledged, it is 7 common for closely-held corporations to restrict the persons to whom shares can be transferred. Id. 8 at 19; F. Hodge O’Neal, Restrictions on Transfer of Stock in Closely Held Corporations: Planning 9 and Drafting, 65 Harv. L. Rev. 773 (1952) (“[S]hareholders in a closely held enterprise usually desire to retain the power to choose future associates.”). From the shareholders’ perspective, there 11 For the Northern District of California United States District Court 10 is good reason for such restrictions—“[e]ach shareholder wants to be in a position to prevent 12 outsiders from entering the business if he doubts their integrity or business judgment.” Id. Looking 13 to California law, the court observed that both the Corporations Code and California case law 14 recognize a closely-held corporation’s interest in restricting share transfers. See Cal Cop. Code § 15 204(b); 9 Witkin, Summary 10th (2005) Corp, § 129, p. 903 (“The usual restriction is designed to 16 safeguard the membership of close corporations from entry of unacceptable outsiders, by requiring a 17 first offering of the shares to existing stockholders or the corporation. It is not an unreasonable 18 curtailment of the right of alienation or an unreasonable deprivation of the shareholder's substantial 19 rights.”). Another of the Insurers’ experts testified that the ROFO may prevent the Trust from seeking 20 21 third-party offers before offering to sell its shares to the ROFO holders. The bankruptcy court 22 disagreed, finding that the ROFO does not preclude such bids. Indeed, the court held that the Trust 23 could solicit third-party bids and submit those bids as evidence of Bayside’s value during baseball 24 arbitration. Accordingly, even though baseball arbitration is a closed process between the Trust and 25 the ROFO holder, the ROFO’s valuation procedures are not necessarily insulated from market 26 influences. The court accordingly found no reason why baseball arbitration would be harmful to the 27 Trust. 28 13 The court further found that the ROFO does not merely burden the trust; it provides potential 1 2 benefits, too. By ensuring that Bayside’s managers will not be required to associate and share 3 profits with third-party buyers, the ROFO “may” enhance the value of the Trust’s shares: While the ROFO might decrease the Trust’s ability to sell the shares for their full value by restricting the persons to whom those shares may be sold, it may have the countervailing effect of increasing the value of those shares by eliciting greater efforts from Ameli and Badakhshan. 4 5 6 7 8 9 11 For the Northern District of California United States District Court 10 12 13 Plant IV, Memo at 20-21. In any event, the court concluded, it is far from clear that the Trust would be able to find a purchaser for its Bayside shares in the open market. Id. at 21. Although one of the Insurers’ experts testified that there is an active market for partial interests in small companies generally, he did not testify that there is an effective market for partial interests in all companies including the likes of Bayside. As the bankruptcy court observed, Bayside’s managers may well be the only persons interested in buying the Trust’s shares. Accordingly, the court concluded, “it is far from certain that the ROFO materially diminishes the benefits of ownership of the shares.” Id. The Insurers contend the bankruptcy court erred by looking towards California law when 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 assessing whether the ROFO’s restraints are permissible. Their appeal, however, overstates the court’s reliance on state law. The bankruptcy court’s approval of the ROFO did not, as the Insurers contend, “fail[] to consider what federal law requires.” (App. at 20:4). The court concluded first and foremost that § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III) permits reasonable restraints on a trust’s ability to transfer shares of the reorganized debtor. Only then did the court look to the law of corporations generally, and to California law in particular, to explain that it is common for closely-held corporations to restrain the transferability of company shares, a specific area on which federal law is silent. To be sure, there are important differences between (i) what is allowed under California corporations law and (ii) what is required under the Bankruptcy Code, but the court did not conflate these concepts.10 Rather, it concluded that despite the ROFO’s restrictions on transfer—restrictions that are commonplace among closely-held corporations generally—the Revised Plan satisfies the control 10 While the law of closely-held corporations protects the interests of a corporation’s managershareholders, § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III) serves to ensure that, among other things, when a trust does not retain majority control upon confirmation, it at least remains in a position to take control and “claim value.” 