hiQ Labs, Inc. v. Linkedin Corporation
Filing
158
ORDER by Judge Edward M. Chen Granting in Part and Denying in Part #137 Defendant's Motion to Dismiss. Amended Complaint due by 10/7/2020. (emcsec, COURT STAFF) (Filed on 9/9/2020)
Case 3:17-cv-03301-EMC Document 158 Filed 09/09/20 Page 1 of 21
1
2
3
4
UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
5
NORTHERN DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA
6
7
HIQ LABS, INC.,
Plaintiff,
8
9
10
v.
LINKEDIN CORPORATION,
Defendant.
11
United States District Court
Northern District of California
Case No. 17-cv-03301-EMC
ORDER GRANTING IN PART AND
DENYING IN PART DEFENDANT’S
MOTION TO DISMISS
Docket No. 137
12
13
Plaintiff hiQ Labs, Inc. has filed suit against LinkedIn Corp. seeking declaratory relief as
14
well as injunctive relief and damages. According to hiQ, it has not violated any laws by
15
“scraping” public information about LinkedIn users from LinkedIn’s website. Furthermore, hiQ
16
asserts, LinkedIn has violated various antitrust and fair practices laws by trying to prevent hiQ
17
from accessing the public information on the website. Currently pending before the Court is
18
LinkedIn’s motion to dismiss the first amended complaint (“FAC”). The motion primarily
19
challenges the antitrust claims asserted for the first time in the FAC.
20
21
Having considered the parties’ briefs as well as the oral argument of counsel, the Court
hereby GRANTS in part and DENIES in part the motion to dismiss.
I.
22
FACTUAL & PROCEDURAL BACKGROUND
23
The main allegations in the FAC which are related to the antitrust claims are as follows.
24
“LinkedIn is the world’s largest professional social network, with over 660 million
25
members.” FAC ¶ 2. Individuals who use the LinkedIn network can make certain information
26
about themselves – e.g., resumes and work history – publicly available on the LinkedIn website.
27
See FAC ¶ 2.
28
“hiQ identified an opportunity for a new kind of ‘people analytics’ services” based on the
Case 3:17-cv-03301-EMC Document 158 Filed 09/09/20 Page 2 of 21
1
information publicly available on LinkedIn. FAC ¶ 3. “People analytics” is
2
a new type of predictive data analysis aimed at providing employers
in-depth, predictive insights into their workforce. People analytics
generally work by performing computerized analyses of employees’
public professional information and history that then show which
employees are at higher risk of looking for a new job, and which
may have skills that are not being utilized in their current job. hiQ
created two specific analytics services: (a) “Keeper,” which tells
employers which of their employees are at the greatest risk of being
recruited away, and (b) “Skill Mapper,” a summary of the breadth
and depth of aggregate or individual skills of current or prospective
employees, which may not be obvious from internal company
documents (such as internal performance reviews or the resume the
employee supplied as part of the hiring process) or conversations
with those employees.
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
FAC ¶ 33. Before hiQ, people analytics either did not exist or was not very accurate – e.g.,
11
United States District Court
Northern District of California
10
employers relied on internal data only and took an ad hoc approach; hiQ, with its people analytics
12
services, was “able to reduce hard costs and transaction costs” for employers. FAC ¶ 35.
13
LinkedIn eventually realized that it might be able to profit by
providing the same type of innovative and revolutionary analytics
hiQ pioneered, and it developed its own competing version of that
analytics service. Then, in May 2017, LinkedIn abruptly,
unlawfully and without cause denied hiQ access to the portion of the
LinkedIn website containing wholly public member profiles.
14
15
16
17
FAC ¶ 6.
18
hiQ is not alone in being denied access to the public portion of LinkedIn’s website;
19
LinkedIn has denied access to other people analytics providers as well. See FAC ¶ 46. However,
20
LinkedIn has not denied access to companies that do not provide people analytics services (e.g.,
21
Google and Bing). See FAC ¶ 47.
22
“The most immediate anticompetitive effect of LinkedIn’s conduct . . . was to eliminate –
23
effectively overnight – nearly all of its people analytics competitors.” FAC ¶ 53. People analytics
24
providers who remain either offer their services at much higher prices than LinkedIn does, or at
25
the same price but with inferior quality. See FAC ¶ 54. Through its actions, LinkedIn has thus
26
reduced consumer choice and price competition. See FAC ¶ 58(d).
27
28
LinkedIn’s conduct implicates two product markets. First, there is the market for
professional social networking platforms. Professional social networking platforms must be
2
Case 3:17-cv-03301-EMC Document 158 Filed 09/09/20 Page 3 of 21
1
differentiated from traditional social networking platforms because the former, unlike the latter,
2
focus only on business relationships. See FAC ¶¶ 20-21 (alleging, inter alia, that “consumers
3
would reasonably switch to other professional social network platforms for business purposes (if
4
they could), but would not similarly use more traditional social networks for the same purposes”).
5
“LinkedIn was, for many years, the only real professional social networking platform . . . .” FAC
6
¶ 25. Today, LinkedIn has “well over 75% of all professional social network users in the United
7
States.” FAC ¶ 25.
8
Second, there is the market for people analytics services. This “type of service . . . did not
9
exist until hiQ first came into being, and the only alternative to such services is the previous set of
ad hoc measures that companies employed when trying to guess employee attrition risk and
11
United States District Court
Northern District of California
10
employees’ full and current skillsets.” FAC ¶ 36.
12
13
Based on, inter alia, the above allegations, hiQ has asserted three antitrust claims.
•
Monopolization, in violation of § 2 of the Sherman Act. According to hiQ,
14
LinkedIn has acquired and maintained monopoly power in the markets for
15
professional social networking platforms and people analytics services through
16
unlawful means, including “leveraging, lock-in, raising rivals’ costs, tying,
17
unilateral refusal to deal, denial of essential facilities, and vertically-arranged
18
boycotts.” FAC ¶ 12.
19
•
Attempted monopolization, also in violation of § 2 of the Sherman Act. According
20
to hiQ, there is a dangerous probability that LinkedIn will monopolize the market
21
for people analytics services because it has engaged in anticompetitive conduct
22
such as “leveraging, lock-in, raising rivals’ costs, tying, unilateral refusal to deal,
23
denial of essential facilities, and vertically-arranged boycotts.” FAC 150.
