O'Bannon, Jr. v. National Collegiate Athletic Association et al
Filing
291
FINDINGS OF FACT AND CONCLUSIONS OF LAW. Signed by Judge Claudia Wilken on 8/8/2014. (ndr, COURT STAFF) (Filed on 8/8/2014)
1
IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
2
FOR THE NORTHERN DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA
3
4
EDWARD O’BANNON, et al.
Plaintiffs,
5
6
7
8
9
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
FINDINGS OF FACT
AND CONCLUSIONS OF
LAW
v.
NATIONAL COLLEGIATE ATHLETIC
ASSOCIATION; ELECTRONIC ARTS
INC.; and COLLEGIATE LICENSING
COMPANY,
Defendants.
________________________________/
11
12
No. C 09-3329 CW
INTRODUCTION
Competition takes many forms.
Although this case raises
13
questions about athletic competition on the football field and the
14
basketball court, it is principally about the rules governing
15
competition in a different arena -- namely, the marketplace.
16
Plaintiffs are a group of current and former college student-
17
athletes.
18
National Collegiate Athletic Association (NCAA) in 2009 to
19
challenge the association’s rules restricting compensation for
20
elite men’s football and basketball players.
21
Plaintiffs seek to challenge the set of rules that bar student-
22
athletes from receiving a share of the revenue that the NCAA and
23
its member schools earn from the sale of licenses to use the
24
student-athletes’ names, images, and likenesses in videogames,
25
live game telecasts, and other footage.
26
these rules violate the Sherman Antitrust Act.
27
this charge and asserts that its restrictions on student-athlete
28
They brought this antitrust class action against the
In particular,
Plaintiffs contend that
The NCAA denies
1
compensation are necessary to uphold its educational mission and
2
to protect the popularity of collegiate sports.
3
A non-jury trial on Plaintiffs’ claims was held between June
4
9, 2014 and June 27, 2014.
5
testimony, documentary evidence, and arguments of counsel
6
presented during and after trial, the Court finds that the
7
challenged NCAA rules unreasonably restrain trade in the market
8
for certain educational and athletic opportunities offered by NCAA
9
Division I schools.
After considering all of the
The procompetitive justifications that the
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
NCAA offers do not justify this restraint and could be achieved
11
through less restrictive means.
12
findings of fact and conclusions of law, and will enter as a
13
remedy a permanent injunction prohibiting certain overly
14
restrictive restraints.
15
16
The Court makes the following
FINDINGS OF FACT
I.
Background
17
A.
18
The NCAA was founded in 1905 by the presidents of sixty-two
The NCAA
19
colleges and universities in order to create a uniform set of
20
rules to regulate intercollegiate football.
21
Undisputed Facts, at ¶ 6.
22
eleven hundred member schools and regulates intercollegiate
23
athletic competitions in roughly two dozen sports.
24
its current constitution, the association seeks to “initiate,
25
stimulate and improve intercollegiate athletics programs for
26
student-athletes and to promote and develop educational
27
leadership, physical fitness, athletics excellence and athletics
Docket No. 189, Stip.
Today, the association has roughly
28
2
According to
1
participation as a recreational pursuit.”
2
Division I Manual, at 15.
3
Ex. 2340, 2013-14 NCAA
1
To achieve these goals, the NCAA issues and enforces rules
4
governing athletic competitions among its member schools.
5
4.
6
bylaws and cover a broad range of subjects.
7
the rules establish academic eligibility requirements for student-
8
athletes, set forth guidelines and restrictions for recruiting
9
high school athletes, and impose limits on the number and size of
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
Id. at
These rules are outlined in the association’s constitution and
Among other things,
athletic scholarships that each school may provide.
11
Id. at 3-5.
Since 1973, the NCAA’s member schools have been organized
12
into three divisions -- Divisions I, II, and III -- based on the
13
number and quality of opportunities that they provide to
14
participate in intercollegiate athletics.
15
¶ 27.
16
quality of opportunities to participate in intercollegiate
17
athletics because they sponsor more sports teams and provide more
18
financial aid to student-athletes than schools in Divisions II and
19
III.2
20
sponsor a minimum of fourteen varsity sports teams, including
21
football, and distribute a baseline amount of financial aid to its
22
student-athletes.
23
365, 367.
Stip. Undisputed Facts
Division I schools provide the greatest number and highest
To qualify for membership in Division I, a school must
Trial Tr. 2043:13-:25 (Delany); Ex. 2340 at
Roughly three-hundred and fifty of the NCAA’s eleven
24
25
26
27
28
1
All exhibit citations in this order are to the page numbers
provided by the parties at trial, which do not necessarily correspond to
the page numbers created by the original author of the exhibit.
2 The NCAA’s bylaws define financial aid to mean “funds provided to
student-athletes from various sources to pay or assist in paying their
cost of education at the institution.” Ex. 2340 at 206. The Court
adopts this definition for the purposes of this order.
3
1
hundred schools currently compete in Division I.
2
1743:23 (Emmert).
Trial Tr.
3
Division I itself further is divided, for the purposes of
4
football competition, into two subdivisions: the Football Bowl
5
Subdivision (FBS) and the Football Championship Subdivision
6
(FCS).
7
schools are allowed to offer up to eighty-five full scholarships
8
to members of their football teams.
9
permitted to offer only a smaller number of full scholarships to
3
Trial Tr. 2144:9-:11 (Petr); Ex. 2340 at 364-67.
FBS
In contrast, FCS schools are
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
members of their teams.
11
schools are able to offer more football scholarships than FCS
12
schools, the level of football competition within FBS is generally
13
higher than within FCS.
Currently, about one hundred and twenty
14
schools compete in FBS.
Id. ¶ 45.
15
Stip. Undisputed Facts ¶ 28.
Because FBS
In addition to the two football subdivisions, Division I
16
schools are also organized into a number of conferences, which
17
essentially function as smaller leagues within the NCAA.
18
conferences -- most of which contain between eight and fifteen
19
schools -- typically have their own membership requirements.
20
conferences also organize conference-specific games and events
21
featuring their member schools, including regular season football
22
games, regular season basketball games, and post-season basketball
23
tournaments.
24
the NCAA and must comply with its constitution and bylaws, they
25
operate independently for the most part and have the authority to
The
Most
Although the conferences are considered members of
26
3
27
28
Prior to 2006, FBS was known as Division I-A and FCS was known as
Division I-AA. For the purposes of simplicity, this order uses “FBS”
and “FCS” to refer to these subdivisions even when discussing studentathletes who played Division I football before 2006.
4
1
generate their own revenue and set their own rules, provided those
2
rules are consistent with NCAA policy.
3
Ex. 2340 at 22.
The rules governing participation and competition in Division
4
I are enacted by an eighteen-member body known as the Division I
5
Board of Directors, which typically receives proposals from the
6
division’s member schools and conferences.
7
1745:2 (Emmert); Ex. 2340 at 35.
8
university presidents and chancellors from eighteen different
9
colleges or universities.
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
Trial Tr. 1744:16-
The Board is made up of
Ex. 2340 at 35.
A school or conference that seeks to propose a new rule or
11
rule change typically does so by submitting the proposal to a
12
designated committee or task force appointed by the Board.
13
Tr. 1745:20-1746:15.
14
the proposal and, if it approves, may forward the proposal to a
15
body known as the Division I Legislative Council, which is made up
16
of athletics administrators from schools in each of the thirty-two
17
Division I conferences.
18
Council may then forward the proposal to the Board of Directors,
19
which has the ultimate authority to approve the proposal by a
20
majority vote.
21
may only be repealed through an override process that involves a
22
vote of sixty-two percent of the NCAA’s member institutions.
23
1747:6-:20.
24
not have any voting power in this process.
Trial
That committee or task force then considers
Id.; Ex. 2340 at 37.
Trial Tr. 1745:20-1746:15.
The Legislative
Actions by the Board
Id.
The NCAA’s current president, Dr. Mark Emmert, does
Id. 1746:19-:24.
25
B.
26
Electronic Arts Inc. (EA) is a corporation which develops and
Electronic Arts Inc. & Collegiate Licensing Company
27
manufactures videogames.
28
and sold an annual NCAA-branded college football videogame every
Stip. Undisputed Facts ¶ 35.
5
It created
1
year between 1997 and 2013.
2
an annual NCAA-branded college basketball game every year between
3
1998 and 2010.
4
entered into licensing agreements with the NCAA and its member
5
schools and paid them for permission to use their intellectual
6
property, including their marks, in the videogames.
7
Exs. 1125, 1126.
8
corporation that licenses trademarks of the NCAA and several of
9
its member schools and conferences.
Id. ¶ 40.
Id. ¶ 39.
It also created and sold
In order to create these games, it
Id. ¶¶ 37-38;
Collegiate Licensing Company (CLC) is a Georgia
Stip. Undisputed Facts ¶¶ 32-
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
34.
11
and CLC in this action, they subsequently agreed to settle those
12
claims.
13
C.
14
Plaintiffs are twenty current and former student-athletes,
Although Plaintiffs originally brought claims against both EA
Plaintiffs
15
all of whom play or played for an FBS football or Division I men’s
16
basketball team between 1956 and the present.
17
Plaintiffs went on to play professional sports after they left
18
college.
19
certified under Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 23(b)(2) in
20
November 2013:
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
Some, but not all,
They represent the following class, which this Court
All current and former student-athletes
residing in the United States who compete on,
or competed on, an NCAA Division I (formerly
known as “University Division” before 1973)
college or university men’s basketball team or
on an NCAA Football Bowl Subdivision (formerly
known as Division I-A until 2006) men’s
football team and whose images, likenesses
and/or names may be, or have been, included or
could have been included (by virtue of their
appearance in a team roster) in game footage
or in videogames licensed or sold by
Defendants, their co-conspirators, or their
licensees.
6
1
Case No. 09-1967, Docket No. 1025, April 11, 2014 Order, at 47-48
2
(amending definition of previously certified class).
3
II.
The Relevant Markets
4
As explained in previous orders, Plaintiffs allege that the
5
NCAA has restrained trade in two related national markets, which
6
they refer to as the “college education market” and the “group
7
licensing market.”
8
the same participants, each market ultimately involves a different
9
set of buyers, sellers, and products.
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
Although these alleged markets involve many of
Accordingly, this order
addresses each market separately.
11
A.
12
The evidence presented at trial, including testimony from
College Education Market
13
both experts and lay witnesses, establishes that FBS football and
14
Division I basketball schools compete to recruit the best high
15
school football and basketball players.
16
(O’Bannon); 114:21-117:17 (Noll); 831:8-:11 (Rascher); 1759:21-:22
17
(Emmert); Ex. 2530.
18
unique bundles of goods and services to elite football and
19
basketball recruits.
20
the cost of tuition, fees, room and board, books, certain school
21
supplies, tutoring, and academic support services.
22
40:2-:20 (O’Bannon); 582:6-:18 (Prothro); 1741:10-:20 (Emmert);
23
Ex. 2340 at 207.
24
coaching, medical treatment, state-of-the-art athletic facilities,
25
and opportunities to compete at the highest level of college
26
sports, often in front of large crowds and television audiences.
27
Trial Tr. 13:4-:12 (O’Bannon); 556:8-558:2 (Prothro); 1157:20-
28
1158:7 (Staurowsky); 1721:3-1722:19 (Emmert).
Trial Tr. 9:1-:7
Specifically, these schools compete to sell
The bundles include scholarships to cover
Trial Tr.
They also include access to high-quality
7
In exchange for
1
these unique bundles of goods and services, football and
2
basketball recruits must provide their schools with their athletic
3
services and acquiesce in the use of their names, images, and
4
likenesses for commercial and promotional purposes.
5
110:12 (Noll).
6
attending college and participating in intercollegiate athletics
7
that are not covered by their scholarships.
8
9
Id. 109:5-
They also implicitly agree to pay any costs of
See Ex. 2340 at 207.
The evidence presented at trial demonstrates that FBS
football and Division I basketball schools are the only suppliers
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
of the unique bundles of goods and services described above.
11
Recruits who are skilled enough to play FBS football or Division I
12
basketball do not typically pursue other options for continuing
13
their education and athletic careers beyond high school.
14
Plaintiffs’ economic expert, Dr. Roger Noll, examined the rates at
15
which elite football and basketball recruits accept athletic
16
scholarships to play FBS football or Division I basketball.
17
observed that, between 2007 and 2011, more than ninety-eight
18
percent of football recruits classified as four- or five-star
19
recruits (the two highest ratings available) by Rivals.com
20
accepted offers to play FBS football.
21
2529.
22
recruits chose to play football at an FCS school and none chose to
23
play at a Division II or III school during that period.
24
Among three-star recruits, ninety-two percent of those offered a
25
scholarship from an FBS school accepted one.
26
percent of all three-star recruits accepted an offer to play
27
football at a non-FBS school.
He
Trial Tr. 113:2-114:13; Ex.
None of the five-star recruits and only 0.2% of four-star
Id.
28
8
Id.
Ex. 2529.
Less than four
1
This pattern is even more stark for basketball recruits.
2
Between 2007 and 2011, no four- or five-star basketball recruits
3
and less than one percent of all two- and three-star recruits
4
accepted offers to play for a non-Division I school.
5
among zero-star recruits, only one percent accepted offers to play
6
basketball outside of Division I.
7
ninety-five percent of all recruits offered Division I basketball
8
scholarships in the Rivals.com sample accepted one.
9
data supports Dr. Noll’s conclusion that “if the top athletes are
Id.
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
Even
In contrast, roughly
10
offered a D-I scholarship, they take it.
11
else.”
12
Id.
Id.
This
They do not go anywhere
Trial Tr. 114:6-:7.
On cross-examination, Dr. Noll conceded that the Rivals.com
13
data he used in his analysis came from recruits’ self-reported
14
information about the scholarship offers they received and
15
accepted.
16
Noll’s opinion unreliable.
17
report accurate information to Rivals.com because the information
18
is relatively easy to verify; after all, a recruit’s lie about
19
accepting a scholarship from a particular school will be
20
discovered as soon as his name does not appear on that school’s
21
roster or list of committed recruits.
22
not presented any data of its own to contradict the Rivals.com
23
data nor any other evidence, expert or otherwise, to cast doubt on
24
Dr. Noll’s conclusion that there are no substitutes for the
25
opportunities offered by FBS football and Division I basketball
26
schools.
27
28
Id. 486:7-:9.
However, this fact does not render Dr.
Recruits have a strong incentive to
In any event, the NCAA has
The only potential substitutes that the NCAA has identified
are the opportunities offered by schools in other divisions,
9
1
collegiate athletics associations, or minor and foreign
2
professional sports leagues.
3
associations, or professional leagues, however, provides the same
4
combination of goods and services offered by FBS football and
5
Division I basketball schools.
6
and III all provide a lower number of scholarships than FBS
7
football and Division I basketball schools, which results in a
8
lower level of athletic competition.
9
Athletic Association (NAIA), National Junior College Athletic
None of these other divisions,
Schools in FCS and Divisions II
The National Intercollegiate
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
Association (NJCAA), National Christian Collegiate Athletic
11
Association (NCCAA), and United States Collegiate Athletic
12
Association (USCAA) likewise provide fewer scholarships and offer
13
a lower level of competition.
14
other divisions and associations are often smaller than FBS
15
football and Division I basketball schools, spend much less on
16
athletics, and may not even provide opportunities to attend a
17
four-year college.
18
2830:12 (Stiroh).
19
schools do not compete with FBS football and Division I basketball
20
schools for recruits.
21
What’s more, the schools in these
Id. 2824:14-:24, 2826:16-2827:7, 2829:17This is why, as Dr. Noll concluded, these other
Dr. Noll also analyzed the Rivals.com data to show that FBS
22
schools almost always defeated non-FBS schools in head-to-head
23
recruiting contests for the same football recruit between 2007 and
24
2011.
25
head-to-head recruiting contests for basketball players revealed
26
the same discrepancy between Division I and non-Division I
27
schools.
28
this discrepancy when comparing head-to-head recruiting contests
Id. 116:6-118:11, 474:23-475:14; Ex. 2530.
Trial Tr. 116:6-118:11.
10
His analysis of
Notably, he did not observe
1
among FBS football schools or Division I basketball schools.
2
Ex. 2530 at 3.
3
within the five major Division I conferences -- namely, the
4
Pacific 12 Conference (Pac 12), Big 12 Conference, Atlantic Coast
5
Conference, Southeastern Conference (SEC), and Big 10
6
Conference -- to that of schools in less prominent Division I
7
conferences, he found that they were still in competition with
8
each other.
9
other divisions and junior colleges and NAIA and all the rest that
Id.;
Even when he compared the success of the schools
Trial Tr. 116:9-:13 (“And unlike the finding for
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
was in the first picture, what we find here is that although the
11
major conferences win more than they lose, in competing against
12
the lesser conferences, there is considerable competitive
13
overlap.”).
14
schools in FCS, Divisions II and III, and other non-NCAA
15
collegiate athletics associations are not substitutes for the
16
bundles of goods and services offered by FBS football and Division
17
I basketball schools.
18
Thus, the bundles of goods and services offered by
Nor are the opportunities offered by the professional leagues
19
that the NCAA has identified here.
20
football and basketball recruits rarely forego opportunities to
21
play FBS football or Division I basketball in order to play
22
professionally.
23
the National Basketball Association (NBA) permits players to enter
24
the league immediately after high school.
25
(O’Bannon).
26
NBA Development League (D-League), the Arena Football League
27
(AFL), and certain foreign football and basketball leagues --
28
permit players to join immediately after high school, recruits do
Dr. Noll noted that elite
Neither the National Football League (NFL) nor
Id. 68:17-69:6
Although other professional leagues -- such as the
11
1
not typically pursue opportunities in those leagues.
2
482:11-:13 (Noll).
3
an analysis of recruits who chose to play professionally in these
4
leagues, he replied that too few had ever done so to conduct such
5
an analysis.
6
analysis of zero.”).
7
even be given an opportunity to play in these leagues.
8
482:14-:17 (“The opportunity is not given to very many high school
9
athletes to play in Europe.”).
Id.
When Dr. Noll was asked why he did not conduct
Id. 484:19-485:13 (“It would be hard to do an
He also noted that many recruits may not
Id.
What’s more, none of these leagues
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
offers the same opportunity to earn a higher education that FBS
11
football and Division I basketball schools provide.
12
these reasons, the Court finds that there are no professional
13
football or basketball leagues capable of supplying a substitute
14
for the bundle of goods and services that FBS football and
15
Division I basketball schools provide.
16
relevant college education market, as described above.
For all of
These schools comprise a
17
B.
18
Professional athletes often sell group licenses to use their
19
names, images, and likenesses in live game telecasts, videogames,
20
game re-broadcasts, advertisements, and other archival footage.4
21
Plaintiffs allege that, in the absence of the NCAA’s challenged
22
rules, FBS football and Division I basketball players would also
23
be able to sell group licenses for the use of their names, images,
Group Licensing Market
24
4
25
26
27
28
Plaintiffs presented some evidence at trial of a market for
licenses to use student-athletes’ names, images, and likenesses in other
merchandise, such as jerseys and bobbleheads. The Court does not
address this market because Plaintiffs previously abandoned all of their
claims related to such markets. Docket No. 827, June 20, 2013 Hrg. Tr.
54:13-:16. In addition, the evidence they presented at trial regarding
merchandise-related licenses did not constitute proof of a market for
group licenses but, rather, only individual licenses.
12
1
and likenesses.
2
certain FBS football and Division I basketball teams would be able
3
to join together to offer group licenses, which they would then be
4
able to sell to their respective schools, third-party licensing
5
companies, or media companies seeking to use student-athletes’
6
names, images, and likenesses.
