Aya Healthcare Services, Inc. et al v. AMN Healthcare, Inc.

Filing 34

ORDER Granting in Part and Denying in Part 30 Defendants' Motion to Dismiss Plaintiffs' Second Amended Complaint. The Court grants in part and denies in part Defendants' motion to dismiss Plaintiffs' SAC. The Court dismisses Pla intiffs' tortious interference with prospective economic relations claim without prejudice. Plaintiffs may file a third amended complaint that cures the deficiencies addressed herein with respect to the tortious interference with prospective economic relations claim on or before 6/29/2018. Signed by Judge Michael M. Anello on 6/19/2018. (rmc)

Download PDF
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT 9 10 11 SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA AYA HEALTHCARE SERVICES, INC., AYA HEALTHCARE, INC., 12 Case No.: 17cv205-MMA (MDD) ORDER GRANTING IN PART AND DENYING IN PART DEFENDANTS’ MOTION TO DISMISS PLAINTIFFS’ SECOND AMENDED COMPLAINT Plaintiffs, 13 v. 14 AMN HEALTHCARE, INC., AMN HEALTHCARE SERVICE, INC., AMN SERVICES, LLC, MEDEFIX, INC., and SHIFTWISE, INC., 15 16 17 [Doc. No. 30] Defendants. 18 19 Plaintiffs Aya Healthcare Services, Inc. and Aya Healthcare, Inc. (collectively, 20 “Plaintiffs” or “Aya”) filed a Second Amended Complaint (“SAC”) against Defendants 21 AMN Healthcare, Inc., AMN Service, Inc., AMN Services, LLC, MEDEFIS, Inc., and 22 Shiftwise, Inc. (collectively, “Defendants” or “AMN”) alleging three federal antitrust 23 claims: a per se claim under Section 1 of the Sherman Act (15 U.S.C. § 1); a quick-look 24 and/or rule of reason claim under Section 1 of the Sherman Act; a claim for attempted 25 monopolization under Section 2 of the Sherman Act (15 U.S.C. § 2); and three California 26 state law claims. See SAC. Defendants now move to dismiss Plaintiffs’ SAC pursuant to 27 Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 12(b)(6). See Doc. No. 30. Plaintiffs filed an opposition 28 to Defendants’ motion, to which Defendants replied. See Doc. Nos. 31, 32. The Court -1- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 found the matter suitable for determination on the papers and without oral argument 2 pursuant to Civil Local Rule 7.1.d.1. See Doc. No. 33. For the reasons set forth below, 3 the Court GRANTS IN PART and DENIES IN PART Defendants’ motion to dismiss. BACKGROUND1 4 5 Plaintiff Aya Healthcare Services, Inc. is a corporation formed under the laws of 6 Delaware that maintains its headquarters in San Diego, California. SAC ¶ 16. Plaintiff 7 Aya Healthcare, Inc. is a corporation formed under the laws of Delaware that maintains 8 its headquarters in San Diego, California. Id. “Plaintiffs are affiliated companies that 9 operate under common control and ownership.” Id. 10 Defendant AMN Healthcare Services, Inc. is a corporation formed under the laws 11 of Delaware that maintains its headquarters in San Diego, California. Id. ¶ 17. 12 Defendant AMN Healthcare, Inc. is a Nevada corporation that maintains its headquarters 13 in San Diego, California. Id. ¶ 18. Defendant AMN Services, LLC is a limited liability 14 company formed under state law that maintains its headquarters in San Diego, California. 15 Id. ¶ 19. Defendant MEDEFIS, Inc. is a corporation formed under state law that 16 maintains its headquarters in Omaha, Nebraska. Id. ¶ 20. Defendants Shiftwise, Inc. is a 17 corporation formed under state law that maintains its headquarters in Portland, Oregon. 18 Id. ¶ 21. Defendant AMN Healthcare Services, Inc. owns and controls Defendant AMN 19 Healthcare, Inc. and the various affiliated companies also sued in this action. See id. ¶ 20 22. 21 Plaintiffs are two affiliated companies that “sell medical-traveler services to 22 hospitals.”2 Id. ¶ 30. Defendants also offer these services and are the dominant providers 23 of such services in the country. See id. ¶ 3. Defendants’ “pool of travelers is by far the 24 largest and most varied in the country.” Id. ¶ 35. Moreover, Defendants operate “two 25                                                 26 27 28 1 Because this matter is before the Court on a motion to dismiss, the Court must accept as true the allegations set forth in the SAC. See Hosp. Bldg. Co. v. Trs. of Rex Hosp., 425 U.S. 738, 740 (1976). 