24
•
Unreasonable restraint of trade, in violation of § 1 of the Sherman Act. According
25
to hiQ, LinkedIn and its members have entered into contracts or combinations that
26
have the effect of unreasonably restraining trade. See FAC ¶ 159. The contracts or
27
combinations include “tying arrangements and vertically-arranged boycotts.” FAC
28
¶ 162.
3
Case 3:17-cv-03301-EMC Document 158 Filed 09/09/20 Page 4 of 21
In addition to the antitrust claims, hiQ has asserted claims for, inter alia, declaratory relief,
1
2
intentional interference with contract and prospective economic advantage, and violation of
3
California Business & Professions Code § 17200.
LinkedIn moves to dismiss certain claims asserted in hiQ’s FAC. In particular, LinkedIn
4
5
argues that all claims for damages (i.e., the antitrust and intentional interference claims) should be
6
dismissed based on the Noerr-Pennington doctrine and the California litigation privilege.
7
LinkedIn further argues that the antitrust claims should be dismissed on various merits grounds
8
(e.g., failure to allege antitrust injury, a product market, and anticompetitive conduct).
II.
9
10
United States District Court
Northern District of California
11
A.
DISCUSSION
Legal Standard
Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 8(a)(2) requires a complaint to include “a short and plain
12
statement of the claim showing that the pleader is entitled to relief.” Fed. R. Civ. P. 8(a)(2). A
13
complaint that fails to meet this standard may be dismissed pursuant to Federal Rule of Civil
14
Procedure 12(b)(6). See Fed. R. Civ. P. 12(b)(6). To overcome a Rule 12(b)(6) motion to dismiss
15
after the Supreme Court’s decisions in Ashcroft v. Iqbal, 556 U.S. 662 (2009), and Bell Atlantic
16
Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544 (2007), a plaintiff’s “factual allegations [in the complaint] ‘must .
17
. . suggest that the claim has at least a plausible chance of success.’“ Levitt v. Yelp! Inc., 765 F.3d
18
1123, 1135 (9th Cir. 2014). The court “accept[s] factual allegations in the complaint as true and
19
construe[s] the pleadings in the light most favorable to the nonmoving party.” Manzarek v. St.
20
Paul Fire & Marine Ins. Co., 519 F.3d 1025, 1031 (9th Cir. 2008). But “allegations in a
21
complaint . . . may not simply recite the elements of a cause of action [and] must contain sufficient
22
allegations of underlying facts to give fair notice and to enable the opposing party to defend itself
23
effectively.” Levitt, 765 F.3d at 1135 (internal quotation marks omitted). “A claim has facial
24
plausibility when the plaintiff pleads factual content that allows the court to draw the reasonable
25
inference that the defendant is liable for the misconduct alleged.” Iqbal, 556 U.S. at 678. “The
26
plausibility standard is not akin to a probability requirement, but it asks for more than a sheer
27
possibility that a defendant has acted unlawfully.” Id. (internal quotation marks omitted).
28
4
Case 3:17-cv-03301-EMC Document 158 Filed 09/09/20 Page 5 of 21
1
2
B.
Claims for Damages
In the FAC, hiQ seeks declaratory relief, injunctive relief, and damages. The request for
3
damages is based on the following causes of action: (1) the antitrust claims and (2) the intentional
4
interference claims. LinkedIn moves to dismiss both damages claims based on the Noerr-
5
Pennington doctrine. LinkedIn also moves to dismiss the intentional interference claims based on
6
the California litigation privilege.
7
8
9
10
United States District Court
Northern District of California
11
12
1.
Noerr-Pennington Doctrine
The essence of the Noerr-Pennington doctrine is that those who
petition any department of the government for redress are immune
from statutory liability for their petitioning conduct. The doctrine
derives from two Supreme Court cases holding that the First
Amendment Petition Clause immunizes acts of petitioning the
legislature from antitrust liability. The doctrine has since been
applied to actions petitioning each of the three branches of
government, and has been expanded beyond its original antitrust
context.
13
Theme Promotions, Inc. v. News Am. Mktg. FSI, 546 F.3d 991, 1006-07 (9th Cir. 2008). For
14
example, the doctrine can apply to a state claim for tortious interference with prospective
15
economic advantage. See id. at 1007; see also Hi-Top Steel Corp. v. Lehrer, 24 Cal. App. 4th 570,
16
577-78 (1994) (noting that, “[w]hile the Noerr-Pennington doctrine was formulated in the context
17
of antitrust cases, it has been applied or discussed in cases involving other types of civil liability,
18
including liability for interference with contractual relations or prospective economic advantage or
19
unfair competition”).
20
LinkedIn concedes that it has not directly petitioned the government for any relief.
21
However, it points out that “[c]onduct incidental to a lawsuit, including a pre-suit demand letter,
22
falls within the protection of the Noerr-Pennington doctrine.” Id. (emphasis added). LinkedIn
23
maintains that hiQ’s antitrust and intentional interference claims “derive from the cease-and-desist
24
letters LinkedIn sent that ostensibly ‘cut off’ hiQ’s access to LinkedIn’s website.” Mot. at 8. See,
25
e.g., FAC ¶¶ 7, 39 (referring to a cease-and-desist letter sent on May 23, 2017); FAC ¶ 43
26
(referring to letter sent on June 24, 2017, reiterating demand to cease and desist).
27
28
In response, hiQ argues that “petitioning activity may be actionable if it is part of a broader
anticompetitive scheme.” Opp’n at 13. The broader anticompetitive scheme includes the actual
5
Case 3:17-cv-03301-EMC Document 158 Filed 09/09/20 Page 6 of 21
1
cutting off of competitors’ access to the public information on LinkedIn’s website – which is not
2
petitioning activity. See Opp’n at 15.
3
hiQ’s argument relies in large part on Hynix Semiconductor Inc. v. Rambus, Inc., 527 F.
4
Supp. 2d 1084 (N.D. Cal. 2007) (Whyte, J.). In Hynix, Rambus was a member of a SSO
5
(standard-setting organization) and allegedly used its membership in the SSO to discover how a
6
particular standard was developing and then drafted patent claims to cover the standard. “Once
7
the industry became ‘locked in’ to the DRAM standard, Rambus sprang the ‘patent trap’ and
8
demanded royalties,” and further “backed up its royalty demands with infringement litigation.” Id.
9
at 1089. Hynix subsequently brought an antitrust claim based on Rambus’s “‘overall course of
10
conduct’ – including [its] patent litigation.” Id.