7
submarkets within this broader group licensing market: (1) a
8
submarket for group licenses to use student-athletes’ names,
9
images, and likenesses in live football and basketball game
Specifically, they contend that members of
Plaintiffs have identified three
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
telecasts; (2) a submarket for group licenses to use student-
11
athletes’ names, images, and likenesses in videogames; and (3) a
12
submarket for group licenses to use student-athletes’ names,
13
images, and likenesses in game re-broadcasts, advertisements, and
14
other archival footage.
15
1.
16
17
Submarket for Group Licenses to Use StudentAthletes’ Names, Images, and Likenesses in Live
Game Telecasts
The Court finds that a submarket exists in which television
18
networks seek to acquire group licenses to use FBS football and
19
Division I basketball players’ names, images, and likenesses in
20
live game telecasts.
21
licensing agreements to use the intellectual property of schools,
22
conferences, and event organizers -- such as the NCAA or a bowl
23
committee -- in live telecasts of football and basketball games.
24
In these agreements, the networks often seek to acquire the rights
25
to use the names, images, and likenesses of the participating
26
student-athletes during the telecast.
27
1994 licensing agreement granting CBS the rights to telecast the
Television networks frequently enter into
28
13
For instance, the NCAA’s
1
Division I men’s basketball tournament every year from 1995 to
2
2002 includes a “Name & Likeness” provision that states:
3
The Network, its sponsors, their advertising
representatives and the stations carrying the
telecasts of the games will have the right to
make appropriate references (including without
limitation, use of pictures) to NCAA and the
universities and colleges of the teams, the
sites, the games and the participants in and
others identified with the games and in the
telecasting thereof, provided that the same do
not constitute endorsements of a commercial
product.
4
5
6
7
8
9
Ex. 2104 at 16 (emphasis added).
A 1999 agreement between the
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
NCAA and CBS for the rights to telecast certain Division I
11
basketball games contains a “Name & Likeness” provision with
12
nearly identical language.
13
make appropriate references (including without limitation, use of
14
pictures) to . . . the participants in and others identified with
15
the games” (emphasis added)).
16
conferences, the University of Notre Dame, and Fox Broadcasting
17
Company for the rights to telecast certain 2007, 2008, and 2009
18
bowl games similarly provides that the event organizer will be
19
solely responsible for ensuring that Fox has “the rights to use
20
the name and likeness, photographs and biographies of all
21
participants, game officials, cheerleaders” and other individuals
22
connected to the game.
23
other contracts containing similar language.
24
at 10 (granting the broadcaster “all name and likeness rights of
25
all participants, officials, competing teams and any other persons
26
connected with the Events that are reasonable or necessary for the
27
Telecast of the Events”); Ex. 3078 at 2-3 (providing that the Big
28
10 would use “reasonable commercial efforts” to obtain from any
Ex. 2116 at 17 (granting the “right to
An agreement between the FBS
Ex. 2162 at 9.
14
Plaintiffs also provided
See, e.g., Ex. 2230
1
non-conference opponent the “right . . . to use its respective
2
players’ names, likenesses, and that school’s trademarks, logos
3
and other items in promoting, advertising and Telecasting any such
4
game”).
5
these rights among television networks.
These contracts demonstrate that there is a demand for
6
Plaintiffs’ broadcasting industry expert, Edwin Desser,
7
confirmed that provisions like these are common and that they have
8
economic value to television networks.
9
699:18-700:3, 681:18-:23 (“If you’re running a business like a
Trial Tr. 651:9-:11,
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
television network, a broadcast station, you would prefer to have
11
consents, and you would like to have somebody stand behind those
12
consents so that you don’t have to worry about somebody coming
13
after you later with a claim.”).
14
exists.
15
group licenses -- not individual licenses.
16
that a “television sports agreement is a bundle of rights and
17
responsibilities that are all interrelated and that, you know,
18
create value, provide comfort, and are [] integrated into the
19
agreement.”
20
student-athlete’s name, image, and likeness during a game telecast
21
would not have any value to a television network unless it was
22
bundled with licenses to use every other participating student-
23
athlete’s name, image, and likeness.
24
Thus, a market for these rights
Plaintiffs also demonstrated that this is a market for
Id. 658:14-:19.
Mr. Desser testified
A license to use an individual
The NCAA’s broadcasting industry expert, Neal Pilson,
25
testified that sports broadcasters need not acquire the rights to
26
use student-athletes’ names, images, and likenesses and that the
27
primary reason they enter into licensing agreements with event
28
organizers is to gain exclusive access to the facility where the
15
1
event will occur.
2
convincing.
3
certain rights even from visiting teams who do not control access
4
to the event facility.
5
that broadcasting agreements -- like those quoted above --
6
sometimes refer expressly to name, image, and likeness “rights.”
7
Id. 805:2-:16.
8
challenged NCAA rules, teams of FBS football and Division I
9
basketball players would be able to create and sell group licenses
Trial Tr. 720:5-:17.
This testimony is not
Mr. Pilson admitted that broadcasters must acquire
Id. 803:5-804:8.
He also acknowledged
Accordingly, the Court finds that, absent the
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
for the use of their names, images, and likenesses in live game
11
telecasts.
12
2.
Submarket for Group Licenses to Use StudentAthletes’ Names, Images, and Likenesses in
Videogames
13
14
Like television networks, videogame developers would seek to
15
acquire group licenses to use the names, images, and likenesses of
16
FBS football and Division I basketball players if the NCAA did not
17
prohibit student-athletes from selling such licenses.
18
make all of its sports-themed videogames “as authentic as
19
possible.”
20
presidents, Joel Linzner, explained, “We have found that it is
21
pleasing to our customers to be able to use the real athletes
22
depicted as realistically as possible and acting as realistically
23
as possible.”
24
(describing demand for use of student-athletes’ names, images, and
25
likenesses in videogames).
26
negotiates licenses with professional sports leagues and teams to
27
use their trademarks, logos, and other intellectual property in
28
videogames.
Trial Tr. 1656:7 (Linzner).
EA seeks to
One of the company’s vice
Id. 1658:3-:6; see also Ex. 2007 at 50-54
To do this, the company typically
Trial Tr. 1656:10-1657:25.
16
It also negotiates with
1
groups of professional athletes for licenses to use their names,
2
images, and likenesses.
3
the same rights from student-athletes in order to produce college
4
sports-themed videogames, if it were permitted to do so.
5
1669:24-1670:24.
6
challenged NCAA rules, there would be a demand among videogame
7
developers for group licenses to use student-athletes’ names,
8
images, and likenesses.
9
Id.
EA would be interested in acquiring
Id.
Accordingly, the Court finds that, absent the
The NCAA asserts that such demand would not exist because it
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
has ceased licensing its intellectual property for use in
11
videogames, making it unlikely that any developer would seek to
12
develop a videogame using the names, images, and likenesses of
13
student-athletes.
14
record.
15
with EA, it has not presented any evidence suggesting that it will
16
never enter into such an agreement again in the future.
17
its current bylaws preclude it from entering into such an
18
agreement.
19
demonstrates that, prior to this litigation, the NCAA found it
20
profitable to license its intellectual property for use in
21
videogames.
22
agreement with EA, even as the company evaded the NCAA’s rules
23
prohibiting it from using student-athletes’ images and likenesses
24
in videogames.
25
videogames featured playable avatars that could easily be
26
identified as real student-athletes despite the NCAA’s express
27
prohibition on featuring student-athletes in videogames.
28
avatars played the same positions as their real-life counterparts,
This assertion is not supported by the trial
Although the NCAA recently declined to renew its license
None of
Furthermore, the evidence presented at trial
Indeed, it continued to renew its annual licensing
Throughout the late 2000s, EA’s NCAA-branded
17
The EA
1
wore the same jersey numbers and uniform accessories, haled from
2
the same home state, and shared the same height, weight,
3
handedness, and skin color.
4
568:6-569:24 (Prothro); 930:5-931:7 (Rascher).
5
reasons, the Court finds that a submarket would exist for group
6
licenses to use student-athletes’ names, images, and likenesses in
7
videogames if student-athletes were permitted to receive
8
compensation for such licenses.
9
3.
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
Trial Tr. 27:14-28:11 (O’Bannon);
For all of these
Submarket for Group Licenses to Use StudentAthletes’ Names, Images, and Likenesses in Game ReBroadcasts, Advertisements, and Other Archival
Footage
Plaintiffs have shown that television networks, advertisers,
and third-party licensing companies seek to use archival footage
of student-athletes in game re-broadcasts, commercials, and other
products.
Several of the live telecasting agreements discussed
above included provisions granting the television network the
rights to use archival footage, as well.
See, e.g. Ex. 3078 at 2-
3 (granting the Big 10 Network the rights to use certain studentathletes’ names and likenesses in “promoting, advertising and
Telecasting” a game); Ex. 2230 at 2 (granting Fox Sports Net the
“right to re-Telecast the Selected Events,” the “right to
distribute highlights of the Selected Events,” and the specific
right to use the “names and likenesses of the players” to promote
certain games as well as the network itself).
Tyrone Prothro, a
former wide receiver for the University of Alabama, saw footage in
a commercial of a famous catch that he made during a game.
Tr. 565:24-566:8.
Trial
Finally, one of the NCAA’s vice presidents,
Mark Lewis, established that the NCAA has licensed all of its
18
1
archival footage from past NCAA championships to a third-party
2
licensing company, T3Media, which acts as the association’s agent
3
in licensing that footage for use in game re-broadcasts,
4
advertisements, and any other products.
5
Although T3Media is not permitted to license footage of current
6
student-athletes, it still acquires the rights to this footage
7
while the student-athletes are in school for later use (after
8
acquiring the student-athletes’ consent).
9
that demand for this footage exists.
Id. 3206:13-:25.
This is enough to show
Based on this evidence, the
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
Court finds that, absent the NCAA’s challenged rules, there would
11
be a demand among television networks, third-party licensing
12
companies, and advertisers for group licenses to use student-
13
athletes in game re-broadcasts, advertisements, and other archival
14
footage.
15
III. The Challenged Restraint
16
NCAA rules prohibit current student-athletes from receiving
17
any compensation from their schools or outside sources for the use
18
of their names, images, and likenesses in live game telecasts,
19
videogames, game re-broadcasts, advertisements, and other footage.
20
Plaintiffs contend that these rules restrain trade in the two
21
markets identified above.
22
The NCAA imposes strict limits on the amount of compensation
23
that student-athletes may receive from their schools.
24
importantly, it prohibits any student-athlete from receiving
25
“financial aid based on athletics ability” that exceeds the value
26
of a full “grant-in-aid.”
27
full “grant-in-aid” as “financial aid that consists of tuition and
28
fees, room and board, and required course-related books.”
Ex. 2340 at 208.
19
Most
The bylaws define a
Id. at
1
207.
2
year.
3
this amount forfeits his athletic eligibility.
4
This amount varies from school to school and from year to
Any student-athlete who receives financial aid in excess of
Id. at 208.
In addition to this cap on athletics-based financial aid, the
5
NCAA also imposes a separate cap on the total amount of financial
6
aid that a student-athlete may receive.
7
prohibits any student-athlete from receiving financial aid in
8
excess of his “cost of attendance.”
9
term “grant-in-aid,” the term “cost of attendance” is a school-
Specifically, it
Ex. 2340 at 208.
Like the
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
specific figure defined in the bylaws.
11
calculated by [a school]’s financial aid office, using federal
12
regulations, that includes the total cost of tuition and fees,
13
room and board, books and supplies, transportation, and other
14
expenses related to attendance” at that school.
15
Because it covers the cost of “supplies, transportation, and other
16
expenses,” the cost of attendance is generally higher than the
17
value of a full grant-in-aid.
18
aid and the cost of attendance varies from school to school but is
19
typically a few thousand dollars.
20
It refers to “an amount
Id. at 206.
The gap between the full grant-in-
5
The NCAA also prohibits any student-athlete from receiving
21
compensation from outside sources based on his athletic skills or
22
ability.
6
Thus, while a student-athlete may generally earn money
23
5
24
25
26
27
28
Under certain circumstances, a student-athlete who has an
unexpected “special financial need” may be permitted to receive
additional aid beyond the cost of attendance. Trial Tr. 2144:252145:14 (Petr). This additional aid comes from his school’s “student
assistance fund” and could include money for “needed clothing, needed
supplies, a computer,” or other academic needs. Ex. 2340 at 238.
6 The NCAA’s bylaws contain a minor exception permitting studentathletes to receive limited compensation for educational expenses
“awarded by the U.S. Olympic Committee or a U.S. national governing
body.” Ex. 2340 at 211.
20
1
from any “on- or off-campus employment” unrelated to his athletic
2
ability, he may not receive “any remuneration for value or utility
3
that the student-athlete may have for the employer because of the
4
publicity, reputation, fame or personal following that he or she
5
has obtained because of athletics ability.”
6
athletes are also barred from endorsing any commercial product or
7
service while they are in school, regardless of whether or not
8
they receive any compensation to do so.
9
Id. at 211.
Student-
Id. at 86.
Dr. Noll testified that these rules restrain competition
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
among schools for recruits.
11
higher, schools would compete for the best recruits by offering
12
them larger grants-in-aid.
13
not capped at the cost of attendance, schools would compete for
14
the best recruits by offering them compensation exceeding the cost
15
of attendance.
16
that the recruits must pay for the combination of educational and
17
athletic opportunities that the schools provide.
18
explained, “if the scholarship value is suppressed, that means the
19
net price paid by a student-athlete to attend college is higher.”
20
Trial Tr. 105:24-107:1.
21
the power to and does suppress the value of athletic scholarships
22
through its grant-in-aid rules, it has increased the prices
23
schools charge recruits.
24
If the grant-in-aid limit were
Similarly, if total financial aid was
This competition would effectively lower the price
As Dr. Noll
Thus, he explained, because the NCAA has
Id. 127:20-129:13.
Dr. Noll’s opinions are consistent with the opinions of the
25
NCAA’s own economic expert, Dr. Daniel Rubinfeld, who testified
26
that the NCAA operates as a “joint venture which imposes
27
restraints” on trade.
28
specifically acknowledged that “the NCAA does impose a restraint,
Id. 2922:20-:21.
21
Dr. Rubinfeld
the restraint we have been discussing in this case.”
2
2921:8-:9.
3
because it serves procompetitive purposes, he never denied that
4
the NCAA restricts competition among its members for recruits.
5
fact, his own economics textbook specifically refers to the NCAA
6
as a “cartel,” which he defined during his testimony as “a group
7
of firms that impose a restraint.”
8
NCAA’s other economic expert, Dr. Lauren Stiroh, testified that
9
the NCAA does not restrain competition in any market, her opinions
10
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
1
were based on the theory that anticompetitive effects cannot arise
11
unless consumers in a “downstream market” are harmed.
12
2766:16-:22.
13
watch or attend college football and basketball games or purchase
14
goods using the names, images, and likenesses of student-athletes.
15
The Court rejects Dr. Stiroh’s theory that Plaintiffs cannot show
16
any anticompetitive effects caused by the alleged restraint
17
without demonstrating some harm to these consumers.
18
cited above demonstrates that student-athletes themselves are
19
harmed by the price-fixing agreement among FBS football and
20
Division I basketball schools.
21
represented by a recruit’s decision to attend and play for a
22
particular school, the school provides tuition, room and board,
23
fees, and book expenses, often at little or no cost to the school.
24
The recruit provides his athletic performance and the use of his
25
name, image, and likeness.
26
the latter at zero by agreeing not to compete with each other to
27
credit any other value to the recruit in the exchange.
28
anticompetitive effect.
Id.
Although he opined that this restraint was lawful
Id. 2975:3-:4.
In
Although the
Id.
In this case, those consumers would be people who
The evidence
In the complex exchange
However, the schools agree to value
This is an
Thus, the Court finds that the NCAA has
22
1
the power -- and exercises that power -- to fix prices and
2
restrain competition in the college education market that
3
Plaintiffs have identified.
4
Dr. Noll testified that elite football and basketball
5
recruits -- the buyers in Plaintiffs’ college education market --
6
could also be characterized as sellers in an almost identical
7
market for their athletic services and licensing rights.
8
143:21-144:8.
9
basketball schools are buyers seeking to acquire recruits’
Id.
In that market, FBS football and Division I
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
athletic services and licensing rights, paying for them with full
11
grants-in-aid but no more.
12
restrictions on student-athlete compensation still represent a
13
form of price fixing but create a buyers’ cartel, rather than a
14
sellers’ cartel.
15
schools would engage in price competition in the market for
16
recruits’ athletic services and licensing rights if there were no
17
restrictions on student-athlete compensation; the only difference
18
would be that they would be viewed as buyers in the transactions
19
rather than sellers.
20
market is essentially a mirror image of the market for recruits’
21
athletic services and licensing rights, the Court finds that the
22
NCAA exercises market power, fixes prices, and restrains
23
competition in both markets.
24
IV.
25
From that perspective, the NCAA’s
Just as in Plaintiffs’ college education market,
Thus, because Plaintiffs’ college education
Asserted Purposes of the Restraint
The NCAA asserts that the challenged restrictions on student-
26
athlete compensation are reasonable because they are necessary to
27
preserve its tradition of amateurism, maintain competitive balance
28
among FBS football and Division I basketball teams, promote the
23
1
integration of academics and athletics, and increase the total
2
output of its product.
3
A.
4
The NCAA asserts that its challenged rules promote consumer
5
demand for its product by preserving its tradition of amateurism
6
in college sports.
7
survey data, and lay witness testimony to support this assertion.
8
The Court does not find this evidence sufficient to justify the
9
challenged restraint.
Preservation of Amateurism
It relies on historical evidence, consumer
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
Dr. Emmert testified that “the rules over the hundred-year
11
history of the NCAA around amateurism have focused on, first of
12
all, making sure that any resources that are provided to a
13
student-athlete are only those that are focused on his or her
14
getting an education.”
15
evidence presented at trial, however, demonstrates that the
16
association’s amateurism rules have not been nearly as consistent
17
as Dr. Emmert represents.
18
numerous times since the NCAA -- then known as the Intercollegiate
19
Athletic Association (IAA) -- enacted its first set of bylaws in
20
1906.
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
Trial Tr. 1737:8-:12.
The historical
In fact, these rules have changed
The IAA’s first bylaws governing amateurism provided,
No student shall represent a College or
University in an intercollegiate game or
contest who is paid or receives, directly or
indirectly, any money or financial concession
or emolument as past or present compensation
for, or as prior consideration or inducement
to play in, or enter any athletic contest,
whether the said remuneration be received
from, or paid by, or at the instance of any
organization, committee or faculty of such
College or University, or any individual
whatever.
28
24
1
Stip. Undisputed Facts ¶¶ 6-7.
This rule would have barred even
2
today’s athletic scholarships.
Despite the breadth of this
3
written prohibition, the IAA’s member schools recruited students
4
using “player subsidies” and other illicit forms of payment.
5
¶ 10.
6
Id.
In 1916, after changing its name to the NCAA, the association
7
adopted a new rule stating that an amateur was “one who
8
participates in competitive physical sports only for pleasure, and
9
the physical, mental, moral, and social benefits directly derived
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
therefrom.”
11
define an amateur as “one who engages in sport solely for the
12
physical, mental or social benefits he derives therefrom, and to
13
whom the sport is nothing more than an avocation.”
14
Id.
The NCAA amended that definition in 1922 to
Id. ¶ 14.
Most schools continued to ignore these rules for the first
15
few decades of the NCAA’s existence.