734 F.3d at 916 n. 9. To the extent a trust chooses to claim value by selling the debtor’s shares, there is some tension between the trust’s interest in transferring the shares and the managershareholders’ interest in retaining some backstop against the prospect of associating with unknown third-party buyers. 14 1 requirement because the ROFO creates benefits for the Trust while ensuring the Trust can sell its 2 Bayside shares through a “reasonable” valuation process. 3 Appellants also lodge a few factual objections, arguing the bankruptcy court committed clear conclusion that the ROFO “may” enhance the value of the Trust’s shares by encouraging Bayside’s 6 managers to “continue to devote their skills and efforts to the company.” See Plant IV, Memo at 20. 7 As it stands, Ameli and Badakhshan already hold five-year employment contracts with Bayside 8 offering significant yearly compensation plus bonuses tied to the company’s net operating profit. 9 Following the five-year term, they have the option of renewing for up to five additional one-year 10 terms. Appellants argue that because of these “lucrative” employment agreements, the managers 11 For the Northern District of California error in its assessment of the ROFO’s potential benefits. For one, Appellants dispute the court’s 5 United States District Court 4 “[n]eed[]” no further encouragement to devote themselves to Bayside. (App. at 20:7, 15). 12 For a bankruptcy court’s factual finding to be “clearly erroneous,” it must be “illogical, 13 implausible, or without support in the record.” In re Retz, 606 F.3d 1189, 1196 (9th Cir. 2010). 14 Although the Insurers offer support for their contention that Ameli and Badakhshan do not “need” 15 more encouragement, their appeal falls far short of explaining why it was illogical, implausible, or 16 without support for the bankruptcy court to find simply that the ROFO “may” enhance Bayside’s 17 value by incentivizing the managers’ continued devotion. After all, the court’s finding was couched 18 in general terms; it did not conclude the ROFO would necessarily increase Bayside’s value. 19 Moreover, it is immaterial whether Bayside’s managers “need” more encouragement. The 20 bankruptcy court concluded only that the ROFO provides additional encouragement, thereby 21 possibly making the company more valuable. 22 Appellants’ second factual objection fares no better. The Insurers argue the bankruptcy 23 court committed clear error by finding it “far from certain” that the Trust would locate a purchaser 24 for its Bayside shares in the open market. Plant IV, Memo at 21. The court reasoned that shares of 25 the company “might not be of much value to a third party” and that the Bayside managers “may be 26 the only parties interested in buying the Trust’s shares.” Id. (emphasis added). Mr. Beaton, one of 27 the Insurers’ experts, posited that while the Bayside ROFO is “essentially meaningless from an 28 economic standpoint” because Bayside’s overall equity value is, at present, marginal, the company could become “considerably more valuable” in five or ten years if its operations were to improve 15 1 “materially.” (App. at 22 n. 18). Appellants take the position that while Bayside today may not be 2 attractive to third-party buyers, it could be highly valuable in the future, at which point the ROFO’s 3 restrictions would pose a more palpable barrier to the Trust’s ability to claim value. Again, 4 however, the Insurers fall far short of explaining why the bankruptcy court’s finding was 5 unsupported, illogical, or implausible. The court concluded there was a lack of testimony showing 6 the existence of an effective market for partial interests in all companies like Bayside. Again, the 7 court’s challenged factual finding was not couched in absolute language; the court found only that it 8 is “far from certain” that the Trust would find a purchaser for its Bayside shares on the open market. 9 Plant IV, Memo at 21. For purposes of establishing that the court committed “clear error,” it is not enough that Appellants point to evidence in the record supporting a contrary outcome. V. 11 For the Northern District of California United States District Court 10 12 CONCLUSION While § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III) “is about control over the reorganized debtor’s future 13 operations,” see 734 F.3d at 915, the statute does not require that the trust retain an unfettered right 14 to sell its shares in the organized debtor. Nor does the statute preclude an arrangement whereby the 15 trust is required to invest in the reorganized debtor at confirmation, even at an over-market price. 16 Because Appellants’ claims of legal and factual error are without merit, the appeal is denied. 17 18 IT IS SO ORDERED. 19 Dated: 8/18/14 20 RICHARD SEEBORG UNITED STATES DISTRICT JUDGE 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 16

Disclaimer: Justia Dockets & Filings provides public litigation records from the federal appellate and district courts. These filings and docket sheets should not be considered findings of fact or liability, nor do they necessarily reflect the view of Justia.


Why Is My Information Online?