United States District Court
Northern District of California
11
Before Judge Whyte, Rambus argued that, “because its use of the courts to enforce its
12
patents is protected petitioning activity pursuant to the Noerr-Pennington doctrine . . . , Hynix
13
could not claim its litigation expenses as damages.” Id. at 1086. Judge Whyte ultimately
14
disagreed.
15
16
17
Judge Whyte noted that there were “three possible approaches to whether patent litigation
can be an anticompetitive act in violation of the antitrust laws.” Id. at 1091.
•
patents can be anticompetitive and part of an unlawful scheme.” Id. at 1091-92.
18
19
Under the first approach (the Second Circuit’s “absolute bar”), “only frivolous
•
Under the second approach (labeled the “Kobe claim”) – and at “the opposite end
20
of the spectrum” – even nonfrivolous patent litigation can be anticompetitive if part
21
of a broader anticompetitive scheme (i.e., “brought in conjunction with other
22
antitrust misconduct”). Id. at 1092-94.
23
•
The third approach was a middle ground between the first two approaches. See id.
24
at 1094. Under the third approach, “good faith litigation” could be “unlawful if
25
done as part of an anticompetitive scheme” but, in order to get litigation costs as
26
part of the damages for the antitrust violation, there must be “an explicit linkage
27
between [the] antitrust violation and the litigation” – i.e., a causal connection. Id.
28
at 1095.
6
Case 3:17-cv-03301-EMC Document 158 Filed 09/09/20 Page 7 of 21
Judge Whyte endorsed the third approach.
1
2
8
[T]he court believes that the Federal Circuit and the Supreme Court
would recognize some “scheme” antitrust allegations that include
constitutionally protected litigation within the “overall course of
conduct,” but only those in which the patent litigation is “causally
connected” to anticompetitive harms. . . . The court concludes that
before otherwise protected litigation can be a part of an
“anticompetitive scheme” claim, the court must first find that the
other aspects of the scheme independently produce anticompetitive
harms. Once this step has been established, the court should ask
whether the accused patent litigation was causally connected to
these anticompetitive harms. If yes, an antitrust plaintiff may then
include good faith patent litigation as part of the anticompetitive
scheme.
9
Id. at 1096-97.1 He added: “[W]here the patent litigation is used to further the harm caused under
3
4
5
6
7
a ‘more traditional antitrust theory,’ a plaintiff should be allowed a full recovery.” Id. at 1097
11
United States District Court
Northern District of California
10
(emphasis added); see also Arista Networks, Inc. v. Cisco Sys. Inc., No. C-16-0923 BLF (N.D.
12
Cal.) (Docket No. 281) (Order at 16) (taking note of plaintiff’s argument that defendant’s
13
intellectual property “lawsuit was the ‘enforcement mechanism’ of the purported ‘open early,
14
closed late’ anticompetitive scheme” – i.e., defendant used the litigation and conduct incidental to
15
that litigation “as tools to further the ‘closing’ step of the ‘open early, closed late’ scheme”)
16
(emphasis added).
According to LinkedIn, the Court should reject the application of Hynix to the instant case
17
18
because the facts in Hynix and the facts in the instant case are not sufficiently similar. LinkedIn
19
maintains that Hynix-type cases all involve “a bait-and-switch, where a defendant affirmatively
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
1
In its papers, LinkedIn argues that the anticompetitive nonpetitioning activity must be
“ineffective” without the petitioning activity in order to avoid the Noerr-Pennington doctrine. See
Reply at 6-7. LinkedIn comes up with this requirement because Judge Whyte stated in Hynix as
follows:
Because Rambus’ alleged conduct at JEDEC can independently
qualify as an anticompetitive harm under section 2, the court finds
that Rambus’ current patent litigation is “causally connected” to
that behavior and therefore properly included in an “anticompetitive
scheme” allegation. To be clear, the causal connection is that a
patent “ambush” or “hold-up” is ineffective without the threat of
litigation.
Hynix, 527 F. Supp. 2d at 1098. But as should be clear from the above, although Judge Whyte did
use the term “ineffective,” he was not imposing some kind of ineffectiveness requirement. Rather,
he simply imposed a requirement of causal connection.
7
Case 3:17-cv-03301-EMC Document 158 Filed 09/09/20 Page 8 of 21
1
misled competitors into using its technology and intellectual property on the understanding that no
2
legal action would result from doing so.” Reply at 5. LinkedIn’s argument is not persuasive. It
3
provides no rationale as to why Hynix should be narrowly construed to these facts. Hynix clearly
4
made a broader point: it asks whether the petitioning activity furthered an anticompetitive scheme
5
involving nonpetitioning activity; if the gravamen of the action centers on nonpetitioning activity,
6
the fact that petitioning activity is employed to further that conduct is not sufficient to implicate
7
the Noerr-Pennington doctrine.
8
LinkedIn argues that even if Hynix has broader application, its cease-and-desist letters
9
(petitioning activity) did not further the anticompetitive scheme that involved the blocking of
access to its website (nonpetitioning activity). LinkedIn points out that its first cease-and-desist
11
United States District Court
Northern District of California
10
letter was issued before it blocked hiQ’s access to the website. See Reply at 7 (“The [first] letter
12
preceded any technical cut-off by a full month.”). But LinkedIn’s position is problematic for two
13
reasons.
14
•
First, LinkedIn’s second cease-and-desist letter was issued on the same day that
15
LinkedIn blocked access. See Mot. at 5 (“LinkedIn implemented IP address blocks
16
on June 24, the same day it sent the second letter.”). Therefore, arguably, the
17
second letter was used to further the anticompetitive scheme involving the
18
blocking.
19
•
Second, it is not clear that the causal connection requirement always demands that
20
the anticompetitive petitioning activity come after the anticompetitive
21
nonpetitioning activity; a cease-and-desist letter that comes before the actual
22
blocking still reinforces the overall anticompetitive scheme.
23
At bottom, LinkedIn’s argument defies the fundamental logic of Hynix.