16
1948, the NCAA enacted a strict set of rules known as the “Sanity
17
Code” designed to curb violations of its bylaws.
18
Sanity Code “required that financial aid be awarded without
19
consideration of athletics ability,” which, again, would have
20
prohibited today’s athletic scholarships.
21
the Sanity Code the following year and, in 1952, created its first
22
enforcement committee to address and prevent rules infractions.
23
Id. ¶ 24.
24
Id. ¶¶ 17-20.
Id.
Then, in
Id. ¶ 20.
The
The NCAA repealed
In 1956, the NCAA enacted a new set of amateurism rules
25
permitting schools to award athletic scholarships to student-
26
athletes.
27
governing athletics-based financial aid and imposed a limit on the
28
size of athletic scholarships that schools were permitted to
Id. ¶ 25.
These rules established a national standard
25
1
offer.
2
precluded student-athletes from receiving any financial aid beyond
3
that needed for “commonly accepted educational expenses,”
4
including tuition, fees, room and board, books, and cash for
5
incidental expenses such as laundry.
6
Id.
That limit -- now known as a full “grant-in-aid” --
Id.
The NCAA continued to revise its scholarship limits after
7
implementing the grant-in-aid limit in 1956. In 1975, for
8
instance, it removed the cash for incidental expenses from the
9
full grant-in-aid.
Walter Byers Depo. 21:21-22:14, 24:6-:17.
It
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
amended the grant-in-aid rules again in 2004 by allowing student-
11
athletes who receive federal Pell grants to receive total
12
assistance in excess of a full grant-in-aid and even in excess of
13
the cost of attendance.
14
at 208.
15
grant are now eligible to receive a full grant-in-aid plus the
16
value of their Pell grant -- currently, just over $5,500 -- even
17
if that total exceeds the cost of attendance.
18
1573:8-:16 (Pastides); Ex. 2340 at 208.
19
rules again in 2013 to permit different levels of compensation for
20
recruits in different sports.
21
tennis recruits to earn up to ten thousand dollars per year in
22
prize money from athletic events before they enroll in college.
23
Ex. 2340 at 75.
24
barred from receiving any prize money in excess of their actual
25
and necessary costs of competing in an event.
26
Trial Tr. 161:10-162:4 (Noll); Ex. 2340
As a result, student-athletes who qualify for a Pell
Trial Tr.
The NCAA amended its
The new rules permit Division I
Other Division I recruits, in contrast, remain
Id.
The amateurism provision in the NCAA’s current constitution
27
states that student-athletes “shall be amateurs in an
28
intercollegiate sport, and their participation should be motivated
26
1
primarily by education and by the physical, mental and social
2
benefits to be derived.
3
athletics is an avocation, and student-athletes should be
4
protected from exploitation by professional and commercial
5
enterprises.”
6
stands in stark contrast to the definitions set forth in the
7
NCAA’s early bylaws.
8
considers the primary motivation for participating in
9
intercollegiate athletics -- was not even a recognized motivation
Student participation in intercollegiate
Ex. 2340 at 18.
This conception of amateurism
Indeed, education -- which the NCAA now
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
for amateur athletes during the years when the NCAA prohibited
11
athletic scholarships.
12
restrictions on student-athlete compensation, which cap athletics-
13
based financial aid below the cost of attendance, are not
14
justified by the definition of amateurism set forth in its current
15
bylaws.
16
The Court finds that the NCAA’s current
Although the NCAA sought to establish the importance of these
17
restrictions by asserting that they increase consumer interest in
18
FBS football and Division I basketball, its evidence supporting
19
this assertion is unpersuasive.
20
survey research expert, Dr. J. Michael Dennis, who conducted a
21
survey of consumer attitudes concerning college sports in 2013.
22
Dr. Dennis surveyed 2,455 respondents across the United States and
23
observed that they generally opposed the idea of paying college
24
football and basketball players.
25
survey contained an initial question that apparently affected many
26
respondents’ answers to the survey’s substantive questions.
27
initial open-ended question asked respondents what they had heard
28
about student-athletes being paid.
It presented testimony from a
Trial Tr. 2613:24-2614:6.
27
His
The
Id. 2716:15-2717:7; Exs. 2629,
1
2630.
2
“single most common response” to this question was that
3
respondents had heard about student-athletes receiving some form
4
of illegal or illicit payments.
5
Many other respondents mentioned paying student-athletes a salary.
6
Trial Tr. 2714:21-2715:2 (Poret); Ex. 2630.
7
testified that his results remained the same even after he removed
8
these specific 274 respondents from his sample, the fact that
9
these respondents expressly mentioned illicit payments or salaries
Plaintiffs’ survey expert, Hal Poret, noted that the
Trial Tr. 2714:2-:20; Ex. 2629.
Although Dr. Dennis
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
at the start of the survey strongly suggests that the question
11
primed respondents to think about such illicit payments when
12
answering the other survey questions.
13
The NCAA relies heavily on the fact that sixty-nine percent
14
of respondents to Dr. Dennis’s survey expressed opposition to
15
paying student-athletes while only twenty-eight percent favored
16
paying them.
17
responses, however, are not relevant to the specific issues raised
18
here and say little about how consumers would actually behave if
19
the NCAA’s restrictions on student-athlete compensation were
20
lifted.
21
consistent with those observed in other polls and surveys
22
concerning college sports, he acknowledged that those other
23
studies may “vary in their quality or their methodology and their
24
implementation.”
25
Accordingly, the Court does not find these findings to be credible
26
evidence that consumer demand for the NCAA’s product would
27
decrease if student-athletes were permitted to receive
28
compensation.
Trial Tr. 2604:21-2605:2; Ex. 4045 at 19.
These
Although Dr. Dennis testified that these responses were
Trial Tr. 2641:24-2642:11; Ex. 4045 at 20.
28
1
The most relevant questions in Dr. Dennis’s survey asked
2
respondents specifically whether they would be more or less likely
3
to watch, listen to, or attend college football and basketball
4
games if student-athletes were paid.
5
respondents stated they would be less likely to watch, listen to,
6
or attend games if student-athletes were paid $20,000 per year.
7
Ex. 4045 at 23.
8
less likely to watch, listen to, or attend games if student-
9
athletes were paid $50,000 per year.
Thirty-eight percent of all
Forty-seven percent stated that they would be
Id.
In contrast, only about
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
four or five percent of respondents said that they would be more
11
likely to watch, listen to, or attend games if student-athletes
12
were paid $20,000 or $50,000 per year.
13
(Dennis).
14
more or less likely to watch, listen to, or attend games if
15
student-athletes were paid these amounts.
16
Trial Tr. 2651:14-2652:8
The remaining respondents stated that they would be no
Id.
While these questions are more germane to consumer behavior
17
than the survey’s findings about respondents’ general opinions
18
about compensating student-athletes, they still do not credibly
19
establish that the specific rules challenged here contribute to
20
consumer demand.
21
opinions about providing student-athletes with a share of
22
licensing revenue generated from the use of their own names,
23
images, and likenesses.
24
(Poret).
25
athletes the full cost of attendance, or any amount less than
26
$20,000 per year.
27
their behavior would be affected if small or large amounts of
28
compensation for the use of student-athletes’ names, images, and
Dr. Dennis did not ask respondents for their
Id. 2669:15-:18 (Dennis); 2709:6-:18
Nor did he ask their opinions about paying student-
Dr. Dennis also failed to ask respondents how
29
1
likenesses were held in trust for them until they left school --
2
one of Plaintiffs’ proposed alternatives here.
3
(Dennis); 2711:21-2712:9, 2718:19-2714:12 (Poret).
4
Id. 2686:18-2687:3
In addition, numerous respondents provided internally
5
inconsistent responses to different survey questions.
6
three of the respondents who said that they favored paying
7
student-athletes also stated that they would be less likely to
8
watch, listen to, or attend games if student-athletes were paid.
9
Id. 2729:25-2730:9.
Eighty-
Another thirty-three respondents stated that
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
they opposed paying student-athletes but said that they would be
11
more likely to watch, listen to, or attend games if student-
12
athletes were paid.
13
respondents did not understand or did not take seriously some of
14
the survey questions and illustrate the limits of Dr. Dennis’s
15
conclusions.
16
Id.
These responses suggest that some
Based on these flaws in Dr. Dennis’s survey, the Court finds
17
that it does not provide credible evidence that demand for the
18
NCAA’s product would decrease if student-athletes were permitted,
19
under certain circumstances, to receive a limited share of the
20
revenue generated from the use of their own names, images, and
21
likenesses.
22
survey to counter Dr. Dennis’s survey, the Court notes that the
23
NCAA produced Dr. Dennis’s survey as a rebuttal report, which may
24
have limited Plaintiffs’ opportunity to commission such a survey.
25
What’s more, Dr. Dennis himself acknowledged that it would be
26
extremely difficult to ask the specific kinds of detailed survey
27
questions most relevant to this case -- specifically, those
Although Plaintiffs did not provide their own opinion
28
30
1
relating to varying amounts and methods of payment for the use of
2
student-athletes’ names, images, and likenesses.
3
Plaintiffs presented other evidence illustrating the limits
4
of opinion surveys as predictors of consumer demand for sports-
5
entertainment products.
6
Daniel Rascher, described how opinion surveys conducted between
7
1970 and the present consistently showed that the public
8
overwhelmingly opposed rising baseball player salaries but
9
continued to watch, listen to, and attend Major League Baseball
Their expert on sports management, Dr.
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
games at a high rate even as player salaries rose during this
11
period.
12
many people felt that the removal of the reserve clause in the
13
1970s -- which ultimately enabled players to become free agents,
14
thus leading to higher salaries -- would undermine the popularity
15
of professional baseball.
16
fans’ stated opposition to rising salaries, Major League Baseball
17
revenues continued to rise after the removal of the reserve
18
clause.
19
‘Hey, we don’t want the players to make so much money,’ ultimately
20
they continue to watch on television, you know, buy tickets,
21
concessions, the whole thing.” (internal quotation marks added)).
22
Dr. Rascher highlighted another survey showing public opposition
23
to the decision of the International Olympic Committee (IOC) to
24
permit professional athletes to compete in the Olympics, even as
25
consumer interest in the Olympics remained high and revenues
26
generated by the event continued to rise during the same period.
27
Id. 904:22-905:18; see also id. 226:15-227:17 (testimony of Dr.
28
Noll that the Olympics are “much more popular now than they were
Id. 901:12-903:24; Ex. 2549.
He specifically noted that
However, despite these predictions and
Id. 903:13-:16 (“So even though the fans in polls say,
31
1
[when] amateur”).
2
pointed to various other formerly amateur sports associations --
3
such as those governing rugby and tennis -- whose events grew in
4
popularity after they began to allow their athletes to accept
5
payments.
6
In addition to the Olympics, Dr. Rascher also
Id. 903:25-904:21.
Although the NCAA presented evidence showing that the Nielsen
7
ratings for professional baseball and the Olympics have declined
8
since the 1970s and 1980s, this does not cast doubt on Dr.
9
Rascher’s findings.
As Dr. Rascher explained, Nielsen ratings
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
measure the share of the population watching a particular event,
11
not the raw number of viewers.
12
a result, Nielsen ratings have declined for virtually every
13
television program or sporting event over the past few decades as
14
the viewing population and number of television channels has
15
grown.
16
which has seen a dramatic increase in the raw number of viewers
17
over the years, has experienced flat Nielsen ratings for several
18
decades.
19
Id.
Id. 986:7-:10, 1019:20-1020:9.
As
Even a single event as popular as the Super Bowl,
Id. 1024:18-1026:7, 1025:6-:15.
Other historical evidence suggests that the NCAA’s
20
restrictions on student-athlete compensation have not contributed
21
significantly to the popularity of FBS football and Division I
22
basketball.
23
testified during his 2007 deposition, for instance, that the
24
NCAA’s decision to remove incidental expenses from the grant-in-
25
aid coverage in 1975 was not motivated by a desire to increase
26
consumer demand for its product.
27
24:6-:17.
28
experienced a tremendous growth in popularity during the period
The NCAA’s former president, the late Walter Byers,
Byers Depo. 21:21-22:14,
In fact, he specifically noted that NCAA sports
32
1
between 1956 and 1975 when grants-in-aid still covered the full
2
cost of attendance.
3
trial record suggests that the removal of incidental expenses or
4
any other changes to the grant-in-aid limit had an impact on the
5
popularity of college sports during this time.
6
Id. 25:15-26:8.
7
None of the evidence in the
Thus, the Court finds that the NCAA’s restrictions on
7
student-athlete compensation are not the driving force behind
8
consumer demand for FBS football and Division I basketball-related
9
products.
Rather, the evidence presented at trial suggests that
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
consumers are interested in college sports for other reasons.
11
Pilson testified, for instance, that the popularity of college
12
sports is driven by feelings of “loyalty to the school,” which are
13
shared by both alumni and people “who live in the region or the
14
conference.”
15
Plonsky, an associate athletics director at the University of
16
Texas (UT), testified that UT sports would remain popular as long
17
as they had “anything in our world to do with the University of
18
Texas.”
19
pretty loyal.”).
20
popularity of the NCAA’s annual men’s basketball tournament stems
21
from the fact that schools from all over the country participate
22
“so the fan base has an opportunity to cheer for someone from
23
their region of the country.”
24
become extremely popular at least in part because there’s someone
Trial Tr. 757:20-758:13.
Mr.
Similarly, Christine
Id. 1414:23-:24; see also id. 1376:13 (“Longhorns are
Dr. Emmert himself noted that much of the
Id. 1757:1-:9; see also id. (“It’s
25
26
27
28
7
The NCAA’s objections to this testimony under Federal Rules of
Evidence 602 and 701 are overruled. Walter Byers was the executive
director of the NCAA between 1956 and 1975, Stip. Undisputed Facts ¶ 23,
and therefore had personal knowledge of the popularity of NCAA sports
during this period.
33
1
from your neighborhood likely to be in the tournament.”).
2
testified that college bowl games have the same appeal.
3
1757:16-:19.
4
restrictions on student-athlete pay is not the driving force
5
behind consumer interest in FBS football and Division I
6
basketball.
7
certain limited restraints on student-athlete compensation, they
8
do not justify the rigid restrictions challenged in this case.
9
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
B.
He
Id.
This evidence demonstrates that the NCAA’s
Thus, while consumer preferences might justify
Competitive Balance
The NCAA asserts that its challenged restraints are
11
reasonable and procompetitive because they are needed to maintain
12
the current level of competitive balance among FBS football and
13
Division I basketball teams.
14
maintain this particular level of competitive balance in order to
15
sustain consumer demand for its product.
16
It further asserts that it must
The Court finds that the NCAA’s current restrictions on
17
student-athlete compensation do not promote competitive balance.
18
As Dr. Noll testified, since the 1970s, numerous sports economists
19
have studied the NCAA’s amateurism rules and nearly all have
20
concluded that the rules have no discernible effect on the level
21
of competitive balance.
22
of the more recent articles addressing the subject, a 2007 study
23
by economist Jim Peach published in the Social Science Journal,
24
found that there is “‘little evidence that the NCAA rules and
25
regulations have promoted competitive balance in college athletics
26
and no a priori reason to think that eliminating the rules would
27
change the competitive balance situation.’”
28
(quoting Peach article).
Trial Tr. 229:8-234:2.
He noted that one
Id. 232:22-233:1
Dr. Rascher reached the same conclusion
34
1
based on his review of the economics literature.
2
922:16.
3
field of sports economics, by Rod Fort, which found that the
4
NCAA’s restrictions on student-athlete pay do not appear to have
5
any impact on competitive balance.
6
Id. 920:9-
He specifically cited one of the leading textbooks in the
Id. 921:10-:18.
The academic consensus on this issue is not surprising given
that many of the NCAA’s other rules and practices suggest that the
8
association is unconcerned with achieving competitive balance.
9
Several witnesses testified that the restrictions on student-
10
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
7
athlete compensation lead many schools simply to spend larger
11
portions of their athletic budgets on coaching, recruiting, and
12
training facilities.
13
910:2-911:7 (Rascher).
14
the average salary for a head football coach exceeds $1.5 million.
15
Id. 1151:20-1152:14 (Staurowsky).
16
schools are able to spend freely in these other areas cancels out
17
whatever leveling effect the restrictions on student-athlete pay
18
might otherwise have.
19
spending by the high-revenue schools or minimize existing
20
disparities in revenue and recruiting.
21
specifically conceded that it is “not the mission of the
22
association to . . . try and take away the advantages of a
23
university that’s made a significant commitment to facilities and
24
tradition and all of the things that go along with building a
25
program.”
26
Id. 296:14-297:18 (Noll); 865:11-866:2,
In the major conferences, for instance,
The fact that high-revenue
The NCAA does not do anything to rein in
In fact, Dr. Emmert
Trial Tr. 1774:23-1775:6.
This same sentiment underlies the NCAA’s unequal revenue
27
distribution formula, which rewards the schools and conferences
28
that already have the largest athletic budgets.
35
Revenues
1
generated from the NCAA’s annual Division I men’s basketball
2
tournament are distributed to the conferences based on how their
3
member schools performed in the tournament in recent years.
4
Docket No. 207, Stip. Re: Broadcast Money, at ¶ 10.
5
the major conferences -- and the highest revenue schools --
6
typically receive the greatest payouts, which hinders, rather than
7
promotes, competitive balance.
As a result,
8
The only quantitative evidence that the NCAA presented
9
related to competitive balance is a cursory statistical analysis
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
conducted by Dr. Rubinfeld comparing the levels of competitive
11
balance in FBS football and Division I basketball to the levels in
12
the NFL and NBA.
13
that the NFL and NBA -- each of which has fewer teams than
14
Division I -- provide an appropriate baseline for comparing
15
competitive balance.
16
suggest that the NCAA’s challenged rules actually produce the
17
levels of competitive balance he observed.
18
Nothing in Dr. Rubinfeld’s analysis suggests
More importantly, his analysis does not
Even if the NCAA had presented some evidence of a causal
19
connection between its challenged rules and its current level of
20
competitive balance, it has not shown that the current level of
21
competitive balance is necessary to maintain its current level of
22
consumer demand.
23
that the ideal level of competitive balance for a sports league is
24
somewhere between perfect competitive balance (where every team
25
has an equal chance of winning every game) and perfect imbalance
26
(where every game has a predictable outcome).
27
(Noll); 3127:2-:21 (Rubinfeld).
28
to identify the specific level of competitive balance between
Trial Tr. 228:20-229:2 (Noll).
It is undisputed
Id. 453:8-:22
The NCAA has not even attempted
36
1
those extremes that is ideal or necessary to sustain its current
2
popularity.
3
Court finds that the NCAA’s challenged rules are not needed to
4
achieve a level of competitive balance necessary, or even likely,
5
to maintain current levels of consumer demand for FBS football and
6
Division I basketball.
Given the lack of such evidence in the record, the
7
C.
8
The NCAA contends that its restrictions on student-athlete
9
Integration of Academics and Athletics
compensation are reasonable and procompetitive because they
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
promote the integration of academics and athletics.
11
particular, it asserts that its challenged rules ensure that
12
student-athletes are able to obtain all of the educational
13
benefits that their schools provide and participate in their
14
schools’ academic communities.
15
integration of academics and athletics increases the quality of
16
the educational services its member schools provide to student-
17
athletes in the college education market that Plaintiffs have
18
identified.
In
According to the NCAA, the
19
For support, the NCAA relies on evidence showing that
20
student-athletes receive both short-term and long-term benefits
21
from being student-athletes.