2 “Hospitals” hereinafter refers to both hospitals and other healthcare facilities. -2- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 software platforms that [their] customers can use to procure travelers from other 2 providers.” Id. Defendants further operate “the largest subcontractor network in the 3 country, employing virtually all other providers in the United States as [their] 4 subcontractors.” Id. ¶ 35. 5 “Travelers are licensed nurses and medical technicians who travel from place to 6 place in order to perform temporary assignments at understaffed hospitals.” Id. ¶ 31. 7 Hospitals do not directly hire medical travelers, but utilize the services of personnel 8 agencies like Plaintiffs and Defendants. See id. These personnel agencies are thus 9 responsible for recruiting qualified medical travelers and coordinating their temporary 10 assignment to hospitals. See id. 11 Generally, Plaintiffs allege that Defendants utilize “a series of mutually reinforcing 12 contractual restraints, including restraints that are unlawful per se, to orchestrate the 13 following outcome: (1) Defendants alone will keep control of the only ‘pool’ of travelers 14 that is sufficiently large and varied to meet the requirements of many or most hospital 15 networks and large hospitals[;]” and “(2) the other rival providers, including Plaintiffs, 16 have been prevented or greatly hindered by Defendants’ restraints from developing their 17 own traveler pools and deploying them in order to compete for the large hospitals’ 18 business and to compete in general in the medical-traveler markets.” Id. ¶ 4. 19 Additionally, by using these practices, Defendants have “specifically intended to acquire 20 monopoly power in the medical-traveler markets. On present trends, there exists a 21 dangerous probability that it will succeed in the effort unless there is an antitrust 22 intervention.” Id. ¶ 330. The Court summarizes the various restraints below. 23 A. 24 No-Poaching Restraints Plaintiffs allege that Defendants oblige “all of [their] subcontractor providers and 25 software-platform providers . . . to accept unilateral no-poaching agreements[.]” Id. ¶ 26 123. These no-poaching agreements “forbid the rival providers in perpetuity to initiate 27 job offers or otherwise solicit any of AMN’s designated ‘employees,’ no matter how or 28 where employed, and even when not currently on assignment for AMN.” Id. (emphasis -3- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 in original). Each rival provider “accepts AMN’s No-Poaching Restraint as an obligatory 2 condition precedent to receiving spillover assignments or access to one of AMN’s 3 software platforms.” Id. at 125. Defendants have “prevailed on nearly all other providers 4 in the United States to accept and observe [their] unilateral No-Poaching Restraints.” Id. 5 ¶ 124. Plaintiffs allege that even if a rival provider agrees one time to act as AMN’s 6 subcontractor, and then that rival sends a single traveler to a remote hospital for one 7 assignment, the “rival thereafter remains expressly forbidden to initiate at any time in the 8 future an employment discussion for any purpose with any of AMN’s 8000 travelers or 9 2500 recruiters and other professionals.” Id. ¶ 132. Defendants, on the other hand, are 10 not subject to a reciprocal restraint. See id. As a result, Plaintiffs contend Defendants 11 have “successfully organized a unilateral employers’ cartel in the medical-traveler 12 markets.” Id. ¶ 124. 13 In order to obtain spillover work, Plaintiffs agreed to “more than twenty of AMN’s 14 subcontractor agreements, each of which includes its No-Poaching Restraints.” Id. ¶ 129. 15 Plaintiffs adhered to these restraints from 2010 to May 2015, when they decided to no 16 longer honor them. See id. During this five-year period, Plaintiffs “lost opportunities 17 and profits[.]” Id. ¶ 263. Plaintiffs assert they continue to suffer harm after ceasing to 18 adhere to Defendants’ no-poaching restraints. For example, “[o]ther providers 19 continually solicit Aya’s recruits, but not AMN’s recruiters.” Id. ¶ 276. Thus, 20 Defendants’ no-poaching restraints place Plaintiffs at a competitive disadvantage because 21 they must “offer inducements to their best employees to avoid losing them to rivals,” 22 while Defendants are “insulated from this competition[.]” Doc. No. 31 at 9. 