24
Finally, LinkedIn contends that, should the Court favor hiQ on the above arguments, then
25
the Court should – at the very least – restrict hiQ’s damages claims. More specifically, LinkedIn
26
maintains that, if the anticompetitive nonpetitioning activity is the blocking of hiQ’s access, then
27
damages should be limited to the timeframe when hiQ was actually blocked – a “six-day period in
28
June 2017.” Mot. at 9 (arguing that “any claim for damages for lack of access for any other
8
Case 3:17-cv-03301-EMC Document 158 Filed 09/09/20 Page 9 of 21
1
period is necessarily based on LinkedIn’s letters and should be dismissed”) (emphasis in original);
2
see also Reply at 6. But LinkedIn’s position is not persuasive because, even if petitioning activity
3
arguably cannot be a basis for liability under the Noerr-Pennington doctrine, that does not mean
4
that a plaintiff cannot get damages based on the petitioning activity,2 and the petitioning activity
5
can take place at a different time than the nonpetitioning activity. Furthermore, LinkedIn takes too
6
narrow a view of the impact that the nonpetitioning activity (blocking of access) could have – that
7
impact could extend beyond the time of the actual blocking. For example, even if the actual
8
blocking lasted for only six days, it seems plausible that this conduct might dissuade hiQ
9
customers from subsequently signing up for hiQ’s people analytics services. Cf. Arista (Docket
No. 281) (Order at 21-22) (noting that “a reasonable jury could find that [the defendant] raised the
11
United States District Court
Northern District of California
10
specter of the . . . lawsuit to persuade customers to abandon [the defendant’s] competitors”).
Accordingly, the Noerr-Pennington doctrine does not bar hiQ’s antitrust and interference
12
13
claims.
14
2.
California Litigation Privilege
15
As noted above, LinkedIn argues that the state claims for intentional interference are also
16
protected by the California litigation privilege. The parties’ briefs indicate that the above analysis
17
for Noerr-Pennington applies here as well. For the reasons stated above, the California litigation
18
privilege is not a bar to hiQ’s interference claims.
19
C.
Antitrust Claims: Product Market
20
LinkedIn contends the antitrust claims are still deficient for independent reasons, including
21
a failure on the part of hiQ to adequately allege a product market – i.e., a people analytics market.3
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
2
See Hovenkamp, et al., IP & Antitrust § 11.04[F] (suggesting that liability should not be based
on protected petitioning but damages are a different matter: “‘a plaintiff that can prove an antitrust
violation without the use of protected petitioning can recover damages caused by that petitioning
as well as damages by the conduct that proved the violation’”).
Technically, hiQ makes reference to two different product markets in the FAC – (1) the market
for people analytics services and (2) the market for professional social networking platforms. See,
e.g., FAC ¶ 110 (alleging that “LinkedIn has willfully acquired and maintained monopoly power
in the relevant markets for professional social networking platforms and people analytics”); FAC ¶
159 (alleging that “LinkedIn and its members have entered into contracts or combinations that
have the effect of unreasonably restraining trade . . . in the relevant markets for professional social
networking platforms and people analytics services”). But LinkedIn challenges only hiQ’s
9
3
Case 3:17-cv-03301-EMC Document 158 Filed 09/09/20 Page 10 of 21
1
A product market “encompass[es] the product at issue as well as all economic substitutes
2
for the product.” Newcal Indus. v. Ikon Office Sol., 513 F.3d 1038, 1045 (9th Cir. 2008). “‘The
3
outer boundaries of a product market are determined by the reasonable interchangeability of use or
4
the cross-elasticity of demand between the product itself and substitutes for it.’”4 Id. “[W]hat
5
constitutes a relevant market is a factual determination for the jury,” Image Tech. Servs. v.
6
Eastman Kodak Co., 125 F.3d 1195, 1203 (9th Cir. 1997); see also Todd v. Exxon Corp., 275 F.3d
7
191, 199-200 (2d Cir. 2001) (stating that, “[b]ecause market definition is a deeply fact-intensive
8
inquiry, courts hesitate to grant motions to dismiss for failure to plead a relevant product market”);
9
however, the relevant market must still be plausibly alleged to make it past a 12(b)(6) challenge.
In the instant case, the FAC indicates that people analytics is “a new type of predictive data
10
United States District Court
Northern District of California
11
analytics aimed at providing employers in-depth predictive insights into their workforce.” FAC ¶
12
33. The FAC also alleges that “[p]eople analytics generally work by performing computerized
13
analyses of employees’ public professional information and history.” FAC ¶ 33. Nevertheless,
14
the parameters of the people analytics market – as pled – are vague. Most notably, as the Court
15
discussed with the parties at the hearing, it is not clear what substitutes there are for people
16
analytics products such as those offered by hiQ. Should a product be considered a substitute if the
17
people analytics are based on an employer’s internally maintained data? Should a product be
18
considered a substitute if the people analytics are based on publicly available information other
19
than that available on LinkedIn’s website? Even if more established analytic techniques have
20
become dated, that does not mean there is no substitutability or cross-elasticity of demand between
21
different modes of people analytics.
22
At the hearing, hiQ asserted that a product that uses an employer’s internally maintained
23
data should not be deemed a substitute but the FAC fails to explain why. For example, the FAC
24
25
26
27
28
attempt to define the people analytics market.
“Elasticity of demand is a concept used to signify the relationship between changes in price and
responsive changes in demand.” United States v. LSL Biotechnologies, 379 F.3d 672, 697 (9th
Cir. 2004); see also Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Tech. Servs., 504 U.S. 451, 469 (1992)
(indicating that cross-elasticity of demand refers to “the extent to which consumers will change
their consumption of one product in response to a price change in another”).
10
4
Case 3:17-cv-03301-EMC Document 158 Filed 09/09/20 Page 11 of 21
1
does not explain why internal data such as performance reviews and resumes should be considered
2
“limited” in nature. FAC ¶ 35. The FAC also fails to explain why, even if an employer was not
3
able to use internal data successfully itself, see FAC ¶ 35 (alleging that “employers tried to
4
manage attrition risk within their organizations through a variety of ad hoc internal methods, and
5
they tried to identify employees’ full skillsets through similarly ad hoc internal means”), the
6
employer could not hire a company to put that data to good use. Indeed, hiQ suggests that that
7
was the conventional approach before hiQ came on the scene with its analytics. It is not plausible
8
to suggest without specific facts that the entire field of analytics using internal data is now
9
obsolete. In fact, it would appear that internal data which might include direct polling could yield
10
United States District Court
Northern District of California
11
information not otherwise accessible via LinkedIn.