22
Heckman, testified that participation in intercollegiate athletics
23
leads to better academic and labor market outcomes for many
24
student-athletes as compared to other members of their
25
socioeconomic groups.
26
found that these benefits are particularly pronounced for student-
27
athletes from disadvantaged backgrounds.
28
additional evidence, including its own data on student-athlete
One of its experts, Dr. James
Trial Tr. 1493:13-1494:25.
37
Id.
Dr. Heckman
The NCAA presented
1
graduation rates, to show that student-athletes enjoy substantial
2
benefits from participating in intercollegiate athletics.
3
However, none of this data nor any of Dr. Heckman’s observations
4
suggests that student-athletes benefit specifically from the
5
restrictions on student-athlete compensation that are challenged
6
in this case.
7
that the long-term educational and academic benefits that student-
8
athletes enjoy stem from their increased access to financial aid,
9
tutoring, academic support, mentorship, structured schedules, and
To the contrary, Dr. Heckman specifically testified
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
other educational services that are unrelated to the challenged
11
rules in this case.
12
Division I basketball schools offer most of these services to
13
their student-athletes independently and are not compelled to do
14
so by the NCAA, particularly not by the challenged rules.
15
Id. 1512:23-1516:17.
FBS football and
The same is true of the various other benefits of integration
16
that the NCAA has identified.
17
student-athletes derive from interacting with faculty and non-
18
student-athletes on campus are achieved mostly through the NCAA’s
19
rules requiring student-athletes to attend class and meet certain
20
academic requirements.
21
association’s rules prohibiting schools from creating dorms solely
22
for student-athletes or from requiring student-athletes to
23
practice more than a certain number of hours each week.
24
these rules is challenged here.
25
For instance, the benefits that
They are also achieved through the
None of
The only evidence that the NCAA has presented that suggests
26
that its challenged rules might be necessary to promote the
27
integration of academics and athletics is the testimony of
28
university administrators, who asserted that paying student38
1
athletes large sums of money would potentially “create a wedge”
2
between student-athletes and others on campus.
3
(Pastides).
4
much compensation was ultimately awarded, some student-athletes
5
might receive more money from the school than their professors.
6
Student-athletes might also be inclined to separate themselves
7
from the broader campus community by living and socializing off
8
campus.
9
Id. 1591:2-:20
These administrators noted that, depending on how
It is not clear that any of the potential problems identified
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
by the NCAA’s witnesses would be unique to student-athletes.
11
fact, when the Court asked Dr. Emmert whether other wealthy
12
students -- such as those who come from rich families or start
13
successful businesses during school -- raise all of the same
14
problems for campus relations, he replied that they did.
15
1790:18-:22.
16
would be any more problematic for campus relations than paying
17
other students who provide services to the university, such as
18
members of the student government or school newspaper.
19
Nonetheless, the Court finds that certain limited restrictions on
20
student-athlete compensation may help to integrate student-
21
athletes into the academic communities of their schools, which may
22
in turn improve the schools’ college education product.
23
In
Id.
It is also not clear why paying student-athletes
Plaintiffs have produced anecdotal and statistical evidence
24
suggesting that the NCAA’s current rules do not serve to integrate
25
FBS football players or Division I basketball players into the
26
academic communities at their schools.
27
the former UCLA basketball star, testified that he felt like “an
28
athlete masquerading as a student” during his college years.
39
For example, Ed O’Bannon,
Id.
1
33:11-:14.
2
Staurowsky, a sports management professor, who studied the
3
experiences of FBS football and Division I basketball players and
4
concluded that the time demands of their athletic obligations
5
prevent many of them from achieving significant academic success.
6
Id. 1175:12-1176:21.
7
NCAA’s data on student-athlete graduation rates and Dr. Heckman’s
8
observations surrounding academic outcomes for student-athletes.
9
However, the Court need not resolve these factual disputes
Plaintiffs also presented testimony from Dr. Ellen
Some of this evidence conflicts with the
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
because, regardless of how they are resolved, the restraints on
11
student-athlete compensation challenged in this case generally do
12
not serve to enhance academic outcomes for student-athletes.
13
D.
14
The NCAA asserts that its challenged rules are reasonable and
Increased Output
15
procompetitive because they enable it to increase the number of
16
opportunities available to schools and student-athletes to
17
participate in FBS football and Division I basketball, which
18
ultimately increases the number of games that can be played.
19
refers to this increased number of FBS football and Division I
20
schools, student-athletes, and games as increased output.
21
It
The Court finds that the NCAA’s restrictions on student-
22
athlete compensation do nothing to increase this output.
23
number of schools participating in FBS football and Division I
24
basketball has increased steadily over time and continues to
25
increase today.
26
participation in FBS football and Division I basketball typically
27
raises a school’s profile and leads to increased athletics-based
28
revenue.
Stip. Undisputed Facts ¶¶ 42-49.
Trial Tr. 872:1-874:20 (Rascher).
40
The
This is because
Although Dr. Emmert
1
and other NCAA and conference officials say that this trend is not
2
the result of increased Division I revenues but, rather, because
3
of schools’ philosophical commitment to amateurism, this theory is
4
implausible.
5
(Sankey); 3188:25-3189:17 (Lewis).
6
conferences have specifically undertaken efforts to change the
7
NCAA’s existing scholarship rules, which suggests that the rules
8
are not the reason that they choose to participate in Division I.
9
Ex. 2095 at 4 (2013 presentation by representatives of the five
Id. 1783:2-:14; 2080:11-:23 (Delany); 2418:5-:25
Schools in some of the major
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
major conferences requesting autonomy to raise existing
11
scholarship limits); Ex. 2527 at 2 (2014 letter from Pac 12 urging
12
other major conferences to support rule changes, including raising
13
the grant-in-aid limit).
14
suggest that any schools joined Division I originally because of
15
its amateurism rules.
16
participate in collegiate sports associations that restrict
17
compensation for student-athletes, including the NCAA’s lower
18
divisions and the NAIA.
19
Division III are bound by the same amateurism provisions of the
20
NCAA’s constitution as the schools in Division I.
21
difference between schools in Division I and schools in other
22
divisions and athletics associations, as explained above, is the
23
amount of resources that Division I schools commit to athletics.
24
Thus, while there may be tangible differences between Division I
25
schools and other schools that participate in intercollegiate
26
sports, these differences are financial, not philosophical.
27
28
What’s more, there is no evidence to
These schools had numerous other options to
Indeed, schools in FCS, Division II, and
The real
For this reason, the NCAA’s assertion that schools would
leave FBS and Division I for financial reasons if the challenged
41
1
restraints were removed is not credible.
2
Emmert and various other athletics administrators that most
3
Division I athletic programs operate at a loss and would not
4
remain in Division I if the challenged rules were removed
5
conflicts with the clear weight of the evidence.
6
1784:6-:18 (Emmert); 3188:25-3189:3 (Lewis).
Indeed, some of the
7
NCAA’s own witnesses undermined this claim.
Dr. Harris Pastides,
8
the president of the University of South Carolina, for instance,
9
specifically testified that his school “would probably continue to
The testimony of Dr.
Trial Tr.
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
compete in football and men’s basketball” if the challenged
11
restrictions on student-athlete compensation were lifted.
12
1598:23-:25.
13
Banowsky, similarly expressed skepticism that universities would
14
leave Division I if the restrictions were removed.
15
2372:20.
16
that most Division I sports programs operate at a loss by noting
17
that UT’s athletics department is not only self-sustaining but, in
18
fact, generates surplus revenue that funds other university
19
programs and expenses.
20
indicated that UT was not abnormal in this regard and that the
21
“vast proportion” of athletics programs across the country are
22
operated by “self-sourced, self-generated” revenues.
23
1468:11.
24
most of which are distributed back to its member schools and
25
conferences, have increased in recent years.
26
Id.
The commissioner of Conference USA, Britton
Id. 2371:25-
Ms. Plonsky also cast doubt on Dr. Emmert’s assertion
Id. 1385:12-:18, 1465:20-1466:10.
She
Id. 1467:22-
Mr. Lewis himself acknowledged that the NCAA’s revenues,
Id. 3195:19-3196:3.
Dr. Rascher offered similar testimony and documented that
27
participation in FBS football and Division I basketball generates
28
significant revenue and is highly profitable for most schools.
42
1
Id. 830:4-831:15.
2
much on coaches and training facilities.
3
that most FBS football schools used to spend even more on their
4
student-athletes before the NCAA lowered its team scholarship cap
5
from 105 to eighty-five.
6
Noll testified that some of the schools that currently compete in
7
FBS and Division I do so without providing the maximum amount of
8
financial aid permitted under NCAA rules.
9
These revenues are what enable them to spend so
Dr. Rascher also noted
Id. 873:20-874:20.
Furthermore, Dr.
Based on this evidence, the Court finds that schools would
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
not exit FBS football and Division I basketball if they were
11
permitted to pay their student-athletes a limited amount of
12
compensation beyond the value of their scholarships.
13
challenged restrictions on compensation do not increase the number
14
of opportunities for schools or student-athletes to participate in
15
Division I.
16
V.
17
The NCAA’s
Alternatives to the Restraint
Plaintiffs have proposed three modifications to the NCAA’s
18
challenged rules which, they contend, would allow the NCAA to
19
achieve the purposes of its challenged rules in a less restrictive
20
manner: (1) raise the grant-in-aid limit to allow schools to award
21
stipends, derived from specified sources of licensing revenue, to
22
student-athletes; (2) allow schools to deposit a share of
23
licensing revenue into a trust fund for student-athletes which
24
could be paid after the student-athletes graduate or leave school
25
for other reasons; or (3) permit student-athletes to receive
26
limited compensation for third-party endorsements approved by
27
their schools.
28
43
1
The Court finds that Plaintiffs’ first proposed
2
alternative -- allowing schools to award stipends -- would limit
3
the anticompetitive effects of the NCAA’s current restraint
4
without impeding the NCAA’s efforts to achieve its stated
5
purposes, provided that the stipends do not exceed the cost of
6
attendance as that term is defined in the NCAA’s bylaws.
7
stipend capped at the cost of attendance would not violate the
8
NCAA’s own definition of amateurism because it would only cover
9
educational expenses.
A
Indeed, as noted above, the NCAA’s member
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
schools used to provide student-athletes with similar stipends
11
before the NCAA lowered its cap on grants-in-aid.
12
21:21-22:14, 24:6-:17.
13
grant-in-aid limit to cover the full cost of attendance would not
14
violate the NCAA’s amateurism rules.
15
Sankey, the executive associate commissioner and chief operating
16
officer of the SEC, expressed the same view during his testimony,
17
as did Dr. Rubinfeld.
18
(Rubinfeld).
Byers Depo.
Dr. Emmert testified that raising the
Trial Tr. 1742:15-:18.
Greg
Id. 2430:23-:24 (Sankey); 3117:2-:4
19
None of the evidence presented at trial suggests that
20
consumer demand for the NCAA’s product would decrease if schools
21
were permitted to provide such stipends to student-athletes once
22
again.
23
stipends would hinder any school’s efforts to educate its student-
24
athletes or integrate them into the academic community on campus.
25
If anything, providing student-athletes with such stipends would
26
facilitate their integration into academic life by removing some
27
of the educational expenses that they would otherwise have to
28
bear, such as school supplies, which are not covered by a full
Nor does any of the evidence suggest that providing such
44
1
grant-in-aid.
2
allow for such stipends also would not have any effect on the
3
NCAA’s efforts to achieve competitive balance or increase its
4
output because, as explained above, its existing restrictions on
5
student-athlete compensation do not advance these goals.
6
Ex. 2340 at 207.
Raising the grant-in-aid cap to
Plaintiffs’ second proposed less restrictive alternative --
7
allowing schools to hold payments in trust for student-athletes --
8
would likewise enable the NCAA to achieve its goals in a less
9
restrictive manner, provided the compensation was limited and
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
distributed equally among team members.
11
Mr. Pilson, testified that he would not be troubled if schools
12
were allowed to make five thousand dollar payments to their
13
student-athletes and that his general concerns about paying
14
student-athletes would be partially assuaged if the payments were
15
held in trust.
16
director, Bernard Muir, similarly acknowledged that his concerns
17
about paying student-athletes varied depending on the size of the
18
payments that they would receive.
19
dollar limit, you know, that varies, but it does concern me when
20
we’re talking about six figures, seven figures in some cases.”).
21
This testimony is consistent with Dr. Dennis’s general observation
22
that, if the NCAA’s restrictions on student-athlete pay were
23
removed, the popularity of college sports would likely depend on
24
the size of payments awarded to student-athletes.
25
therefore finds that permitting schools to make limited payments
26
to student-athletes above the cost of attendance would not harm
27
consumer demand for the NCAA’s product -- particularly if the
28
student-athletes were not paid more or less based on their
Trial Tr. 770:25-771:18.
45
The NCAA’s own witness,
Stanford’s athletic
Id. 254:3-:18 (“Where I set the
The Court
1
athletic ability or the quality of their performances and the
2
payments were derived only from revenue generated from the use of
3
their own names, images, and likenesses.
4
Holding these limited and equal shares of licensing revenue
5
in trust until after student-athletes leave school would further
6
minimize any potential impact on consumer demand.
7
student-athletes are already permitted to receive compensation for
8
the use of their names, images, and likenesses in game re-
9
broadcasts and other archival footage of their college
Indeed, former
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
performances as long as they enter into such agreements after they
11
leave school.
12
if current and future student-athletes were given the opportunity
13
to receive compensation from their schools after they leave
14
college.
15
athletes while they are enrolled would not erect any new barriers
16
to schools’ efforts to educate student-athletes or integrate them
17
into their schools’ academic communities.
18
finds that consumer demand for the NCAA’s products would not
19
change if schools were allowed to offer and student-athletes on
20
FBS football and Division I basketball teams were allowed, after
21
leaving college, to receive limited and equal shares of licensing
22
revenue generated from the use of their names, images, and
23
likenesses during college.
The popularity of college sports would not suffer
Likewise, holding compensation in trust for student-
The Court therefore
24
Although Drs. Emmert and Rubinfeld suggested that student-
25
athletes could potentially monetize these future earnings while
26
they are still in school by taking out loans against the trust,
27
the NCAA could easily prohibit such borrowing, just as it
28
currently prohibits student-athletes from borrowing against their
46
1
future earnings as professional athletes.
2
(prohibiting student-athletes from accepting any loan issued based
3
on the “student-athlete’s athletics reputation, skill or pay-back
4
potential as a future professional athlete”).
5
witnesses testified that its current rules would not suffice to
6
prevent student-athletes from borrowing against their future
7
compensation.
8
schools could place the money in a special account, such as a
9
spendthrift trust, to prevent such borrowing.
See Ex. 2340 at 236
None of the NCAA’s
Nor did they rule out that the NCAA and its member
Accordingly, the
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
Court finds that allowing FBS football and Division I basketball
11
schools to hold in trust a limited and equal share of licensing
12
revenue for their recruits would provide a less restrictive means
13
of achieving the NCAA’s stated purposes.
14
Plaintiffs’ third proposed alternative, however -- allowing
15
student-athletes to receive money for endorsements -- does not
16
offer a less restrictive way for the NCAA to achieve its purposes.
17
Allowing student-athletes to endorse commercial products would
18
undermine the efforts of both the NCAA and its member schools to
19
protect against the “commercial exploitation” of student-athletes.
20
Although the trial record contains evidence -- and Dr. Emmert
21
himself acknowledged -- that the NCAA has not always succeeded in
22
protecting student-athletes from commercial exploitation, this
23
failure does not justify expanding opportunities for commercial
24
exploitation of student-athletes in the future.
25
themselves previously indicated that they were not seeking to
26
enjoin the NCAA from enforcing its current rules prohibiting such
27
endorsements.
Plaintiffs
In light of this record, the Court finds that
28
47
1
Plaintiffs’ third proposed less restrictive alternative does not
2
offer the NCAA a viable means of achieving its stated goals.
3
4
5
CONCLUSIONS OF LAW
I.
Legal Standard under the Section 1 of the Sherman Act
Section 1 of the Sherman Act makes it illegal to form any
“contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or
7
conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several
8
States.”
9
section, a plaintiff must show “‘(1) that there was a contract,
10
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
6
combination, or conspiracy; (2) that the agreement unreasonably
11
restrained trade under either a per se rule of illegality or a
12
rule of reason analysis; and (3) that the restraint affected
13
interstate commerce.’”
14
1062 (9th Cir. 2001) (citing Hairston v. Pacific 10 Conference,
15
101 F.3d 1315, 1318 (9th Cir. 1996)).
16
15 U.S.C. § 1.
To prevail on a claim under this
Tanaka v. Univ. of S. Cal., 252 F.3d 1059,
In this case, Plaintiffs allege that the NCAA’s rules and
17
bylaws operate as an unreasonable restraint of trade.
18
particular, they seek to challenge the set of rules that preclude
19
FBS football players and Division I men’s basketball players from
20
receiving any compensation, beyond the value of their athletic
21
scholarships, for the use of their names, images, and likenesses
22
in videogames, live game telecasts, re-broadcasts, and archival
23
game footage.
24
enacted and are enforced pursuant to an agreement among its
25
Division I member schools and conferences.
26
that these rules affect interstate commerce.
27
only remaining question here is whether the challenged rules
28
restrain trade unreasonably.
In
The NCAA does not dispute that these rules were
48
Nor does it dispute
Accordingly, the
1
“The rule of reason is the presumptive or default standard”
2
for making this determination.
3
Safeway, Inc., 651 F.3d 1118, 1133 (9th Cir. 2011) (citing Texaco
4
Inc. v. Dagher, 547 U.S. 1, 5 (2006)).
5
restraints may be examined under a truncated “quick look” or per
6
se analysis, the Supreme Court has “expressed reluctance to adopt
7
per se rules with regard to ‘restraints imposed in the context of
8
business relationships where the economic impact of certain
9
practices is not immediately obvious.’”
California ex rel. Harris v.
Although certain
State Oil Co. v. Khan,
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
522 U.S. 3, 10 (1997) (citing FTC v. Indiana Federation of
11
Dentists, 476 U.S. 447, 458-459 (1986)).
12
specifically held that concerted actions undertaken by joint
13
ventures should be analyzed under the rule of reason.
14
Needle, Inc. v. Nat’l Football League, 560 U.S. 183, 203 (2010)
15
(“When ‘restraints on competition are essential if the product is
16
to be available at all,’ per se rules of illegality are
17
inapplicable, and instead the restraint must be judged according
18
to the flexible Rule of Reason.” (citing NCAA v. Board of Regents
19
of Univ. of Oklahoma, 468 U.S. 85, 101 (1984))).
20
explained in prior orders, the Court analyzes the challenged
21
restraint in this case under the rule of reason rather than a
22
“quick look” or per se rule.
23
1025, April 11, 2014 Order, at 8-9; Case No. 09-1967, Docket No.
24
151, Feb. 8, 2010 Order, at 9–10.
25
The Supreme Court has
American
Thus, as
See Case No. 09-1967, Docket No.
“A restraint violates the rule of reason if the restraint’s
26
harm to competition outweighs its procompetitive effects.”
27
Tanaka, 252 F.3d at 1063.
28
shifting framework to conduct this balancing.
Courts typically rely on a burden-
49
Under that
1
framework, the “plaintiff bears the initial burden of showing that
2
the restraint produces ‘significant anticompetitive effects’
3
within a ‘relevant market.’”
4
1319).
5
defendant must come forward with evidence of the restraint’s
6
procompetitive effects.”
7
this burden, the plaintiff must “show that ‘any legitimate
8
objectives can be achieved in a substantially less restrictive
9
manner.’”