23 B. 24 No-Hire Restraints Plaintiffs also allege that Defendants proposed multiple no-hire agreements to 25 them from 2014 to 2016 in exchange for spillover assignments, but Plaintiffs “rejected 26 each proposal.” Id. ¶ 146. Plaintiffs “believe[] that other direct competitors of AMN 27 have felt constrained to accept its proposed no-hire agreements, and that AMN proposes, 28 monitors and enforces these agreements.” Id. ¶ 157. In fact, Plaintiffs are aware of facts -4- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 which confirm that at least one other provider of travelers, Host Healthcare, Inc. (“Host”) 2 agreed to a unilateral no-hire agreement. Id. ¶¶ 158-59; 171. By enforcing the no- 3 poaching and no-hire restraints, Defendants have “established and operated a non- 4 reciprocal employers’ cartel in the medical-traveler markets.” Id. ¶ 297. 5 C. 6 Employee Restraints & Sham Litigation Moreover, Plaintiffs claim that in order to reinforce their no-poaching restraints, 7 Defendants require “all of [their] travelers, recruiters and other employees to accept 8 broadly worded non-solicitation covenants and trade-secret covenants as conditions of 9 their employment at AMN[.]” Id. ¶ 172. The alleged employee restraints provide that 10 the names and contact information of Defendants’ employees are “classified as AMN’s 11 trade secrets, and the designation applies to AMN’s present employees as well as all 12 other travelers enrolled on its rosters, including those who have no current assignment 13 from AMN.” Id. ¶ 173. The employee restraints also include “broad non-solicitation 14 covenants, which forbid any former employee of AMN to solicit any of its designated 15 ‘employees’ for one year or eighteen months[.]” Id. 16 Plaintiffs allege that if a recruiter working for Defendants accepts employment 17 from a rival provider, and contacts any of the travelers they designate as their trade 18 secrets, Defendants threaten to initiate, and on four occasions have initiated, “objectively 19 baseless claims against both the recruiter and [their] rival[.]” Id. ¶ 182. In October 2015, 20 Defendants sued Plaintiffs, and two of Defendants’ former recruiters who came to work 21 for Plaintiffs, in California state court. Id. ¶ 193. The Superior Court determined in 22 April 2017 that Defendants’ claims in the state court action were both “objectively 23 baseless” and “subjectively baseless[.]” Id. ¶ 205. 24 D. Software Platform Restraints and Exclusive Dealings Contracts 25 Plaintiffs further allege that Defendants use two other kinds of contractual 26 restraints: (1) restrictive covenants in their software-platform agreements and vendor- 27 provider agreements; and (2) mandatory exclusive-dealing contracts with large hospitals. 28 Id. ¶ 226. As a result of Defendants’ “exclusive-dealing contracts and software-platform -5- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 sales, AMN has foreclosed competition for 50% of all sales of medical-traveler services 2 in several of the largest, most lucrative regional submarkets, including the Greater Los 3 Angeles Metropolitan Area; the San Francisco Bay Area; the Greater Washington, D.C. 4 Metropolitan Area; [and] the Greater Baltimore Metropolitan Area[.]” Id. ¶ 229. 5 Additionally, Defendants have used these practices to substantially foreclose competition 6 in the following regional submarkets: Hawaii (87% market foreclosure); Nebraska (83%); 7 Maine (83%); Vermont (80%); Arkansas (73%); Montana (67%); Nevada (64%); and 8 New Hampshire (61%). Id. ¶ 230. “These restrictive conditions exist principally to 9 protect AMN from competitive pressures,” yet the conditions “prevent rival sellers from 10 offering innovative or more competitive terms of service and from providing more 11 responsive service[.]” Id. ¶ 227. 