As for a product that bases its people analytics on publicly available information other than
12
LinkedIn, hiQ made a different argument at the hearing. According to hiQ, in theory, such a
13
product would be a substitute (and thus in the same market as hiQ’s products) but, hiQ
14
maintained, as a practical matter, the only place to get publicly available data is LinkedIn. But
15
similar to above, the FAC contains no specific allegations establishing such. The Court does not
16
doubt that LinkedIn is a useful source for publicly available data given its focus on professional
17
social networking and its prominence in the professional social networking space; however, that
18
does not mean that useful publicly available information cannot be gleaned from other sources
19
such as Google and Facebook or other industry directories and sources. Indeed, in this day and
20
age, it would not be surprising if a person’s digital footprint – even apart from LinkedIn – were
21
enlightening to the analytics task.
22
The Court acknowledges hiQ’s suggestion that products using employer internal data or
23
publicly available data other than LinkedIn’s are different in quality from hiQ’s products – and
24
thus it is at least a question of fact whether there is some elasticity of demand between them and
25
whether those products are in the same market as hiQ’s products. See generally Brown Shoe Co.
26
v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 326, 82 S. Ct. 1502, 1524-25 (1962) (“agree[ing] with the District
27
Court that in this case a further division of product lines based on ‘price/quality’ differences
28
[medium-priced shoes and low-priced shoes] would be ‘unrealistic’”); see also In re Live Concert
11
Case 3:17-cv-03301-EMC Document 158 Filed 09/09/20 Page 12 of 21
1
Antitrust Litig., 247 F.R.D. 98, 129 (C.D. Cal. 2007) (indicating that consumers may differentiate
2
or distinguish among products based on performance, price, and so forth but that does not
3
necessarily mean that the products are in separate markets). The problem for hiQ is that it has not
4
yet shown that it is plausible that the relevant market should be defined as that which uses only
5
LinkedIn data.
Accordingly, the Court finds all of hiQ’s antitrust claims deficient for failure to adequately
6
7
allege a product market.5 The Court, however, shall give hiQ an opportunity to amend to correct
8
this deficiency.
9
D.
Antitrust Claims: Anticompetitive Conduct
There are additional reasons why the antitrust claims are not viable as currently pled. In
11
United States District Court
Northern District of California
10
particular, LinkedIn persuasively argues that hiQ has failed to adequately allege anticompetitive
12
conduct.
For its first antitrust claim – monopolization in violation of § 2 of the Sherman Act – hiQ
13
14
alleges as follows:
15
18
LinkedIn has willfully acquired and maintained monopoly power in
the relevant markets [i.e., the market for professional social
networking platforms and the market for people analytics services],
by means of predatory, exclusionary, and anticompetitive conduct,
including but not limited to by means of lock-in, raising rivals’
costs, tying, unilateral refusal to deal, denial of essential facilities,
and vertically-arranged boycotts . . . .
19
FAC ¶ 112. hiQ repeats these theories for its second antitrust claim, i.e., attempted
20
monopolization). See FAC ¶ 150. For the final antitrust claim – concerted action that
21
unreasonably restrains trade – hiQ asserts the tying and vertical boycott theories only. See FAC ¶
22
162. Each of the above theories, as addressed below, is deficient.
16
17
23
1.
24
As an initial matter, the Court rejects LinkedIn’s contention that hiQ cannot raise a theory
25
Unilateral Refusal to Deal
of unilateral refusal to deal because, during the Ninth Circuit proceedings, hiQ stated that it was
26
27
28
5
Because the Court finds a deficiency in the allegation of a product market, it does not address
LinkedIn’s argument that hiQ has failed to adequately allege monopoly or market power in the
relevant market.
12
Case 3:17-cv-03301-EMC Document 158 Filed 09/09/20 Page 13 of 21
1
not asserting such a theory. See Mot. at 21 (asserting that, “[h]aving discouraged the Ninth Circuit
2
from considering its case under a duty-to-deal framework, hiQ cannot now revive this theory
3
under the exact same facts”). Although LinkedIn makes an analogy to the doctrine of judicial
4
estoppel, that doctrine requires that a court rely on a representation being made by the party
5
against whom estoppel is asserted. See Casa Del. Caffe Vergnano S.P.A. v. Italflavors San Diego,
6
Ltd. Liab. Co., 816 F.3d 1208, 1213 (9th Cir. 2016) (noting that judicial estoppel “‘generally
7
prevents a party from prevailing in one phase of a case on an argument and then relying on a
8
contradictory argument to prevail in another phase’”). LinkedIn has made no showing that the
9
Ninth Circuit relied on hiQ’s representation above in making its decision on hiQ’s motion for a
10
preliminary injunction.
United States District Court
Northern District of California
11
As for the merits of the unilateral refusal-to-deal theory, the Court begins with the
12
predicate that, “[a]s a general rule, businesses are free to choose the parties with whom they will
13
deal, as well as the prices, terms, and conditions of that dealing.” Pac. Bell Tel. Co. v. linkLine
14
Communs., Inc., 555 U.S. 438, 448 (2009). This includes dealing or not dealing with a rival. See
15
Aerotec Int’l, Inc. v. Honeywell Int’l, Inc., 836 F.3d 1171, 1184 (9th Cir. 2016) (stating that “there
16
is ‘no duty to deal under the terms and conditions preferred by [a competitor’s] rivals’”).
17
However, there are “limited circumstances in which a firm’s unilateral refusal to deal with its
18
rivals can give rise to antitrust liability,” as indicated in the Supreme Court’s seminal case Aspen
19
Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 U.S. 585 (1985). See Aerotec, 836 F.3d at 1184.
20
That being said, the Aspen Skiing exception is very narrow, as both the Supreme Court and Ninth
21
Circuit have made clear. See Verizon Communs., Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis v. Trinko, LLP, 540
22
U.S. 398, 409 (2004) (characterizing Aspen Skiing as “at or near the boundary of § 2 liability”);
23
FTC v. Qualcomm Inc., 969 F.3d 974 (9th Cir. 2020), available at No. 19-16122, 2020 U.S. App.
24
LEXIS 25347, at *30 (9th Cir. Aug. 11, 2020) (stating that Aspen Skiing represents a “limited
25
exception to [the] general rule that there is no antitrust duty to deal”); Aerotec, 836 F.3d at 1184
26
(stating that Aspen Skiing is a “narrow exception”).