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
11
II.
Id. (citing Hairston, 101 F.3d at
If the plaintiff satisfies this initial burden, “the
Id.
Finally, if the defendant meets
Id. (citing Hairston, 101 F.3d at 1319).
Anticompetitive Effects in the Relevant Markets
“Proof that defendant’s activities had an impact upon
12
competition in the relevant market is ‘an absolutely essential
13
element of the rule of reason case.’”
14
v. San Fernando Valley Bd. of Realtors, 786 F.2d 1400, 1405 (9th
15
Cir. 1986) (citations omitted).
16
this context,
17
Supermarket of Homes, Inc.
The term “relevant market,” in
21
“encompasses notions of geography as well as
product use, quality, and description. The
geographic market extends to the area of
effective competition . . . where buyers can
turn for alternative sources of supply. The
product market includes the pool of goods or
services that enjoy reasonable
interchangeability of use and cross-elasticity
of demand.”
22
Tanaka, 252 F.3d at 1063 (quoting Oltz v. St. Peter’s Cmty. Hosp.,
23
861 F.2d 1440, 1446 (9th Cir. 1988) (internal citations omitted)).
18
19
20
24
Here, Plaintiffs allege that the challenged restraint causes
25
anticompetitive effects in two related national markets: (1) the
26
“college education market,” in which colleges and universities
27
compete to recruit student-athletes to play FBS football or
28
Division I basketball; and (2) the “group licensing market,” in
50
1
which videogame developers, television networks, and others
2
compete for group licenses to use the names, images, and
3
likenesses of FBS football and Division I men’s basketball players
4
in videogames, telecasts, and clips.
5
these markets in turn.
6
A.
7
8
9
The Court addresses each of
College Education Market
1.
Market Definition
As outlined in the findings of fact, Plaintiffs produced
sufficient evidence at trial to establish the existence of a
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
national market in which NCAA Division I schools compete to sell
11
unique bundles of goods and services to elite football and
12
basketball recruits.
13
recruits the opportunity to earn a higher education while playing
14
for an FBS football or Division I men’s basketball team.
15
exchange, the recruits who accept these offers provide their
16
schools with their athletic services and acquiesce in their
17
schools’ use of their names, images, and likenesses while they are
18
enrolled.
19
attendance not covered by their grants-in-aid.
20
Specifically, these schools compete to offer
8
In
The recruits must also pay for any other costs of
The NCAA contends that it does not restrain competition in
21
this market.
22
Division I basketball schools lack the power to fix prices in this
23
market because they must compete with other colleges and
24
universities -- such as those in other divisions and college
In particular, it argues that FBS football and
25
8
26
27
28
This market could be divided into two submarkets -- one in which
Division I basketball schools compete for elite basketball recruits and
one in which FBS football schools compete for elite football recruits.
However, because the parties’ evidence and arguments in this case apply
generally to both of these submarkets, there is no need to subdivide the
broader market for the purposes of this analysis.
51
1
athletic associations -- in supplying educational and athletic
2
opportunities to elite recruits.
3
professional sports leagues and domestic minor leagues which might
4
likewise provide alternatives to playing FBS football or Division
5
I basketball.
6
leagues, the NCAA argues, Plaintiffs have defined the field of
7
competition in the college education market too narrowly.
8
The NCAA also points to foreign
By failing to account for these other schools and
The “field of competition” within a given product market
consists of “the group or groups of sellers or producers who have
10
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
9
actual or potential ability to deprive each other of significant
11
levels of business.”
12
Inc., 875 F.2d 1369, 1374 (9th Cir. 1989).
13
limited to producers of the particular “product at issue” but also
14
includes the producers of “all economic substitutes for the
15
product.”
16
1038, 1045 (9th Cir. 2008).
17
economic substitutes, courts typically consider two factors:
18
“first, [the product’s] reasonable interchangeability for the same
19
or similar uses; and second, cross-elasticity of demand, an
20
economic term describing the responsiveness of sales of one
21
product to price changes in another.”
22
Coliseum Comm’n v. Nat’l Football League, 726 F.2d 1381, 1393 (9th
23
Cir. 1984); see also Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S.
24
294, 325 (1962) (“The outer boundaries of a product market are
25
determined by the reasonable interchangeability of use or the
26
cross-elasticity of demand between the product itself and
27
substitutes for it.”).
28
the price, use, and qualities of all potential substitutes for the
Thurman Indus., Inc. v. Pay ‘N Pak Stores,
This group is not
Newcal Indus., Inc. v. Ikon Office Solution, 513 F.3d
To determine whether a product has
Los Angeles Memorial
This analysis requires an examination of
52
1
product at issue.
2
Co., 328 F.3d 1145, 1163 (9th Cir. 2003) (“For antitrust purposes,
3
a ‘market is composed of products that have reasonable
4
interchangeability for the purposes for which they are produced --
5
price, use and qualities considered.’” (citations omitted)).
6
analysis of these factors in the present case demonstrates that
7
Plaintiffs have properly defined the scope of a relevant college
8
education market.
9
See Paladin Associates, Inc. v. Montana Power
An
As set forth in the findings of fact, the product that FBS
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
and Division I schools offer is unique.
11
educational and athletic opportunities offered by schools outside
12
of FBS football and Division I -- including schools in FCS,
13
Divisions II and III, and associations like the NAIA, USCAA,
14
NJCAA, or NCCAA -- differ significantly in both price and quality
15
from those offered by FBS and Division I schools.
16
schools typically offer a lower level of athletic competition,
17
inferior training facilities, lower-paid coaches, and fewer
18
opportunities to play in front of large crowds and on television.
19
Furthermore, because many of these schools do not offer athletic
20
scholarships, the cost of attending these institutions is much
21
higher for many student-athletes than the cost of attending an FBS
22
football or Division I basketball school.
23
who receive scholarship offers to play FBS football or Division I
24
basketball rarely turn them down and, when they do, almost never
25
do so to play football or basketball at a school outside of FBS or
26
Division I.
27
compete with FBS and Division I schools in the recruiting market,
28
just as they do not on the football field or the basketball court.
The combination of
Non-Division I
This is why recruits
In short, non-FBS and non-Division I schools do not
53
1
The same holds true for professional sports leagues such as
2
the AFL, NBA D-League, and foreign football and basketball
3
leagues.
4
earn a higher education or regularly showcase their athletic
5
talents on national television.
6
demonstrates that FBS football and Division I basketball command a
7
significantly larger domestic television audience than virtually
8
every other football or basketball league, with the exceptions of
9
the NFL and NBA (neither of which permits an athlete to enter its
These leagues do not offer recruits opportunities to
The NCAA’s own evidence
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
league directly from high school).
11
football and basketball recruits rarely pursue careers in these
12
second-tier leagues immediately after high school and
13
overwhelmingly prefer to play for FBS football teams and Division
14
I basketball teams.
15
The evidence shows that elite
In sum, the qualitative differences between the opportunities
16
offered by FBS football and Division I basketball schools and
17
those offered by other schools and sports leagues illustrate that
18
FBS football schools and Division I basketball schools operate in
19
a distinct market.
20
(S.D. Ind.) (finding plaintiff’s allegations regarding “the
21
superior competition, institutional support, overall preference,
22
higher revenue, and more scholarship opportunities provided in
23
Division I football, as opposed to Division II or NAIA football”
24
sufficient to support his assertion that “Division II and NAIA
25
football are not adequate substitutes for Division I football and,
26
thus, not part of the same relevant market”); White v. NCAA, Case
27
No. 06-999, Docket No. 72, at 3 (C.D. Cal. Sept. 20, 2006)
28
(finding plaintiff’s allegations that student-athletes had no
See Rock v. NCAA, 2013 WL 4479815, at *13
54
1
reasonably interchangeable alternatives for the “unique
2
combination of coaching-services and academics” offered by FBS
3
football and Division I basketball schools sufficient to plead a
4
relevant market).
5
fluctuations in the price of attending FBS and Division I schools
6
resulting from changes in the grant-in-aid limit have not caused
7
large numbers of FBS football and Division I basketball recruits
8
to migrate toward other schools or professional leagues.
9
Trial Tr. 127:4-:17 (Noll); Lucas Auto. Engineering, Inc. v.
So, too, does the fact that historic
See
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
Bridgestone/Firestone, Inc., 275 F.3d 762, 767 (9th Cir. 2001)
11
(“The determination of what constitutes the relevant product
12
market hinges, therefore, on a determination of those products to
13
which consumers will turn, given reasonable variations in
14
price.”).
15
schools and professional leagues that the NCAA has identified lack
16
the power to deprive FBS football and Division I basketball
17
schools of a significant number of recruits.
18
other schools and leagues are not suppliers in the market that
19
Plaintiffs have identified.
20
Taken together, this evidence shows that the various
2.
Accordingly, these
The Challenged Restraint
21
Because FBS football and Division I basketball schools are
22
the only suppliers in the relevant market, they have the power,
23
when acting in concert through the NCAA and its conferences, to
24
fix the price of their product.
25
power by forming an agreement to charge every recruit the same
26
price for the bundle of educational and athletic opportunities
27
that they offer: to wit, the recruit’s athletic services along
28
with the use of his name, image, and likeness while he is in
They have chosen to exercise this
55
1
school.
2
offering any recruit a cash rebate, deferred payment, or other
3
form of direct compensation -- that school may be subject to
4
sanctions by the NCAA.
5
If any school seeks to lower this fixed price -- by
This price-fixing agreement constitutes a restraint of trade.
6
The evidence presented at trial makes clear that, in the absence
7
of this agreement, certain schools would compete for recruits by
8
offering them a lower price for the opportunity to play FBS
9
football or Division I basketball while they attend college.
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
Indeed, the NCAA’s own expert, Dr. Rubinfeld, acknowledged that
11
the NCAA operates as a cartel that imposes a restraint on trade in
12
this market.
13
Despite this undisputed evidence, the NCAA contends that its
14
conduct does not amount to price-fixing because the price that
15
most student-athletes actually pay is “at or close to zero” due to
16
their athletic scholarships.
17
commercial nature of the transactions between FBS football and
18
Division I basketball schools and their recruits.
19
true that many FBS football and Division I basketball players do
20
not pay for tuition, room, or board in a traditional sense, they
21
nevertheless provide their schools with something of significant
22
value: their athletic services and the rights to use their names,
23
images, and likenesses while they are enrolled.
24
pay the incidental expenses of their college attendance.
25
Seventh Circuit recently observed that these “transactions between
26
NCAA schools and student-athletes are, to some degree, commercial
27
in nature, and therefore take place in a relevant market with
28
respect to the Sherman Act.”
This argument mischaracterizes the
While it is
They must also
The
Agnew v. NCAA, 683 F.3d 328, 341
56
1
(7th Cir. 2012).
2
schools make with premier athletes -- full scholarships in
3
exchange for athletic services -- are not noncommercial, since
4
schools can make millions of dollars as a result of these
5
transactions.”
6
The court reasoned that “the transactions those
Id. at 340.
A court in the Central District of California similarly
7
concluded that these transactions take place within a cognizable
8
antitrust market.
9
student-athletes had stated a valid Sherman Act claim against the
In White, the court found that a group of
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
NCAA by alleging that its cap on the value of grants-in-aid
11
operated as a price-fixing agreement among FBS football and
12
Division I basketball schools.
13
4.
14
plaintiffs had failed to allege a sufficient harm to competition.
15
It explained,
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
Case No. 06-999, Docket No. 72, at
The court specifically rejected the NCAA’s argument that the
Plaintiffs’ [complaint] alleges that studentathletes are consumers of the higher education
and coaching services that the NCAA schools
provide. Plaintiffs allege that the GIA
[grant-in-aid] cap operates to restrict the
price at which student-athletes purchase those
services by forcing student-athletes to bear a
greater portion of the cost of attendance than
they would have borne if the GIA cap had not
been in place. Taken in a light most
favorable to the Plaintiffs, these allegations
suggest that the GIA cap harms would-be
buyers, forcing them to pay higher prices than
would result from unfettered competition.
Id. (citations omitted).
The same reasoning governs here, where
Plaintiffs have shown that FBS football and Division I basketball
schools have fixed the price of their product by agreeing not to
offer any recruit a share of the licensing revenues derived from
the use of his name, image, and likeness.
57
1
The fact that this price-fixing agreement operates by
2
undervaluing the name, image, and likeness rights that the
3
recruits provide to the schools -- rather than by explicitly
4
requiring schools to charge a specific monetary price -- does not
5
preclude antitrust liability here.
6
prohibits various kinds of price-fixing agreements, even indirect
7
restraints on price.
8
310 U.S. 150, 223 (1940) (“[T]he machinery employed by a
9
combination for price-fixing is immaterial.
Federal antitrust law
See United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co.,
Under the Sherman Act
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
a combination formed for the purpose and with the effect of
11
raising, depressing, fixing, pegging, or stabilizing the price of
12
a commodity in interstate or foreign commerce is illegal per
13
se.”).
14
Supreme Court held that an agreement among beer wholesalers to
15
cease providing interest-free credits to retailers was “merely one
16
form of price fixing” and could therefore be “presumed illegal”
17
under § 1 of the Sherman Act.
18
Court reasoned that the “agreement to terminate the practice of
19
giving credit is [] tantamount to an agreement to eliminate
20
discounts, and thus falls squarely within the traditional per se
21
rule against price fixing.”
22
terms must be characterized as an inseparable part of the
23
price.”).
24
“wholesalers had competed with each other with respect to trade
25
credit, and the credit terms for individual retailers had varied
26
substantially.”
27
practice thus “extinguish[ed] one form of competition among the
28
sellers” and could be presumed unlawful, even though it did not
In Catalano, Inc. v. Target Sales, Inc., for instance, the
446 U.S. 643, 650 (1980).
The
Id. at 648; see also id. (“[C]redit
It noted that, prior to their agreement, the
Id. at 644-45.
The agreement to eliminate this
58
1
ultimately require the sellers to set their prices at some
2
specific, pre-determined level.
3
Id.
Like the wholesalers’ agreement in Catalano, the agreement
4
among FBS football and Division I basketball schools not to offer
5
recruits a share of their licensing revenue eliminates one form of
6
price competition.
7
prices indirectly, rather than directly, it is nevertheless
8
sufficient to satisfy Plaintiffs’ initial burden under the rule of
9
reason.
Although this agreement may operate to fix
Plaintiffs need not identify an agreement as obviously
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
unlawful as the wholesalers’ agreement in Catalano to establish a
11
per se violation, let alone to meet the lower burden imposed by
12
the first step of a rule of reason analysis.
13
45 (“[W]e have held agreements to be unlawful per se that had
14
substantially less direct impact on price than the agreement
15
alleged in this case.”).
16
See 446 U.S. at 644-
Indeed, in another case involving concerted action by members
17
of a sports league, then-Judge Sotomayor observed that an
18
antitrust plaintiff may sometimes meet its burden by identifying
19
an agreement to fix prices indirectly.
20
Properties, Inc. v. Salvino, Inc., 542 F.3d 290, 337 (2d Cir.
21
2008) (Sotomayor, J., concurring).
22
sought to challenge an agreement among Major League Baseball teams
23
to license their trademarks and other intellectual property
24
exclusively through a designated third party called Major League
25
Baseball Properties (MLBP).
26
agreement violated the Sherman Act because it eliminated price
27
competition among the teams as suppliers of intellectual property.
28
A three-judge panel of the Second Circuit rejected this claim,
See Major League Baseball
In that case, the plaintiff
The plaintiff alleged that the
59
finding that the agreement did not constitute price-fixing.
2
separate concurrence, then-Judge Sotomayor noted that, although
3
she agreed that the licensing arrangement was lawful, she believed
4
that the majority had endorsed “an overly formalistic view of
5
price fixing.”
6
agreement does not specify a price to be charged, the effect of
7
the agreement clearly eliminates price competition between the
8
[teams] for trademark licenses.
9
competition from the market is the essence of price fixing.”
10
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
1
at 335; see also id. at 336-37 (“In other words, an agreement
11
between competitors to ‘share profits’ or to make a third party
12
the exclusive seller of their competing products that has the
13
purpose and effect of fixing, stabilizing, or raising prices may
14
be a per se violation of the Sherman Act, even if no explicit
15
price is referenced in the agreement.”).
16
also noted that such an agreement could be unlawful, even if it
17
was only meant to bind members of a joint venture.
18
Id. at 334.
In a
She reasoned, “While the MLBP
An agreement to eliminate price
Id.
Then-Judge Sotomayor
She explained,
[T]he antitrust laws prohibit two companies A
and B, producers of X, from agreeing to set
the price of X. Likewise, A and B cannot
simply get around this rule by agreeing to set
the price of X through a third-party
intermediary or “joint venture” if the purpose
and effect of that agreement is to raise,
depress, fix, peg, or stabilize the price of
X.
19
20
21
22
9
23
Id. at 336.
24
agreement served a procompetitive purpose, because it increased
Although she ultimately concluded that the MLBP
25
26
27
28
9
The Supreme Court recently relied on this language from thenJudge Sotomayor’s concurrence in another Sherman Act case involving a
challenge to concerted action by members of a sports league. American
Needle, 560 U.S. at 202 (“[C]ompetitors ‘cannot simply get around’
antitrust liability by acting ‘through a third-party intermediary or
60
1
the total number of licenses sold, her opinion nevertheless
2
illustrates that price-fixing agreements take many forms and may
3
be unlawful even if they are implemented by members of a joint
4
venture.
5
Although Plaintiffs have characterized FBS football and
6
Division I basketball schools as sellers in the market for
7
educational and athletic opportunities, in their post-trial brief
8
they argued that the schools could alternatively be characterized
9
as buyers in a market for recruits’ athletic services and
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
licensing rights.
11
recruitment of the highest ranked male high school football and
12
basketball players each year.
13
Plaintiffs’ antitrust claim arises under a theory of monopsony,
14
rather than monopoly, alleging an agreement to fix prices among
15
buyers rather than sellers.
16
violate § 1 of the Sherman Act just as a price-fixing agreement
17
among sellers would.
18
Grp., Inc., 629 F.3d 697, 705 (7th Cir. 2011) (“Ordinarily, price-
19
fixing agreements exist between sellers who collude to set their
20
prices above or below prevailing market prices.
21
also violate § 1 by forming what is sometimes known as a ‘buyers’
22
cartel.’”); Vogel v. Am. Soc. of Appraisers, 744 F.2d 598, 601
23
(7th Cir. 1984) (“Just as a sellers’ cartel enables the charging
24
of monopoly prices, a buyers’ cartel enables the charging of
25
monopsony prices; and monopoly and monopsony are symmetrical
26
distortions of competition from an economic standpoint.”
The relevant market would be that for the
Viewed from this perspective,
Such an agreement, if proven, would
See generally Omnicare, Inc. v. UnitedHealth
But buyers may
27
28
‘joint venture.’’” (quoting Salvino, 542 F.3d at 336 (Sotomayor, J.,
concurring)).
61
1
(citations omitted)).
2
“kinship between monopoly and monopsony suggests that similar
3
legal standards should apply to claims of monopolization and to
4
claims of monopsonization.”
5
Hardwood Lumber Co., Inc., 549 U.S. 312, 322 (2007) (citing Roger
6
G. Noll, “‘Buyer Power’ and Economic Policy,” 72 Antitrust L.J.
7
589, 591 (2005)).
8
9
The Supreme Court has noted that the
Weyerhaeuser Co. v. Ross-Simmons
In recent years, several courts have specifically recognized
that monopsonistic practices in a market for athletic services may
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
provide a cognizable basis for relief under the Sherman Act.