12 E. Summary of Plaintiffs’ Allegations 13 In sum, Plaintiffs assert that the “cumulative effect of AMN’s no-poaching 14 restraints and Employee Restraints is pernicious and exclusionary for AMN’s rivals: the 15 rivals cannot solicit any of AMN’s employees, and AMN’s recruiters, who are best 16 placed to solicit these employees, dare not leave AMN to work for any rival.” Id. ¶ 219. 17 “There is therefore a chronic, worsening shortage of available travelers and only one 18 conspicuously large pool of them—AMN’s pool.” Id. ¶ 221. Defendants have utilized 19 “unlawful trade restraints and baseless litigation to prevent and discourage [their] rivals 20 from seeking to make hires from this pool. [Their] purpose is to remain the only provider 21 that can offer such as pool.” Id. 22 PROCEDURAL HISTORY 23 Plaintiffs commenced the instant action on February 2, 2017. See Doc. No. 1. 24 Defendants previously moved to dismiss Plaintiffs’ First Amended Complaint (“FAC”). 25 See Doc. No. 15. The Court held a hearing on Defendants’ motion on July 14, 2017 and 26 entertained the oral arguments of counsel. See Doc. No. 20. The Court took the matter 27 under submission for further review and consideration, and issued an order granting in 28 part Defendants’ motion to dismiss Plaintiffs’ FAC. See Doc. No. 22. Specifically, the -6- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 Court found that Plaintiffs failed to sufficiently allege antitrust standing, a requisite 2 element of their Sherman Act claims. See id. at 8. The Court deferred ruling on 3 Plaintiffs’ state law claims until Plaintiffs could sufficiently allege a federal claim. See 4 id.3 5 On January 8, 2018, Plaintiffs filed their SAC asserting six causes of action for: (1) 6 per se violations of Section 1 of the Sherman Act; (2) quick-look/rule of reason violations 7 of Section 1 of the Sherman Act; (3) attempted monopolization in violation of Section 2 8 of the Sherman Act; (4) violations of the California Cartwright Act; (5) Tortious 9 Interference with Prospective Economic Relations; and (6) violations of California’s 10 Unfair Competition Law (“UCL”). See SAC. On February 5, 2018, Defendants filed the 11 instant motion, seeking to dismiss Plaintiffs’ SAC with prejudice. See Doc. No. 30. 12 13 LEGAL STANDARD A Rule 12(b)(6) motion to dismiss tests the sufficiency of the complaint. Navarro 14 v. Block, 250 F.3d 729, 732 (9th Cir. 2001). A pleading must contain “a short and plain 15 statement of the claim showing that the pleader is entitled to relief. . . .” Fed. R. Civ. P. 16 8(a)(2). However, plaintiffs must also plead “enough facts to state a claim to relief that is 17 plausible on its face.” Fed. R. Civ. P. 12(b)(6); Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544, 18 570 (2007). The plausibility standard thus demands more than a formulaic recitation of 19 the elements of a cause of action, or naked assertions devoid of further factual 20 enhancement. Ashcroft v. Iqbal, 556 U.S. 662, 678 (2009). Instead, the complaint “must 21 contain allegations of underlying facts sufficient to give fair notice and to enable the 22 opposing party to defend itself effectively.” Starr v. Baca, 652 F.3d 1202, 1216 (9th Cir. 23 2011). 24 25 26 27 28 In reviewing a motion to dismiss under Rule 12(b)(6), courts must assume the truth                                                 3 Because the Court determined that Plaintiffs failed to sufficiently allege antitrust standing in their FAC, the Court did not address the merits of Plaintiffs’ claims. The parties now wish to incorporate by reference arguments made in their respective briefs regarding Plaintiffs’ FAC. As such, the Court cites to such documents where relevant. -7- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 of all factual allegations and must construe them in the light most favorable to the 2 nonmoving party. Cahill v. Liberty Mut. Ins. Co., 80 F.3d 336, 337-38 (9th Cir. 1996). 3 The court need not take legal conclusions as true merely because they are cast in the form 4 of factual allegations. Roberts v. Corrothers, 812 F.2d 1173, 1177 (9th Cir. 1987). 5 Similarly, “conclusory allegations of law and unwarranted inferences are not sufficient to 6 defeat a motion to dismiss.” Pareto v. FDIC, 139 F.3d 696, 699 (9th Cir. 1998). 