27
28
In Aspen Skiing, the defendant owned three of four mountain areas for skiing, and the
plaintiff owned the fourth. The two parties
13
Case 3:17-cv-03301-EMC Document 158 Filed 09/09/20 Page 14 of 21
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
United States District Court
Northern District of California
11
12
13
14
15
had cooperated for years in the issuance of a joint, multiple-day, allarea ski ticket. After repeatedly demanding an increased share of
the proceeds, the defendant canceled the joint ticket. The plaintiff,
concerned that skiers would bypass its mountain without some joint
offering, tried a variety of increasingly desperate measures to recreate the joint ticket, even to the point of in effect offering to buy
the defendant’s tickets at retail price. The defendant refused even
that. [The Supreme Court] upheld a jury verdict for the plaintiff,
reasoning that “[t]he jury may well have concluded that [the
defendant] elected to forgo these short-run benefits because it was
more interested in reducing competition . . . over the long run by
harming its smaller competitor.”
Trinko, 540 U.S. at 408-09 (2004).
The Ninth Circuit has explained that, under Aspen Skiing,
a company engages in prohibited, anticompetitive conduct when (1)
it “unilateral[ly] terminat[es] . . . a voluntary and profitable course
of dealing”; (2) “the only conceivable rationale or purpose is ‘to
sacrifice short-term benefits in order to obtain higher profits in the
long run from the exclusion of competition’“; and (3) the refusal to
deal involves products that the defendant already sells in the existing
market to other similarly situated customers.
Qualcomm, 2020 U.S. App. LEXIS 25347, at *30-31.
In the instant case, hiQ has failed to adequately allege at least the first two Aspen Skiing
16
factors. For example, hiQ has failed to make a plausible case that it and LinkedIn had engaged in
17
a voluntary course of dealing. In ¶ 37, hiQ alleges as follows:
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
LinkedIn has known of hiQ since at least 2015, when it started
participating in hiQ’s annual “Elevate” conference. The hiQ Elevate
conference was designed to build a community around the emerging
field of people analytics and has provided a regular forum for
participants to share insights and disseminate best practices.
LinkedIn has sent representatives to each iteration of that conference
since hiQ’s founding. hiQ has spoken freely about its public data
collection from LinkedIn at Elevate; LinkedIn has thus always
understood what hiQ does. Over the years, LinkedIn has itself
participated regularly in hiQ Elevate events. At a 2016 Elevate
conference, LinkedIn employee Lorenzo Canlas received special
recognition and accepted the hiQ Elevate “Impact Award.”
25
FAC ¶ 37. But that certain LinkedIn employees knew about hiQ and its practices does not mean
26
that the two companies were thereby dealing with one another. It is not even clear whether these
27
LinkedIn employees were high-level employees who could act on behalf of the company. And
28
even if they were, LinkedIn’s tolerance of hiQ’s data gathering did not give rise to an agreement
14
Case 3:17-cv-03301-EMC Document 158 Filed 09/09/20 Page 15 of 21
1
or an “implicit understanding” between the companies. LiveUniverse v. MySpace, Inc., 304 Fed.
2
Appx. 554, 557 (9th Cir. 2008) (noting “nothing in the complaint suggests an agreement, or even
3
an implicit understanding, between MySpace and LiveUniverse”) (emphasis omitted). Unlike
4
Aspen Skiing, there was no mutual commerce or course of dealing between LinkedIn and hiQ.
5
Moreover, even if there were a voluntary course of dealing between LinkedIn and hiQ, hiQ
6
still must show that LinkedIn sacrificed a profitable course of dealing in the short term in order to
7
benefit long term from the exclusion of competition. Absent what would otherwise be irrational
8
short-term behavior (like the defendant’s conduct in Aspen Skiing), there is no antitrust claim for
9
refusal to deal. To establish this element, hiQ maintains that “people analytics help prove
LinkedIn’s value proposition; specifically, they demonstrate why it is valuable for both employees
11
United States District Court
Northern District of California
10
and employers to belong to LinkedIn’s professional social network, and why the public
12
employment database benefits those who participate.” FAC ¶ 38. Thus, hiQ implies that
13
LinkedIn lost business as a result of hiQ’s being excluded from access to information publicly
14
available on LinkedIn’s website. But hiQ has not specifically alleged that, e.g., employers stopped
15
using LinkedIn’s services (or discouraged employees from using LinkedIn’s services) after
16
LinkedIn blocked hiQ from accessing its website. Its theory of short-term sacrifice is far from
17
obvious or even intuitive. Absent specific factual allegations, it is speculative to assume that
18
LinkedIn gave up any short-term benefit by refusing to deal with hiQ.
19
20
Accordingly, to the extent hiQ’s antitrust claims are predicated on a unilateral refusal to
deal, the Court finds such a theory, as pled, implausible.
21
2.
22
LinkedIn also asserts the essential facilities doctrine as another theory of anticompetitive
23
24
25
26
27
28
Denial of Essential Facilities
conduct.
[An essential facilities] theory is a variation on a [unilateral] refusal
to deal claim. It imposes liability where competitors are denied
access to an input that is deemed essential, or critical, to
competition. Although the Supreme Court has never recognized the
doctrine, [the Ninth Circuit has] continued to treat it as having a
basis in § 2 of the Sherman Act.
To establish a violation of the essential facilities doctrine, [a
plaintiff] must show (1) that [the defendant] is a monopolist in
15
Case 3:17-cv-03301-EMC Document 158 Filed 09/09/20 Page 16 of 21
control of an essential facility, (2) that [the plaintiff], as [the
defendant’s] competitor, is unable reasonably or practically to
duplicate the facility, (3) that [the defendant] has refused to provide
[the plaintiff] access to the facility, and (4) that it is feasible for [the
defendant] to provide such access. Because mandating access, as
the essential facilities doctrine implies, shares the same concerns as
mandating dealing with a competitor, a facility is essential “only if
control of the facility carries with it the power to eliminate
competition in the downstream market.”
1
2
3
4
5
6
Aerotec, 836 F.3d at 1184-85; see also Alaska Airlines, Inc. v. United Airlines, Inc., 948 F.2d 536,
7
544 (9th Cir. 1991) (stating that “[a] facility that is controlled by a single firm will be considered
8
‘essential’ only if control of the facility carries with it the power to eliminate competition in the
9
downstream market”).