11
e.g., Rock, 2013 WL 4479815, at *11 (finding that plaintiff had
12
identified a cognizable market in which “buyers of labor (the
13
schools) are all members of NCAA Division I football and are
14
competing for the labor of the sellers (the prospective student-
15
athletes who seek to play Division I football)”); In re NCAA I-A
16
Walk-On Football Players Litig., 398 F. Supp. 2d 1144, 1150 (W.D.
17
Wash. 2005) (“Plaintiffs have alleged a sufficient ‘input’ market
18
in which NCAA member schools compete for skilled amateur football
19
players.”).
20
that the “proper identification of a labor market for student-
21
athletes . . . would meet plaintiffs’ burden of describing a
22
cognizable market under the Sherman Act.”
23
that Plaintiffs’ alternative monopsony theory mirrors their
24
monopoly price-fixing theory, the evidence presented and facts
25
found above are sufficient to establish a restraint of trade in a
26
market for recruits’ athletic services just as they are to
27
establish a restraint of trade in the college education market.
28
As explained above, viewed from this perspective, the sellers in
See,
Indeed, the Seventh Circuit recently noted in Agnew
62
683 F.3d at 346.
Given
1
this market are the recruits; the buyers are FBS football and
2
Division I basketball schools; the product is the combination of
3
the recruits’ athletic services and licensing rights; and the
4
restraint is the agreement among schools not to offer any recruit
5
more than the value of a full grant-in-aid.
6
this restraint, schools would compete against one another by
7
offering to pay more for the best recruits’ athletic services and
8
licensing rights -- that is, they would engage in price
9
competition.
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
In the absence of
The NCAA argues that Plaintiffs cannot prevail under a
11
monopsony theory because they have not presented evidence of an
12
impact on price or output in a “downstream market.”
13
2766:16-:22 (Stiroh).
14
only way that a restraint on an input market -- such as a market
15
for recruits’ athletic services and licensing rights -- can give
16
rise to an anticompetitive harm is if that restraint ultimately
17
harms consumers by reducing output or raising prices in a
18
downstream market.
19
among economists, they are not supported by the relevant case law.
20
The Supreme Court has indicated that monopsonistic practices that
21
harm suppliers may violate antitrust law even if they do not
22
ultimately harm consumers.
23
Crystal Sugar Co., 334 U.S. 219 (1948), the Supreme Court
24
considered whether an agreement among sugar refiners to fix the
25
prices they paid for sugar beets constituted a violation of the
26
Sherman Act.
27
combination condemned by the Act, even though the price-fixing was
28
by purchasers, and the persons specially injured . . . are
Trial Tr.
They cite Dr. Stiroh’s testimony that the
Whatever merit Dr. Stiroh’s views might have
In Mandeville Island Farms v. Am.
It concluded that “the agreement is the sort of
63
sellers, not customers or consumers.”
2
Court reached this conclusion despite a vehement dissent from
3
Justice Jackson noting that the price of sugar had not been
4
affected by the refiners’ agreement.
5
decision, thus, “strongly suggests that suppliers . . . are
6
protected by antitrust laws even when the anti-competitive
7
activity does not harm end-users.”
8
v. Sw. Bell Tel. Co., 305 F.3d 1124, 1134 (10th Cir. 2002); see
9
also Knevelbaard Dairies v. Kraft Foods, Inc., 232 F.3d 979, 988
10
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
1
(9th Cir. 2000) (“The Supreme Court’s references to the goals of
11
achieving ‘the lowest prices, the highest quality and the greatest
12
material progress’ and of ‘assur[ing] customers the benefits of
13
price competition’ do not mean that conspiracies among buyers to
14
depress acquisition prices are tolerated.
15
field makes clear that the interaction of competitive forces, not
16
price-rigging, is what will benefit consumers.” (emphasis added)).
17
Id. at 235.
Id. at 247.
Notably, the
The majority’s
Telecor Communications, Inc.
Every precedent in the
This is consistent with a long line of cases, including some
18
decided by the Ninth Circuit, recognizing that restraints on
19
competition within a labor market may give rise to an antitrust
20
violation under § 1 of the Sherman Act.
21
Shipowners’ Ass’n, 272 U.S. 359, 365 (1926) (holding that a multi-
22
employer agreement among ship owners restrained trade in a labor
23
market for sailors); Todd v. Exxon Corp., 275 F.3d 191, 201 (2d
24
Cir. 2001) (Sotomayor, J.) (holding that a conspiracy among oil
25
industry employers to set salaries at “artificially low levels”
26
restrained trade in a labor market and noting that “a horizontal
27
conspiracy among buyers [of labor] to stifle competition is as
28
unlawful as one among sellers”); Ostrofe v. H.S. Crocker Co.,
64
See, e.g., Anderson v.
1
Inc., 740 F.2d 739, 740 (9th Cir. 1984) (holding that a multi-
2
employer agreement in the paper lithograph label industry may
3
restrain trade in a “market for personal services”).
4
consistent with the many recent cases, some of which are cited
5
above, recognizing the validity of antitrust claims against the
6
NCAA based on anticompetitive harms in a labor market.
7
Agnew, 683 F.3d at 346 (recognizing that the NCAA’s scholarship
8
rules may restrain trade in a “labor market for student-athletes”
9
and noting that “labor markets are cognizable under the Sherman
It is also
See, e.g.,
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
Act”); Law v. NCAA, 134 F.3d 1010, 1015 (10th Cir. 1998) (finding
11
that an NCAA rule capping compensation for entry-level coaches
12
restrained trade in a “labor market for coaching services” and
13
noting that “[l]ower prices cannot justify a cartel’s control of
14
prices charged by suppliers, because the cartel ultimately robs
15
the suppliers of the normal fruits of their enterprises”); In re
16
NCAA I-A Walk-On Football Players Litig., 398 F. Supp. 2d at 1150
17
(recognizing that the NCAA’s scholarship rules may restrain trade
18
in an “‘input’ market in which NCAA member schools compete for
19
skilled amateur football players”).
20
Southern District of Indiana recently rejected the NCAA’s argument
21
that a student-athlete would need to plead a “‘market-wide impact
22
on the price or output of any commercial product’” in order to
23
state a valid Sherman Act claim challenging its former prohibition
24
on multi-year football scholarships.
25
*14 (S.D. Ind.) (quoting NCAA’s brief).
26
found that the student-athlete’s complaint “adequately plead[]
27
anticompetitive effects of the challenged bylaws” in the
28
“‘nationwide market for the labor of Division I football student
65
In fact, a court in the
Rock, 2013 WL 4479815, at
The court in that case
1
athletes’” based on his allegations that, in the absence of the
2
challenged scholarship rules, the schools competing for his
3
services would have offered him a multi-year scholarship.
4
*3, *15 (quoting complaint).
5
the plaintiff had identified a cognizable harm to competition by
6
alleging that removing the challenged restraint would “would force
7
the schools to ‘compete’ for recruits.”
8
here have presented sufficient evidence to show an analogous
9
anticompetitive effect in a similar labor market.
Id. at
The court specifically noted that
Id. at *15.
Plaintiffs
Accordingly,
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
they have shown a cognizable harm to competition under the rule of
11
reason.
12
The Court notes that Plaintiffs had not articulated a
13
monopsony theory prior to trial.
14
trial in response to the Court’s questions.
15
Court has addressed Plaintiffs’ monopoly theory in greater detail.
16
However, Plaintiffs presented significant evidence to support a
17
monopsony theory during trial.
18
length in their post-trial briefs.
19
trial and the facts found here, as well as the law, support both
20
theories.
21
monopsony theory.
Their expert addressed it at
For this reason, the
Both sides discussed the theory at
The evidence presented at
The NCAA is not prejudiced by alternative reliance on a
22
B.
23
Plaintiffs also allege that the NCAA has restrained
24
competition in three specific national submarkets of a broader
25
national group licensing market: namely, the submarkets for group
26
licenses to use student-athletes’ names, images, and likenesses in
27
(1) live game telecasts, (2) videogames, and (3) game re-
Group Licensing Market
28
66
1
broadcasts, highlight clips, and other archival footage.
2
Court addresses each of these submarkets separately.
3
1.
4
5
The
Submarket for Group Licenses to Use StudentAthletes’ Names, Images, and Likenesses in Live
Game Telecasts
As noted above, television networks compete for the rights to
6
telecast live FBS football and Division I basketball games.
7
order to secure these rights, networks typically purchase licenses
8
to use the intellectual property of the participating schools and
9
conferences during the game telecast as well as the names, images,
In
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
and likenesses of the participating student-athletes.10
11
student-athletes are not permitted by NCAA rules to license the
12
rights to use their names, images, and likenesses, the networks
13
deal exclusively with schools and conferences when acquiring the
14
student-athletes’ rights.
Because
15
As the Court found above, in the absence of the NCAA’s
16
restrictions on student-athlete compensation, student-athletes on
17
certain FBS football and Division I basketball teams would be able
18
to sell group licenses for the use of their names, images, and
19
likenesses to television networks.
20
licenses to the television networks directly or do so through some
21
intermediate buyer -- such as their school or a third-party
22
licensing company -- which would bundle the group license with
23
other intellectual property and performance rights and sell the
They would either sell those
24
25
26
27
28
10
As discussed in the findings of fact, when a third party -- such
as a bowl committee or the NCAA itself -- has organized a particular
athletic event, the networks may also purchase a separate license from
that party to use its intellectual property during the telecast.
Because these transactions do not involve the transfer of rights to use
student-athletes’ names, images, and likenesses, they are not relevant
to this discussion.
67
1
full bundle of rights to the network.
2
student-athletes would sell their group licenses to the networks
3
directly or through some intermediate buyer, however, a submarket
4
for such group licenses would exist.
Regardless of whether the
5
The NCAA denies that such a market exists as a matter of law.
6
It argues that the First Amendment and certain state laws preclude
7
student-athletes from asserting any rights of publicity in the use
8
of their names, images, and likenesses during live game telecasts.
9
The Court has previously rejected this argument.
See April 11,
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
2014 Order at 21.
11
believed that student-athletes lacked publicity rights in the use
12
of their names, images, and likenesses, they may have still sought
13
to acquire these rights as a precautionary measure.
14
often negotiate licenses to acquire uncertain rights.
15
Distribution & Mktg., Inc. v. Major League Baseball Advanced
16
Media, L.P., 505 F.3d 818, 826 (8th Cir. 2007) (Colloton, J.,
17
dissenting) (“CBC surely can ‘agree,’ as a matter of good business
18
judgment, to bargain away any uncertain First Amendment rights
19
that it may have in exchange for the certainty of what it
20
considers to be an advantageous contractual arrangement.”); Hynix
21
Semiconductors, Inc. v. Rambus, Inc., 2006 WL 1991760, at *4 (N.D.
22
Cal.) (crediting expert testimony that “a negotiating patentee and
23
licensee generally agree to a lower royalty rate if there is
24
uncertainty as to whether the patents are actually valid and
25
infringed”).
26
evidence of the existence of a national submarket for group
27
licenses.
Furthermore, even if some television networks
Businesses
See C.B.C.
The NCAA’s argument does not undermine Plaintiffs’
28
68
1
That said, Plaintiffs have not identified any harm to
2
competition in this submarket.
3
element of a Section 1 violation under the rule of reason is
4
injury to competition in the relevant market.”
5
Inc. v. S. Pac. Transp. Co., 858 F.2d 567, 570 (9th Cir. 1988).
6
That injury must go “beyond the impact on the claimant” and reach
7
“a field of commerce in which the claimant is engaged.”
8
McNamara, 979 F.2d 728, 738 (9th Cir. 1992) (citations and
9
quotation marks omitted); see also Sicor Ltd. v. Cetus Corp., 51
As previously noted, an “essential
Alliance Shippers,
Austin v.
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
F.3d 848, 854 (9th Cir. 1995) (“Under the rule of reason approach,
11
the plaintiff must show an injury to competition, rather than just
12
an injury to plaintiff’s business.” (emphasis in original;
13
citations and quotation marks omitted)).
14
shown that the NCAA’s challenged rules harm student-athletes by
15
depriving them of compensation that they would otherwise receive,
16
they have not shown that this harm results from a restraint on
17
competition in the group licensing market.
18
have failed to show that the challenged rules hinder competition
19
among any potential buyers or sellers of group licenses.
20
While Plaintiffs have
In particular, they
The sellers in this market would be the student-athletes.
21
Plaintiffs have not presented any evidence to show that, in the
22
absence of the challenged restraint, teams of student-athletes
23
would actually compete against one another to sell their group
24
licenses.
25
that such competition would not occur.
26
network that seeks to telecast a particular athletic event would
27
have to obtain a group license from every team that could
28
potentially participate in that event.
In fact, the evidence in the record strongly suggests
69
This is because any
For instance, a network
seeking to telecast a conference basketball tournament would have
2
to obtain group licenses from all of the teams in that conference.
3
Under those circumstances, none of the teams in the conference
4
would compete against each other as sellers of group licenses
5
because the group licenses would constitute perfect complements:
6
that is, every group license would have to be sold in order for
7
any single group license to have value.
8
Hovenkamp, “Implementing Antitrust’s Welfare Goals,” 81 Fordham L.
9
Rev. 2471, 2487 (2013) (“Perfect complements are goods that are
10
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
1
invariably used together -- or, more technically, situations in
11
which one good has no value unless it can be consumed together
12
with the other good.”).
13
conference would never have to compete with teams outside of the
14
conference because those teams -- as non-participants in the
15
conference tournament -- would not be able to sell their group
16
licenses with respect to that event in the first place.
17
this scenario, teams of student-athletes would never actually
18
compete against each other as sellers of group licenses, even if
19
the challenged NCAA rules no longer existed.
20
See generally Herbert
At the same time, the teams in that
Thus, in
The same outcome would result whenever any network sought to
21
telecast any other FBS football and Division I basketball event.
22
Although the specific set of group licenses required for each
23
event would vary, the lack of competition among student-athlete
24
teams would remain constant: in every case, the network would need
25
to acquire group licenses from a specific set of teams, none of
26
which would have any incentive to compete either against each
27
other or against any teams whose group licenses were not required
28
for the telecast.
These conditions would hold regardless of
70
1
whether the student-athlete teams sold their group licenses to the
2
television networks directly or through some intermediary, such as
3
their schools, because the demand for group licenses would be
4
dictated primarily by the identity of the teams eligible to
5
participate in each event.
6
might compete against each other in order to secure a specific
7
telecasting contract with a particular network, the challenged
8
NCAA rules do not inhibit this type of competition.
9
are already free to compete against each other in this way.
To the extent that entire conferences
Conferences
So,
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
too, are any individual pairs of schools whose teams are scheduled
11
to play against each other in specific regular season games.
12
the conferences, these pairs may freely compete against other
13
pairs of schools whose games are scheduled for the same time in
14
order to secure a contract with whatever networks can show games
15
during that time slot.
16
presented sufficient evidence to show that student-athlete teams
17
would actually compete against each other in any of these ways if
18
they were permitted to sell group licenses to use their names,
19
images, and likenesses.
20
11
Like
In any event, Plaintiffs have not
Plaintiffs have also failed to identify any situation in
21
which buyers of group licenses might compete against each other.
22
As noted above, there are two sets of potential buyers in this
23
market: the television networks, which would buy group licenses
24
directly from the student-athlete teams, and intermediate buyers,
25
11
26
27
28
The evidence presented at trial suggests that most telecasting
contracts, even for regular season games, are negotiated at the
conference-wide level -- not the individual team level. Nevertheless,
the Court notes that the challenged rules would not suppress competition
in this market even if contracts to telecast regular season games were
negotiated at the individual team level.
71
1
which would bundle those licenses with other rights and sell those
2
bundles of rights to the networks.
3
buyers -- the television networks -- already compete freely
4
against one another for the rights to use student-athletes’ names,
5
images, and likenesses in live game telecasts.
6
not be able to purchase these rights directly from the student-
7
athletes, they nevertheless compete to acquire these rights from
8
other sources, such as schools and conferences.
9
networks do not compete to purchase these rights directly from the
The first set of potential
Although they may
The fact that the
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
student-athletes is due to the assurances by the schools,
11
conferences, and NCAA that they have the authority to grant these
12
rights.
13
schools of the student-athletes’ rights, or otherwise be unlawful,
14
but they are not anticompetitive because they do not inhibit any
15
form of competition that would otherwise exist.
16
student-athletes to seek compensation for group licenses would not
17
increase the number of television networks in the market or
18
otherwise enhance competition among them.
19
Such assurances might constitute conversion by the
12
Allowing
Nor would it increase competition among any potential
20
intermediate buyers in this market, such as third-party licensing
21
companies and schools.
22
television networks, already free to compete against one another
23
to acquire the rights to use student-athletes’ names, images, and
24
likenesses in live game telecasts.
Third-party licensing companies are, like
They may be barred from
25
26
27
28
12
Plaintiffs voluntarily dismissed all of their claims against the
NCAA for “individual damages, disgorgement of profits, and an
accounting.” Docket No. 198, Stip. Dismissal, at 2. They also
dismissed their claims for unjust enrichment. Accordingly, the Court
does not consider these claims here.
72
1
purchasing these rights directly from the student-athletes but
2
they are not barred from competing to acquire these rights through
3
other channels.
4
Unlike television networks and third-party licensing
5
companies, schools do not currently compete for group licenses to
6
use student-athletes’ names, images, and likenesses in live game
7
telecasts.
8
solely from the challenged restraint.
9
lifted, each school would still only be able to purchase group
This lack of competition, however, does not stem
Even if the restraint were
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
licenses from its own student-athletes because those are the only
11
licenses that the school could bundle with its own intellectual
12
property rights for sale to a network.
13
purchase a marketable group license from student-athletes at
14
another school.
15
another for the rights to use individual student-athletes’ names,
16
images, and likenesses, they do so only as sellers in the college
17
education market or consumers in the market for recruits’ athletic
18
services and licensing rights.
19
the market for group licenses.
No school would be able to
To the extent that schools do compete against one
They do not compete as buyers in
20
Accordingly, Plaintiffs have failed to show that the
21
challenged NCAA rules harm competition in this submarket.
22
Although they have presented sufficient evidence to establish that
23
they were injured by the NCAA’s conduct, as noted above, “[i]njury
24
to an antitrust plaintiff is not enough to prove injury to
25
competition.”
26
1464, 1469 (9th Cir. 1986).
27
competition only in the college education market or the market for
28
recruits’ athletic services and licensing rights.
O.S.C. Corp. v. Apple Computer, Inc., 792 F.2d
Plaintiffs have shown an injury to
73
1
2.
2
3
Submarket for Group Licenses to Use StudentAthletes’ Names, Images, and Likenesses in
Videogames
Plaintiffs have presented sufficient evidence to establish
4
that, absent the challenged NCAA rules, a national submarket would
5
exist in which videogame developers would compete for group
6
licenses to use student-athletes’ names, images, and likenesses.
7
This submarket is analogous to the live telecasting submarket
8
discussed above.
9
licenses in the videogame submarket would be student-athletes on
As in that submarket, the sellers of group
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
certain FBS football and Division I basketball teams.
11
would either be videogame developers or intermediate buyers who
12
would bundle the student-athletes’ rights with other parties’
13
rights and sell those bundles to videogame developers.
14
The buyers
The NCAA contends that, even if student-athletes were
15
permitted to receive compensation for the use of their names,
16
images, and likenesses, this submarket would not exist.
17
that it and some of its member conferences recently decided to
18
stop licensing their intellectual property for use in videogames.
19
Without access to this intellectual property, the NCAA argues,
20
videogame developers cannot develop marketable videogames and,
21
thus, would not seek to purchase group licenses from student-
22
athletes.