10
In the instant case, hiQ asserts that LinkedIn’s social networking platform amounts to an
United States District Court
Northern District of California
11
essential facility. However, the Court cannot assess the viability of hiQ’s essential facilities
12
argument without there first being a properly defined downstream market (i.e., the people
13
analytics market). The Court therefore dismisses the essential facilities theory based on a failure
14
to adequately allege a people analytics market.
15
3.
16
In the FAC, hiQ further alleges anticompetitive conduct on the basis that
17
Lock-In
LinkedIn lured users desiring professional social networking
services into joining LinkedIn with the promise that their
employment information would be their own and could be publicly
shared and accessed. . . . At a certain point, LinkedIn’s growth and
dominance became self-reinforcing, meaning that users needed to
stay a part of its professional social network platform, or else be
excluded from the largest and most useful professional social
network in the world.
18
19
20
21
22
FAC ¶ 116. Allegedly, a similar lure and lock into the network took place with respect to
23
employers: “LinkedIn promised prospective employer members that they could access users’
24
public employment information without restriction.” FAC ¶ 117. According to hiQ, “[o]nce users
25
were locked into its professional social network platform, LinkedIn utilized the power that lock-in
26
conferred in order to advantage itself to the exclusion of its people analytics competitors . . . .”
27
FAC ¶ 118.
28
In its motion to dismiss, LinkedIn argues that hiQ’s lock-in theory should be rejected as it
16
Case 3:17-cv-03301-EMC Document 158 Filed 09/09/20 Page 17 of 21
1
fails to map onto the “classic” lock-in situation “where a consumer buys one product from a
2
company, and then, without warning, is forced to buy aftermarket products or services from that
3
same company at monopolistic prices in order to use the product.” Mot. at 28 (citing Eastman
4
Kodak Co. v. Image Tech. Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451, 476 (1992)). In response, hiQ contends that
5
there must be a flexible approach in evaluating whether conduct is anticompetitive. See Avaya
6
Inc., RP v. Telecom Labs, Inc., 838 F.3d 354, 404 (3d Cir. 2016) (noting that the court had
7
previously “declined to read Kodak as applying narrowly to only cases involving ‘[a]n aftermarket
8
policy change’”).
While hiQ makes a fair point regarding flexibility, it is still invoking the concept of a lock-
10
in as a basis for the antitrust violation – and a lock-in typically means that a locked-in consumer is
11
United States District Court
Northern District of California
9
exploited, as even the Third Circuit case cited by hiQ indicates. See id. (stating that, under Kodak,
12
“exploitation of locked-in customers is one theory that courts will recognize to justify [antitrust]
13
liability” for conduct in an aftermarket related to a primary market) (emphasis added); see also
14
Mich. Div. – Monument Builders of N. Am. v. Mich. Cemetery Ass’n, 524 F.3d 726, 737 (6th Cir.
15
2008) (noting that “[m]arket power may exist in a lock-in case where once a customer buys one
16
product, he or she is locked in to buying another product because of the seller’s rules”); Xerox
17
Corp. v. Media Scis., Inc., 660 F. Supp. 2d 535, 546-47 (S.D.N.Y. 2009) (noting that post-Kodak
18
decisions “establish that for a nonmonopolist producer of a durable good to be held to have
19
monopoly power in the aftermarket for parts, service, or supplies, a plaintiff generally must show
20
that (i) customers who own the good are ‘locked in’ by the prohibitive costs of switching to an
21
alternate product, and (ii) the lock-in permitted those customers to be exploited”). In the instant
22
case, hiQ has not explained how LinkedIn has exploited its locked-in customers (i.e., users).
23
Indeed, hiQ does not appear to claim any exploitation of locked-in customers; instead, it suggests
24
that LinkedIn has used the lock-in to harm people analytics providers. See Opp’n at 22. Similar
25
to the problem with hiQ’s tying argument, see infra, this is not a case whether the same party
26
lured to do business with the defendant is then evoked in to purchase additional products and
27
serving from that defendant.
28
The Court therefore finds the lock-in theory implausible and without precedent and
17
Case 3:17-cv-03301-EMC Document 158 Filed 09/09/20 Page 18 of 21
1
dismisses it.
2
4.
Tying
3
“A tying arrangement is ‘an agreement by a party to sell one product but only on the
4
condition that the buyer also purchases a different (or tied) product, or at least agrees that he will
5
not purchase that product from any other supplier.’”6 Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at 461-62. “[I]f
6
the seller has ‘appreciable economic power’ in the tying product market and if the arrangement
7
affects a substantial volume of commerce in the tied market,” there is an antitrust violation. Id. at
8
462.
“The essential characteristic of an invalid tying arrangement lies in
the seller’s exploitation of its control over the tying product to force
the buyer into the purchase of a tied product that the buyer either did
not want at all, or might have preferred to purchase elsewhere on
different terms. When such ‘forcing’ is present, competition on the
merits in the market for the tied item is restrained and the Sherman
Act is violated.”
9
10
United States District Court
Northern District of California
11
12
13
Id. at 464 n.9.
14
In the FAC, hiQ alleges that the tying product is LinkedIn’s “professional social
15
networking platform” and the tied product is people analytics services. FAC ¶ 125. hiQ further
16
alleges that there is illegal tying because “LinkedIn has conditioned the provision of its dominant
17
professional social networking platform on the use of its people analytics services (or the non-use
18
of its competitors’ people analytics services).” FAC ¶ 126.
19
The tying claim, however, makes no sense. hiQ has not explained how LinkedIn has
20
essentially forced employers to purchase LinkedIn’s people analytics product (or forced employers
21
not to purchase other companies’ comparable products) in order for the employers to use
22
LinkedIn’s professional social networking platform. Again, there are two different consumer
23
groups: (1) those individuals who use LinkedIn’s professional social network, and (2) employers
24
25
26
27
28
6
A tying theory is usually brought under § 1 of the Sherman Act instead of § 2. See, e.g.,
Systemcare, Inc. v. Wang Labs. Corp., 117 F.3d 1137, 1142-43 (10th Cir. 1997) (“hold[ing] that a
contract between a buyer and seller satisfies the concerted action element of section 1 of the
Sherman Act where the seller coerces a buyer’s acquiescence in a tying arrangement imposed by
the seller[;] [t]he essence of section 1’s contract, combination, or conspiracy requirement in the
tying context is the agreement, however reluctant, of a buyer to purchase from a seller a tied
product or service along with a tying product or service”).