23
It notes
This argument overstates the significance of the decisions of
24
the NCAA and some of its member conferences not to license their
25
intellectual property to videogame developers.
26
videogame developers do not need the intellectual property rights
27
of both the NCAA and all of its conferences in order to produce a
28
college sports videogame.
To begin with,
If a sufficient number of schools and
74
1
conferences were willing to license their intellectual property
2
for use in videogames, a submarket for student-athletes’ group
3
licenses would likely exist.
4
testified at trial that EA remains interested in acquiring the
5
rights to use student-athletes’ names, images, and likenesses and
6
would seek to acquire them if not for the NCAA’s challenged rules
7
and the present litigation.
8
recent decisions of the NCAA and some of its conferences not to
9
license their intellectual property has not permanently eliminated
Indeed, Mr. Linzner specifically
This testimony suggests that the
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
the demand for group licenses to use student-athletes’ names,
11
images, and likenesses.
12
could have been adopted due to this litigation and could be
13
reversed at any time -- do not establish the lack of a videogame
14
submarket.
15
13
Accordingly, these decisions -- which
Nevertheless, Plaintiffs have not identified any injury to
16
competition within this submarket.
17
telecasting submarket, the ultimate buyers in this submarket --
18
videogame developers -- would need to acquire group licenses from
19
a specific set of teams in order to create their product.
20
set might include all of the teams within Division I, all of the
21
teams within the major conferences, or some other set of teams
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
13
Just as in the live
This
The NCAA’s other argument -- that videogame developers would not
need to acquire group licenses because their use of student-athletes’
names, images, and likenesses is protected under the First Amendment -was rejected by the Ninth Circuit earlier in this litigation. In re
NCAA Student-Athlete Name & Likeness Licensing Litig., 724 F.3d 1268,
1284 (9th Cir. 2013) (concluding that “EA’s use of the likenesses of
college athletes like Samuel Keller in its video games is not, as a
matter of law, protected by the First Amendment”); see also Hart v.
Electronic Arts, Inc., 717 F.3d 141, 170 (3d Cir. 2013) (holding that
“the NCAA Football 2004, 2005 and 2006 games at issue in this case do
not sufficiently transform Appellant’s identity to escape the right of
publicity claim”).
75
1
that the videogame developer believed would be necessary to
2
produce a marketable product.
3
included within that set, those teams would not compete against
4
each other as sellers of group licenses, even in the absence of
5
the challenged rules, because they would all share an interest in
6
ensuring that the videogame developer acquired each of the group
7
licenses required to create its product.
8
not compete against any teams outside of the set because the
9
videogame developer determined that those other teams’ group
Regardless of which teams were
These teams would also
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
licenses were not required to produce the videogame.
11
competition between teams (or conferences) is even less likely in
12
the videogame submarket than the live telecasting submarket
13
because videogame developers -- unlike television networks -- are
14
not constrained by the number of group licenses that they could
15
use to produce their product.
16
demonstrates that videogame companies could, and often did,
17
feature nearly every FBS football and Division I basketball team
18
in their videogames.
19
individual teams and conferences to sell group licenses is
20
extremely unlikely.
21
happen), it is not restrained by the challenged NCAA restrictions
22
on student-athlete compensation.
23
telecasting submarket, the challenged rules do not suppress
24
competition in this submarket.
Indeed,
The evidence presented at trial
Under these circumstances, competition among
And, to the extent that it happens (or would
Thus, just as with the live
25
26
27
28
76
1
3.
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
Submarket for Group Licenses to Use StudentAthletes’ Names, Images, and Likenesses in Game ReBroadcasts, Highlight Clips, and Other Archival
Footage
Plaintiffs allege that the NCAA’s challenged rules impose
restraints on a national submarket for group licenses to use
student-athletes’ names, images, and likenesses in game rebroadcasts, highlight clips, and other archival game footage, both
for entertainment and to advertise products.
However, they have
not presented sufficient evidence to show that the NCAA has
imposed any restraints in this submarket.
As found above, the
undisputed evidence shows that the NCAA has designated a thirdparty agent to negotiate and manage all licensing related to its
archival footage.
That third-party agent, T3Media, is expressly
prohibited from licensing any footage that features current
student-athletes.
It is also contractually required to obtain the
rights to use the names, images, and likenesses of any former
student-athletes who appear in footage that it has licensed.
Thus, under this arrangement, no current or former studentathletes are actually deprived of any compensation for game rebroadcasts or other archival footage that they would otherwise
receive in the absence of the challenged NCAA rules.
What’s more,
even if Plaintiffs had made such a showing, they have not
presented sufficient evidence to show an injury to competition in
this submarket.
In order to license all of the footage in the
NCAA’s archives, T3Media would have to obtain a group license from
every team that has ever competed in FBS or Division I.
These
teams, once again, would have no incentive to compete against each
28
77
1
other in selling their group licenses.
2
enforcing its challenged rules would not change that.
3
III. Procompetitive Justifications
4
Enjoining the NCAA from
Because Plaintiffs have presented sufficient evidence to show
5
that the NCAA’s rules impose a restraint on competition in the
6
college education market, the Court must determine whether that
7
restraint is justified.
8
consider whether the “anticompetitive aspects of the challenged
9
practice outweigh its procompetitive effects.”
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
In making this determination, it must
Paladin
Associates, 328 F.3d at 1156.
11
The NCAA has asserted four procompetitive justifications for
12
its rules barring student-athletes from receiving compensation for
13
the use of their names, images, and likenesses: (1) the
14
preservation of amateurism in college sports; (2) promoting
15
competitive balance among FBS football and Division I basketball
16
teams; (3) the integration of academics and athletics; and (4) the
17
ability to generate greater output in the relevant markets.
18
Court considers each of these procompetitive justifications in
19
turn.
The
20
A.
21
As noted in the findings of fact, the NCAA asserts that its
Amateurism
22
restrictions on student-athlete compensation are necessary to
23
preserve the amateur tradition and identity of college sports.
24
contends that this tradition and identity contribute to the
25
popularity of college sports and help distinguish them from
26
professional sports and other forms of entertainment in the
27
marketplace.
28
commitment to amateurism, recent consumer opinion surveys, and
It
For support, it points to historical evidence of its
78
1
testimony from various witnesses regarding popular perceptions of
2
college sports.
3
restrictions on student-athlete compensation, it does not justify
4
the specific restrictions challenged in this case.
5
it does not justify the NCAA’s sweeping prohibition on FBS
6
football and Division I basketball players receiving any
7
compensation for the use of their names, images, and likenesses.
8
Although the NCAA has cited the Supreme Court’s decision in
9
Although this evidence could justify some limited
In particular,
Board of Regents as support for its amateurism justification, its
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
reliance on the case remains unavailing.
11
orders, Board of Regents addressed limits on television
12
broadcasting, not payments to student-athletes, and “does not
13
stand for the sweeping proposition that student-athletes must be
14
barred, both during their college years and forever thereafter,
15
from receiving any monetary compensation for the commercial use of
16
their names, images, and likenesses.”
17
The Supreme Court’s suggestion in Board of Regents that, in order
18
to preserve the quality of the NCAA’s product, student-athletes
19
“must not be paid,” 468 U.S. at 102, was not based on any factual
20
findings in the trial record and did not serve to resolve any
21
disputed issues of law.
22
assertions of the NCAA’s own counsel in the case, who stated
23
during oral argument that the NCAA was not relying on amateurism
24
as a procompetitive justification and “might be able to get more
25
viewers and so on if it had semi-professional clubs rather than
26
amateur clubs.”
27
85.
28
programs of amateur football, it is probably reducing its net
As explained in previous
Oct. 25, 2013 Order at 15.
In fact, the statement ran counter to the
Oral Arg. Tr. at 25, Board of Regents, 468 U.S.
He further argued, “When the NCAA says, we are running
79
1
profits.”
2
able to increase its intake if it abolished or reduced the
3
academic standards that its players must meet.”).
4
also presented ample evidence here to show that the college sports
5
industry has changed substantially in the thirty years since Board
6
of Regents was decided.
7
1081, 1099 (7th Cir. 1992) (Flaum, J., concurring in part and
8
dissenting in part) (“The NCAA continues to purvey, even in this
9
case, an outmoded image of intercollegiate sports that no longer
Id. (emphasis added); see also id. (“The NCAA might be
Plaintiffs have
See generally Banks v. NCAA, 977 F.2d
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
jibes with reality.
11
Supreme Court’s incidental phrase in Board of Regents does not
12
establish that the NCAA’s current restraints on compensation are
13
procompetitive and without less restrictive alternatives.
14
The times have changed.”).
Accordingly, the
The historical record that the NCAA cites as evidence of its
15
longstanding commitment to amateurism is unpersuasive.
16
record reveals that the NCAA has revised its rules governing
17
student-athlete compensation numerous times over the years,
18
sometimes in significant and contradictory ways.
19
evincing the association’s adherence to a set of core principles,
20
this history documents how malleable the NCAA’s definition of
21
amateurism has been since its founding.
22
This
Rather than
The association’s current rules demonstrate that, even today,
23
the NCAA does not consistently adhere to a single definition of
24
amateurism.
25
status even if he accepts ten thousand dollars in prize money the
26
year before he enrolls in college.
27
recruit, however, would forfeit his athletic eligibility if he did
28
the same.
A Division I tennis recruit can preserve his amateur
A Division I track and field
Similarly, an FBS football player may maintain his
80
1
amateur status if he accepts a Pell grant that brings his total
2
financial aid package above the cost of attendance.
3
football player would no longer be an amateur if he were to
4
decline the Pell grant and, instead, receive an equivalent sum of
5
money from his school for the use of his name, image, and likeness
6
during live game telecasts.
7
indicative of “core principles.”
8
9
But the same
Such inconsistencies are not
Nonetheless, some restrictions on compensation may still
serve a limited procompetitive purpose if they are necessary to
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
maintain the popularity of FBS football and Division I basketball.
11
If the challenged restraints actually play a substantial role in
12
maximizing consumer demand for the NCAA’s products --
13
specifically, FBS football and Division I basketball telecasts,
14
re-broadcasts, ticket sales, and merchandise -- then the
15
restrictions would be procompetitive.
16
U.S. at 120 (recognizing that “maximiz[ing] consumer demand for
17
the product” is a legitimate procompetitive justification).
18
Attempting to make this showing, the NCAA relies on consumer
19
opinion surveys, including the survey it commissioned from Dr.
20
Dennis specifically for this case.
21
survey -- which contained several methodological flaws and did not
22
ask respondents about the specific restraints challenged in this
23
case -- does not provide reliable evidence that consumer interest
24
in FBS football and Division I basketball depends on the NCAA’s
25
current restrictions on student-athlete compensation.
26
Plaintiffs offered evidence demonstrating that such surveys are
27
inevitably a poor tool for accurately predicting consumer
28
behavior.
See Board of Regents, 468
As noted above, however, this
Further,
Dr. Rascher highlighted various polls and surveys which
81
1
documented widespread public opposition to rule changes that
2
ultimately led to increased compensation for professional baseball
3
players and Olympic athletes even as Major League Baseball and the
4
IOC were experiencing periods of massive revenue growth.
5
evidence counsels strongly against giving any significant weight
6
to Dr. Dennis’s survey results.
7
suggest is that the public’s attitudes toward student-athlete
8
compensation depend heavily on the level of compensation that
9
student-athletes would receive.
This
What Dr. Dennis’s survey does
This is consistent with the
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
testimony of the NCAA’s own witnesses, including Mr. Muir and Mr.
11
Pilson, who both indicated that smaller payments to student-
12
athletes would bother them less than larger payments.
13
Ultimately, the evidence presented at trial suggests that
14
consumer demand for FBS football and Division I basketball-related
15
products is not driven by the restrictions on student-athlete
16
compensation but instead by other factors, such as school loyalty
17
and geography.
18
be more popular in places where college teams are located.
19
Similarly, Ms. Plonsky noted that popular interest in college
20
sports was driven principally by the loyalty of local fans and
21
alumni.
22
offered a tiddlywinks team, that would somehow be popular with
23
some segment of whoever loves our university.”
24
1415:2.
25
Mr. Pilson explained that college sports tend to
She testified, “I would venture to say that if we [UT]
Trial Tr. 1414:25-
The Court therefore concludes that the NCAA’s restrictions on
26
student-athlete compensation play a limited role in driving
27
consumer demand for FBS football and Division I basketball-related
28
products.
Although they might justify a restriction on large
82
1
payments to student-athletes while in school, they do not justify
2
the rigid prohibition on compensating student-athletes, in the
3
present or in the future, with any share of licensing revenue
4
generated from the use of their names, images, and likenesses.
5
B.
6
The NCAA asserts that its challenged rules are justified by
Competitive Balance
7
the need to maintain the current level of competitive balance
8
among its FBS football and Division I basketball teams in order to
9
maintain their popularity.
This Court has previously recognized
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
that a sports league’s efforts to achieve the optimal competitive
11
balance among its teams may serve a procompetitive purpose if
12
promoting such competitive balance increases demand for the
13
league’s product.
14
Needle, 560 U.S. at 204 (“We have recognized, for example, ‘that
15
the interest in maintaining a competitive balance’ among ‘athletic
16
teams is legitimate and important.’” (citing Board of Regents, 468
17
U.S. at 117)).
18
“hypothesis that legitimates the maintenance of competitive
19
balance as a procompetitive justification under the Rule of Reason
20
is that equal competition will maximize consumer demand for the
21
product.”
22
See April 11, 2014 Order at 33; American
As the Supreme Court has explained, the
Board of Regents, 468 U.S. at 119-20.
Here, the NCAA has not presented sufficient evidence to show
23
that its restrictions on student-athlete compensation actually
24
have any effect on competitive balance, let alone produce an
25
optimal level of competitive balance.
26
economists who have studied the issue, as summarized by Drs. Noll
27
and Rascher, is that the NCAA’s current restrictions on
28
compensation do not have any effect on competitive balance.
83
The consensus among sports
1
Although Dr. Rubinfeld disagreed with this conclusion, he could
2
not identify another economist who shared his view and did not
3
offer any testimony to rebut the specific findings of the academic
4
literature cited by Drs. Noll and Rascher.
5
him whether his opinions were based on any academic literature,
6
Dr. Rubinfeld directed the Court to the economic articles cited in
7
his most recent report on competitive balance.
8
articles cited in that report found that the NCAA’s restrictions
9
on student-athlete compensation promote competitive balance.
When the Court asked
But none of the
In
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
fact, the only article his report cited that actually examined
11
competitive balance in college sports was a 2004 article by Katie
12
Baird, which Dr. Noll quoted during his testimony.
13
testified, that article concluded, “‘[L]ittle evidence supports
14
the claim that NCAA regulations help level the playing field.
15
best, they appear to have had a very limited effect, and at worst
16
they have served to strengthen the position of the dominant
17
teams.’”
18
Rubinfeld’s independent analysis of competitive balance was also
19
unpersuasive because it did not show a causal link between the
20
NCAA’s challenged rules and competitive balance.
21
importantly, his analysis did not show that consumer demand for
22
the NCAA’s product would decrease if FBS football or Division I
23
basketball teams were less competitively balanced than they
24
currently are.
25
is driven primarily by factors such as school loyalty and
26
geography.
27
28
As Dr. Noll
Trial Tr. 230:18-231:11 (quoting Baird article).
At
Dr.
More
As found above, the popularity of college sports
Neither of these is dependent on competitive balance.
In its post-trial brief, the NCAA cites a passage from Board
of Regents which states that the district court in that case found
84
1
that the NCAA’s “restrictions designed to preserve amateurism”
2
served to promote competitive balance.
3
district court order, 546 F. Supp. 1276, 1296, 1309-10 (W.D. Okla.
4
1982)).
5
more importantly, is contrary to the evidence presented in this
6
case.
7
football and Division I basketball have grown exponentially since
8
Board of Regents was decided and that, as a result of this growth,
9
many schools have invested more heavily in their recruiting
468 U.S. at 119 (citing
That factual finding is not binding on this Court and,
The record in this case shows that revenues from FBS
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
efforts, athletic facilities, dorms, coaching, and other amenities
11
designed to attract the top student-athletes.
12
several witnesses referred to as an “arms race,” has likely
13
negated whatever equalizing effect the NCAA’s restraints on
14
student-athlete compensation might have once had on competitive
15
balance.
16
the wealth of academic studies concluding that the restraints on
17
student-athlete compensation do not promote competitive balance --
18
preclude this Court from giving any significant weight to the
19
district court’s factual findings in Board of Regents.
20
This trend, which
These changed factual circumstances -- in addition to
Accordingly, the NCAA may not rely on competitive balance
21
here as a justification for the challenged restraint.
22
evidence is not sufficient to show that it must create a
23
particular level of competitive balance among FBS football and
24
Division I basketball teams in order to maximize consumer demand
25
for its product.
26
restraint actually helps it achieve the optimal level of
27
competitive balance.
Its
Nor is it sufficient to show that the challenged
28
85
1
C.
2
The NCAA asserts that its restrictions on student-athlete
Integration of Academics and Athletics
3
compensation help educate student-athletes and integrate them into
4
their schools’ academic communities.
5
integration of academics and athletics serves to improve the
6
quality of educational services provided to student-athletes in
7
the restrained college education market.14
8
that this goal -- improving product quality -- may be a legitimate
9
procompetitive justification.
It argues that the
Courts have recognized
See County of Tuolumne v. Sonora
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
Cmty. Hosp., 236 F.3d 1148, 1160 (9th Cir. 2001) (recognizing that
11
improving product quality may be a legitimate procompetitive
12
justification); Law, 134 F.3d at 1023 (recognizing that
13
“increasing output, creating operating efficiencies, making a new
14
product available, enhancing service or quality, and widening
15
consumer choice” may be procompetitive justifications).
16
The evidence presented by the NCAA suggests that integrating
17
student-athletes into the academic communities at their schools
18
improves the quality of the educational services that they
19
receive.
20
testified about the benefits that student-athletes derive from
21
participating in their schools’ academic communities.
22
confirmed that they appreciated receiving these educational
As noted above, several university administrators
Plaintiffs
23
24
14
25
26
27
28
In its post-trial brief, the NCAA argues that the integration of
academics and athletics also increases consumer demand for its other
product -- FBS football and Division I basketball games. It presented
scant evidence at trial to support this assertion. In any event, to the
extent that the NCAA contends that its restrictions on student-athlete
compensation increase consumer demand for FBS football and Division I
basketball games, the Court addresses that argument in its discussion of
the NCAA’s asserted procompetitive justification of amateurism.
86
1
benefits when they were student-athletes, while Dr. Heckman
2
testified that these benefits also carry long-term value.
3
That said, the NCAA has not shown that the specific
4
restraints challenged in this case are necessary to achieve these
5
benefits.
6
educational benefits described above regardless of whether or not
7
the NCAA permitted them to receive compensation for the use of
8
their names, images, and likenesses.
9
receive scholarships, for instance, and would almost certainly
Indeed, student-athletes would receive many of the same
They would continue to
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
continue to receive tutoring and other academic support services.
11
As long as the NCAA continued to monitor schools’ academic
12
progress rates and require that student-athletes meet certain
13
academic benchmarks -- a requirement that is not challenged
14
here -- the schools’ incentives to support their student-athletes
15
academically would remain unchanged.
16
athletes’ own incentives to perform well academically would remain
17
the same, particularly if they were required to meet these
18
academic requirements as a condition of receiving compensation for
19
the use of their names, images, and likenesses.