18
Case 3:17-cv-03301-EMC Document 158 Filed 09/09/20 Page 19 of 21
1
want to purchase people analytics products. As noted above, there is no tying of products directed
2
at the same consumer group.
3
5.
Vertically-Arranged Boycotts
4
hiQ’s theory of a vertical boycott suffers from a similar flaw as does its tying theory.
5
According to hiQ, “LinkedIn has induced, coerced, or otherwise forced LinkedIn members
6
(including without their knowledge) to boycott LinkedIn’s competitors for the people analytics
7
service.” FAC ¶ 142. But hiQ has failed to explain how LinkedIn was able to coerce its members;
8
there is no allegation that, e.g., LinkedIn does not allow anyone to use its professional social
9
networking platform if he/she/it purchases people analytics services from hiQ or any other
provider. In its opposition, hiQ argues that LinkedIn improperly prohibits its members from
11
United States District Court
Northern District of California
10
sharing their information as they choose (contrary to what it represented to members to lure them
12
in). But even if LinkedIn engaged in some kind of misconduct there, that does not explain how
13
any members were thereby forced to boycott hiQ’s or other companies’ people analytics services.
14
6.
Raising Rivals’ Costs
15
In the FAC, hiQ alleges that, “[b]y foreclosing people analytics competitors’ access to the
16
public employment information database on its site, LinkedIn raised those competitors’ costs to do
17
business.” FAC ¶ 121. As LinkedIn points out in its papers, this theory seems to be nothing more
18
than a unilateral refusal to deal, and this theory is problematic for the reasons discussed above.
19
In its opposition brief, hiQ tries to get around this problem by claiming that this theory is
20
based on both unilateral action by LinkedIn (a § 2 violation) and concerted action between
21
LinkedIn and its members (a § 1 violation). See Opp’n at 18 (arguing that the refusal-to-deal
22
standard discussed above “applies only to unilateral conduct” and not to concerted conduct).
23
According to hiQ, this theory involves concerted action because LinkedIn’s User Agreement
24
“prevent[s] people analytic providers [as users] from accessing [other] users’ otherwise public
25
employment” and, by relying on the User Agreement, “LinkedIn artificially raised its people
26
analytics’ competitors’ costs and pushed them out of the market.” Opp’n at 19. But the § 1 claim,
27
as pled in the FAC, is based only on tying and vertical boycotts. See FAC ¶ 162 (“These
28
contracts, combinations, or conspiracies include but are not limited to tying arrangements and
19
Case 3:17-cv-03301-EMC Document 158 Filed 09/09/20 Page 20 of 21
1
vertically-arranged boycotts.”). No viable Section 1 claim is stated. Even if that were not the
2
case, § 1 claims typically involve concerted action between multiple defendants or between a
3
defendant and a third party that harms the plaintiff – not concerted action between the defendant
4
and the plaintiff. hiQ cites no precedent for this novel theory.
5
7.
6
Finally, LinkedIn attacks the leveraging theory tendered by hiQ. With respect to
7
Leveraging
leveraging, hiQ alleges as follows in the FAC:
8
11
LinkedIn has used its monopoly power in [the market for
professional social networking platforms] in a predatory,
exclusionary, and anticompetitive manner to monopolize the people
analytics services market and exclude competitors from that market,
including but not limited to by means of lock-in, raising rivals’
costs, tying, unilateral refusal to deal, denial of essential facilities,
and vertically-arranged boycotts.
12
FAC ¶ 114. LinkedIn argues that, based on the above allegation, the leveraging theory is simply a
13
derivative theory. LinkedIn emphasizes that the fact of leveraging, in and of itself, does not give
14
rise to a viable claim; rather, there must also be some anticompetitive conduct. See Doe v. Abbott
15
Labs., 571 F.3d 930, 931 (9th Cir. 2009) (holding that “allegations of monopoly leveraging
16
through pricing conduct in two markets [does not] state a claim under § 2 of the Sherman Act,
17
absent an antitrust refusal to deal (or some other exclusionary practice) in the monopoly market or
18
below-cost pricing in the second market”). hiQ does not disagree that there be anticompetitive
19
conduct in order for there to be a viable leveraging theory. This makes sense because an antitrust
20
violation requires that there be anticompetitive conduct and leveraging by itself is not inherently
21
anticompetitive in nature.
9
United States District Court
Northern District of California
10
22
Accordingly, as LinkedIn argues, the leveraging theory rises or falls with the other theories
23
identified above.
24
8.
25
For the foregoing reasons, the Court finds each theory of anticompetitive conduct
Summary
26
implausible. The Court further finds the majority of these theories futile. The only theories where
27
hiQ may be able to allege a plausible claim for relief are (1) the unilateral refusal to deal and (2)
28
the essential facilities doctrine. The Court shall allow amendment on these two theories, although
20
Case 3:17-cv-03301-EMC Document 158 Filed 09/09/20 Page 21 of 21
1
it notes it is skeptical of the refusal-to-deal theory in light of the narrowness of the Aspen Skiing
2
exception.7
III.
3
CONCLUSION
4
LinkedIn’s motion to dismiss is granted in part and denied in part.
5
The motion to dismiss the interference claims is denied as they are not barred by the
6
Noerr-Pennington doctrine or the California litigation privilege.
7
The motion to dismiss the antitrust claims is granted. hiQ has failed to adequately allege a
8
product market (i.e., the people analytics market). In addition, hiQ has failed to adequately allege
9
anticompetitive conduct. The Court shall give hiQ leave to amend its antitrust claims, but only to
the extent they are based on the theories of unilateral refusal to deal and the essential facilities
11
United States District Court
Northern District of California
10
doctrine. The other theories are futile.
hiQ shall have four weeks to file an amended complaint. LinkedIn shall have four weeks
12
13
thereafter to respond to the amended complaint.
This order disposes of Docket No. 137.
14
15
IT IS SO ORDERED.
16
17
18
Dated: September 9, 2020
19
______________________________________
EDWARD M. CHEN
United States District Judge
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
7
Because hiQ has not pled plausible anticompetitive conduct in the first place, the Court does not
address LinkedIn’s additional contention that hiQ has failed to adequately allege antitrust injury.
21
Disclaimer: Justia Dockets & Filings provides public litigation records from the federal appellate and district courts. These filings and docket sheets should not be considered findings of fact or liability, nor do they necessarily reflect the view of Justia.
Why Is My Information Online?