20
requirement might even strengthen student-athletes’ incentives to
21
focus on schoolwork.
22
Similarly, the student-
Such a
As found above, the only way in which the challenged rules
23
might facilitate the integration of academics and athletics is by
24
preventing student-athletes from being cut off from the broader
25
campus community.
26
compensation may help schools achieve this narrow procompetitive
27
goal.
28
NCAA may not use this goal to justify its sweeping prohibition on
Limited restrictions on student-athlete
As with the NCAA’s amateurism justification, however, the
87
1
any student-athlete compensation, paid now or in the future, from
2
licensing revenue generated from the use of student-athletes’
3
names, images, and likenesses.
4
D.
5
The NCAA argues that the challenged restraint increases the
Increased Output
6
output of its product.
7
output may be a legitimate procompetitive justification.
8
Board of Regents, 468 U.S. at 114; Law, 134 F.3d at 1023.
9
Courts have recognized that increased
See
Here, the NCAA argues that its restrictions on student-
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
athlete compensation increase the number of opportunities for
11
schools and student-athletes to participate in Division I sports,
12
which ultimately increases the number of FBS football and Division
13
I basketball games played.
14
output in two ways: first, by attracting schools with a
15
“philosophical commitment to amateurism” to compete in Division I
16
and, second, by enabling schools that otherwise could not afford
17
to compete in Division I to do so.
18
Trial Brief, at 24.
19
It claims that its rules increase this
Docket No. 279, NCAA Post-
Neither of these arguments is persuasive.
The NCAA has not presented sufficient evidence to show that a
20
significant number of schools choose to compete in Division I
21
because of a “philosophical commitment to amateurism.”
22
in the findings of fact, some Division I conferences have recently
23
sought greater autonomy from the NCAA specifically so that they
24
could enact their own rules, including new scholarship rules.
25
These efforts suggest that many current Division I schools are
26
committed neither to the NCAA’s current restrictions on student-
27
athlete compensation nor to the idea that all Division I schools
28
must award scholarships of the same value.
88
As noted
1
Similarly, the NCAA’s argument that the current rules enable
2
some schools to participate in Division I that otherwise could not
3
afford to do so is unsupported by the record.
4
nor its member conferences require high-revenue schools to
5
subsidize the FBS football or Division I basketball teams at
6
lower-revenue schools.
7
any cost savings by not paying their student-athletes, there is no
8
evidence that those cost savings are being used to fund additional
9
teams or scholarships.
Neither the NCAA
Thus, to the extent that schools achieve
In any event, Plaintiffs are not seeking
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
an injunction requiring schools to provide compensation to their
11
student-athletes -- they are seeking an injunction to permit
12
schools to do so.
13
portion of their athletic budget for this purpose would not be
14
forced to do so.
15
schools’ athletic programs would be driven to financial ruin or
16
would leave Division I if other schools were permitted to pay
17
their student-athletes.
18
increasing spending on training facilities at many schools suggest
19
that these schools would, in fact, be able to afford to offer
20
their student-athletes a limited share of the licensing revenue
21
generated from their use of the student-athletes’ own names,
22
images, and likenesses.
23
increased output as a justification for the challenged restraint
24
here.
25
IV.
26
Schools that cannot afford to re-allocate any
There is thus no reason to believe that any
The high coaches’ salaries and rapidly
Accordingly, the NCAA may not rely on
Less Restrictive Alternatives
As outlined above, the NCAA has produced sufficient evidence
27
to support an inference that some circumscribed restrictions on
28
student-athlete compensation may yield procompetitive benefits.
89
1
First, it presented evidence suggesting that preventing schools
2
from paying FBS football and Division I basketball players large
3
sums of money while they are enrolled in school may serve to
4
increase consumer demand for its product.
5
evidence suggesting that this restriction may facilitate its
6
member schools’ efforts to integrate student-athletes into the
7
academic communities on their campuses, thereby improving the
8
quality of educational services they offer.
9
NCAA has met its burden under the rule of reason to that extent,
Second, it presented
Thus, because the
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
the burden shifts back to Plaintiffs to show that these
11
procompetitive goals can be achieved in “‘other and better
12
ways’” -- that is, through “‘less restrictive alternatives.’”
13
Bhan v. NME Hospitals, Inc., 929 F.2d 1404, 1410 n.4 (9th Cir.
14
1991) (citations omitted).
15
“As part of their burden to show the existence of less
16
restrictive alternatives, [] plaintiffs must also show that ‘an
17
alternative is substantially less restrictive and is virtually as
18
effective in serving the legitimate objective without
19
significantly increased cost.’”
20
1159 (citations omitted; emphasis in original).
21
less restrictive alternatives “should either be based on actual
22
experience in analogous situations elsewhere or else be fairly
23
obvious.”
24
¶ 1913b (3d ed. 2006).
25
restrictive alternative is not feasible with “evidence that the
26
proffered alternative has been tried but failed, that it is
27
equally or more restrictive, or otherwise unlawful.”
County of Tuolomne, 236 F.3d at
In addition, any
Phillip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law
A defendant may show that a proffered less
28
90
Id.
1
A court need not address the availability of less restrictive
2
alternatives for achieving a purported procompetitive goal “when
3
the defendant fails to meet its own obligation under the rule of
4
reason burden-shifting procedure.”
5
1024 n.16 (“Because we hold that the NCAA did not establish
6
evidence of sufficient procompetitive benefits, we need not
7
address question of whether the plaintiffs were able to show that
8
comparable procompetitive benefits could be achieved through
9
viable, less anticompetitive means.”).
Id.; see also Law, 134 F.3d at
Thus, in the present case,
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
the Court does not consider whether Plaintiffs’ proposed less
11
restrictive alternatives would promote competitive balance or
12
increase output because the NCAA failed to meet its burden with
13
respect to these stated procompetitive justifications.
14
the Court’s inquiry focuses only on whether Plaintiffs have
15
identified any less restrictive alternatives for both preserving
16
the popularity of the NCAA’s product by promoting its current
15
Rather,
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
15
The Court notes, however, that the NCAA could easily adopt
several less restrictive rules if it wished to increase competitive
balance or output. With respect to competitive balance, for instance,
the NCAA could adopt a more equal revenue distribution formula. As
noted above, its current formula primarily rewards the schools that
already have the largest athletic budgets. This uneven distribution of
revenues runs counter to the association’s stated goal of promoting
competitive balance. See, e.g., Salvino, 542 F.3d at 333 (noting that
“disproportionate distribution of licensing income would foster a
competitive imbalance” among Major League Baseball teams); Smith v. Pro
Football, Inc., 593 F.2d 1173, 1188 (D.C. Cir. 1978) (“The least
restrictive alternative of all, of course, would be for the NFL to
eliminate the draft entirely and employ revenue-sharing to equalize the
teams’ financial resources [as] a method of preserving ‘competitive
balance’ nicely in harmony with the league’s self-proclaimed ‘jointventure’ status.”). As for the NCAA’s stated goal of increasing output,
the NCAA already has the power to achieve this goal in a much more
direct way: by amending its current requirements for entry into Division
I or increasing the number of athletic scholarships Division I schools
are permitted to offer.
91
1
understanding of amateurism and improving the quality of
2
educational opportunities for student-athletes by integrating
3
academics and athletics.
4
As set forth in the findings of fact, Plaintiffs have
5
identified two legitimate less restrictive alternatives for
6
achieving these goals.
7
and Division I basketball schools to award stipends to student-
8
athletes up to the full cost of attendance, as that term is
9
defined in the NCAA’s bylaws, to make up for any shortfall in its
First, the NCAA could permit FBS football
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
grants-in-aid.
11
in trust limited and equal shares of its licensing revenue to be
12
distributed to its student-athletes after they leave college or
13
their eligibility expires.
14
from funding the stipends or payments held in trust with anything
15
other than revenue generated from the use of the student-athletes’
16
own names, images, and likenesses.
17
these stipends and deferred payments would increase price
18
competition among FBS football and Division I basketball schools
19
in the college education market (or, alternatively, in the market
20
for recruits’ athletic services and licensing rights) without
21
undermining the NCAA’s stated procompetitive objectives.
22
Second, the NCAA could permit its schools to hold
The NCAA could also prohibit schools
Permitting schools to award
The NCAA notes that Dr. Noll did not discuss a system of
23
holding payments in trust for student-athletes in his expert
24
reports or during his testimony.
25
Plaintiffs from proposing such a system as a less restrictive
26
alternative here.
27
restrictive alternatives that are “based on actual experience in
28
analogous situations elsewhere” or otherwise “fairly obvious.”
However, this does not bar
As noted above, courts may consider any less
92
1
Areeda & Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 1913b.
2
for holding payments in trust falls squarely within this category.
3
One of Plaintiffs’ experts, Dr. Rascher, discussed the creation of
4
a trust in his opening report, which was disclosed to the NCAA
5
more than eight months before trial.
6
Report ¶¶ 80, 86.
7
of Dr. Rascher’s report here, it notes that the report provided
8
the NCAA with ample notice of this proposal.
Plaintiffs’ proposal
See Sept. 2013 Rascher
Although the Court does not rely on the content
16
Plaintiffs’ counsel
9
16
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
The Court also notes that, over the past two decades, numerous
commentators have suggested that the NCAA could hold payments in trust
for its student-athletes without violating generally accepted
understandings of amateurism used by other sports organizations. See,
e.g., Sean Hanlon & Ray Yasser, “‘J.J. Morrison’ and His Right of
Publicity Lawsuit Against the NCAA,” 15 Vill. Sports & Ent. L.J. 241,
294 (2008) (“Searching for a solution to the problem posed by this
Comment, commentators have suggested a ‘have-your-cake-and-eat-it-too’
approach whereby a trust would be created, allowing student-athletes the
ability to preserve their amateur status while their athletic
eligibility remains. The money generated through the use of the
commercial value of their identity would be placed in a trust until the
expiration of their athletic eligibility.”); Kristine Mueller, “No
Control over Their Rights of Publicity: College Athletes Left Sitting
the Bench,” 2 DePaul J. Sports L. & Contemp. Probs. 70, 87-88 (2004)
(“One suggestion put forth is to create a trust for the athletes, which
would become available to them upon graduation. . . . [This proposal]
allows the athletes to reap the financial benefits of their labors,
while maintaining the focus on amateur athletics.”); Vladimir P. Belo,
“The Shirts Off Their Backs: Colleges Getting Away with Violating the
Right of Publicity,” 19 Hastings Comm. & Ent. L.J. 133, 155 (1996)
(“Should the NCAA hold steadfastly to its notions of amateurism and
resist payment to the athletes, the trust fund alternative could be a
fair and reasonable compromise. First of all, it could be limited to
certain merchandising monies, such as those associated with selling game
jerseys or any other revenue from marketing a student-athlete’s name and
likeness.”); Stephen M. Schott, “Give Them What They Deserve:
Compensating the Student-Athlete for Participation in Intercollegiate
Athletics,” 3 Sports Law. J. 25, 45 (1996) (“Revenue from television
rights, tickets sales, and donations from boosters could be used to
establish these trust funds. Overall, some type of trust fund may
provide the best alternative way of compensating the student-athlete and
preserving the educational objectives of the NCAA.”); Kenneth L.
Shropshire, “Legislation for the Glory of Sport: Amateurism and
Compensation,” 1 Seton Hall J. Sport L. 7, 27 (1991) (“From an NCAA
established trust fund the student athlete could receive a student life
stipend.”).
93
1
also raised the issue repeatedly during trial and several of the
2
NCAA’s key witnesses -- including Dr. Emmert, Mr. Pilson, and Dr.
3
Rubinfeld -- were specifically given an opportunity to respond to
4
the idea.
5
explanation as to why the NCAA could not implement a trust payment
6
system like the one Plaintiffs propose.
7
concludes that a narrowly tailored trust payment system -- which
8
would allow schools to offer their FBS football and Division I
9
basketball recruits a limited and equal share of the licensing
None of these witnesses provided a persuasive
The Court therefore
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
revenue generated from the use of their names, images, and
11
likenesses -- constitutes a less restrictive means of achieving
12
the NCAA’s stated procompetitive goals.
13
V.
14
Summary of Liability Determinations
For the reasons set forth above, the Court concludes that the
15
NCAA’s challenged rules unreasonably restrain trade in violation
16
of § 1 of the Sherman Act.
17
prohibiting student-athletes from receiving any compensation for
18
the use of their names, images, and likenesses restrains price
19
competition among FBS football and Division I basketball schools
20
as suppliers of the unique combination of educational and athletic
21
opportunities that elite football and basketball recruits seek.
22
Alternatively, the rules restrain trade in the market where these
23
schools compete to acquire recruits’ athletic services and
24
licensing rights.
25
Specifically, the association’s rules
The challenged rules do not promote competitive balance among
26
FBS football and Division I basketball teams, let alone produce a
27
level of competitive balance necessary to sustain existing
28
consumer demand for the NCAA’s FBS football and Division I
94
1
basketball-related products.
2
the NCAA’s output of Division I schools, student-athletes, or
3
football and basketball games.
4
limited procompetitive benefits by marginally increasing consumer
5
demand for the NCAA’s product and improving the educational
6
services provided to student-athletes, Plaintiffs have identified
7
less restrictive ways of achieving these benefits.
8
9
Nor do the rules serve to increase
Although the rules do yield some
In particular, Plaintiffs have shown that the NCAA could
permit FBS football and Division I basketball schools to use the
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
licensing revenue generated from the use of their student-
11
athletes’ names, images, and likenesses to fund stipends covering
12
the cost of attendance for those student-athletes.
13
permit schools to hold limited and equal shares of that licensing
14
revenue in trust for the student-athletes until they leave school.
15
Neither of these practices would undermine consumer demand for the
16
NCAA’s products nor hinder its member schools’ efforts to educate
17
student-athletes.
18
VI.
19
It could also
Remedy
“The several district courts of the United States are
20
invested with jurisdiction to prevent and restrain violations” of
21
§ 1 of the Sherman Act.
22
that Plaintiffs must make a showing of irreparable harm in order
23
to obtain permanent injunctive relief here, it failed to cite any
24
authority holding that such a showing is required in an action
25
brought under the Sherman Act.
26
district courts the authority to enjoin violations of its
27
provisions and does not impose any additional requirements on
28
plaintiffs who successfully establish the existence of an
15 U.S.C. § 4.
Although the NCAA asserts
The Sherman Act itself gives
95
1
unreasonable restraint of trade.
2
enter an injunction to remove any unreasonable elements of the
3
restraint found in this case.17
4
Accordingly, this Court will
Consistent with the less restrictive alternatives found, the
5
Court will enjoin the NCAA from enforcing any rules or bylaws that
6
would prohibit its member schools and conferences from offering
7
their FBS football or Division I basketball recruits a limited
8
share of the revenues generated from the use of their names,
9
images, and likenesses in addition to a full grant-in-aid.
The
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
injunction will not preclude the NCAA from implementing rules
11
capping the amount of compensation that may be paid to student-
12
athletes while they are enrolled in school; however, the NCAA will
13
not be permitted to set this cap below the cost of attendance, as
14
the term is defined in its current bylaws.
15
The injunction will also prohibit the NCAA from enforcing any
16
rules to prevent its member schools and conferences from offering
17
to deposit a limited share of licensing revenue in trust for their
18
FBS football and Division I basketball recruits, payable when they
19
leave school or their eligibility expires.
20
injunction will permit the NCAA to set a cap on the amount of
21
money that may be held in trust, it will prohibit the NCAA from
22
setting a cap of less than five thousand dollars (in 2014 dollars)
23
for every year that the student-athlete remains academically
Although the
24
25
26
27
28
17
In a footnote to its post-trial brief, the NCAA argues for the
first time that “a number of states have made it illegal to offer
[student-athletes] compensation beyond a scholarship or grant-in-aid to
entice them to attend a particular school.” NCAA Post-Trial Brief at
35. However, all of the statutes it cites for support expressly exempt
colleges and universities or distinguish between the prohibited payments
and scholarships, financial aid, and other grants.
96
1
eligible to compete.
2
concerns about student-athlete compensation would be minimized or
3
negated if compensation was capped at a few thousand dollars per
4
year.
5
NCAA permits student-athletes to receive if they qualify for a
6
Pell grant and the amount that tennis players may receive prior to
7
enrollment.
8
suggests that the NCAA’s legitimate procompetitive goals will be
9
undermined by allowing such a modest payment.
The NCAA’s witnesses stated that their
This is also comparable to the amount of money that the
None of the other evidence presented at trial
Schools may offer
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
lower amounts of deferred compensation if they choose but may not
11
unlawfully conspire with each another in setting these amounts.
12
To ensure that the NCAA may achieve its goal of integrating
13
academics and athletics, the injunction will not preclude the NCAA
14
from enforcing its existing rules -- or enacting new rules -- to
15
prevent student-athletes from using the money held in trust for
16
their benefit to obtain other financial benefits while they are
17
still in school.
18
representation that they are only seeking to enjoin restrictions
19
on the sharing of group licensing revenue, the NCAA may enact and
20
enforce rules ensuring that no school may offer a recruit a
21
greater share of licensing revenue than it offers any other
22
recruit in the same class on the same team.
23
compensation schools decide to place in trust may vary from year
24
to year.
25
continuing to enforce all of its other existing rules which are
26
designed to achieve its legitimate procompetitive goals.
27
includes its rules prohibiting student-athletes from endorsing
28
commercial products, setting academic eligibility requirements,
Furthermore, consistent with Plaintiffs’
The amount of
Nothing in the injunction will preclude the NCAA from
97
This
1
prohibiting schools from creating athlete-only dorms, and setting
2
limits on practice hours.
3
preclude the NCAA from enforcing its current rules limiting the
4
total number of football and basketball scholarships each school
5
may award, which are not challenged here.
6
Nor shall anything in this injunction
The injunction will not be stayed pending any appeal of this
7
order but will not take effect until the start of next FBS
8
football and Division I basketball recruiting cycle.
9
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
CONCLUSION
College sports generate a tremendous amount of interest, as
11
well as revenue and controversy.
12
and conflicting opinions about the best policies to apply in
13
regulating these sports.
14
whether the NCAA violates antitrust law by agreeing with its
15
member schools to restrain their ability to compensate Division I
16
men’s basketball and FBS football players any more than the
17
current association rules allow.
18
the Court finds that this restraint does violate antitrust law.
Interested parties have strong
Before the Court in this case is only
For the reasons set forth above,
19
To the extent other criticisms have been leveled against the
20
NCAA and college policies and practices, those are not raised and
21
cannot be remedied based on the antitrust causes of action in this
22
lawsuit.
23
other perceived inequities in college athletics and higher
24
education generally, could be better addressed as a policy matter
25
by reforms other than those available as a remedy for the
26
antitrust violation found here.
27
be undertaken by the NCAA, its member schools and conferences, or
28
Congress.
It is likely that the challenged restraints, as well as
Such reforms and remedies could
Be that as it may, the Court will enter an injunction,
98
1
in a separate order, to cure the specific violations found in this
2
case.
3
The clerk shall enter judgment in favor of the Plaintiff
4
class.
5
parties shall not file any post-trial motions based on arguments
6
that have already been made.
7
IT IS SO ORDERED.
Plaintiffs shall recover their costs from the NCAA.
The
8
9
United States District Court
For the Northern District of California
10
Dated: August 8, 2014
CLAUDIA WILKEN
United States District Judge
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
99
Disclaimer: Justia Dockets & Filings provides public litigation records from the federal appellate and district courts. These filings and docket sheets should not be considered findings of fact or liability, nor do they necessarily reflect the view of Justia.
Why Is My Information Online?