7 In determining the propriety of a Rule 12(b)(6) dismissal, courts generally may not 8 look beyond the complaint for additional facts. United States v. Ritchie, 342 F.3d 903, 9 908 (9th Cir. 2003). “A court may, however, consider certain materials—documents 10 attached to the complaint, documents incorporated by reference in the complaint, or 11 matters of judicial notice—without converting the motion to dismiss into a motion for 12 summary judgment.” Id.; see also Lee v. City of Los Angeles, 250 F.3d 668, 688 (9th Cir. 13 2001). Where dismissal is appropriate, a court should grant leave to amend unless the 14 plaintiff could not possibly cure the defects in the pleading. Knappenberger v. City of 15 Phoenix, 566 F.3d 936, 942 (9th Cir. 2009). 16 DISCUSSION 17 Defendants move to dismiss Plaintiffs’ SAC in its entirety, arguing that Plaintiffs 18 fail to allege facts showing that they suffered antitrust injury, and that Plaintiffs fail to 19 sufficiently plead each of their six causes of action. See Doc. No. 30-1. The Court 20 addresses Defendants’ arguments in turn. 21 A. 22 Antitrust Injury As a threshold matter, Defendants argue that Plaintiffs have again failed to allege 23 antitrust injury. See Doc. No. 30-1 at 3. The Court previously found Plaintiffs’ 24 allegations regarding antirust injury insufficient. See Doc. No. 22. Plaintiffs assert that 25 they have cured these deficiencies in their SAC by alleging two types of harm: (1) 26 exclusionary harm; and (2) retaliatory harm. See SAC ¶ 262. 27 “Private suits to enforce the Sherman Act are authorized by Section 4 of the 28 Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. § 15(a), which provides that ‘any person who shall be injured in -8- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 his business or property by reason of anything forbidden in the antitrust laws may sue 2 therefor . . . .’” Knevelbaard Dairies v. Kraft Foods, Inc., 232 F.3d 979, 987 (9th Cir. 3 2000). The Supreme Court has interpreted “any person” to mean any person who has 4 suffered an “antitrust injury, which is to say injury of the type the antitrust laws were 5 intended to prevent and that flows from that which makes defendants’ acts unlawful.” 6 Atl. Richfield Co. v. USA Petroleum Co., 495 U.S. 328, 334 (1990) (quoting Brunswick 7 Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477, 489 (1977) (emphasis in original)). 8 “An injury caused by an antitrust violation will not count as an antitrust injury ‘unless it 9 is attributable to an anti-competitive aspect of the practice under scrutiny.’” Int’l 10 Longshore and Warehouse Union v. ICTSI Or., Inc., 863 F.3d 1178, 1186 (9th Cir. 2017) 11 (quoting Atl. Richfield Co., 495 U.S. at 334). “If the injury flows from aspects of the 12 defendant’s conduct that are beneficial or neutral to competition, there is no antitrust 13 injury, even if the defendant’s conduct is illegal per se.” Rebel Oil Co., Inc. v. Atl. 14 Richfield Co., 51 F.3d 1421, 1433 (9th Cir. 1995). 15 In determining whether a plaintiff has antitrust standing, the Ninth Circuit has 16 outlined various factors for courts to consider: (1) whether the plaintiff’s injury is of “the 17 type the antitrust laws were intended to forestall;” (2) the directness of the injury; (3) the 18 speculative nature of the harm; (4) the risk of duplicative recovery; and (5) the 19 complexity of apportioning damages. Knevelbaard Dairies, 232 F.3d at 987. “A 20 showing of the first factor—antitrust injury—is ‘necessary, but not always sufficient, to 21 establishing standing under [section] 4 [of the Clayton Act].’” Tawfilis v. Allergan, Inc., 22 157 F. Supp. 3d 853, 862 (C.D. Cal. 2015) (citing Am. Ad Mgmt. Inc. v. Gen. Tel. Co. of 23 Cal., 190 F.3d 1051, 1055 (9th Cir. 1999) (internal quotation marks and citation 24 omitted)). The Ninth Circuit also requires “that the injured party be a participant in the 25 same market as the alleged malefactors.” Bhan v. NME Hosps., Inc., 772 F.2d 1467, 26 1470 (9th Cir. 1985). “In other words, the party alleging the injury must be either a 27 consumer of the alleged violator’s goods or services or a competitor of the alleged 28 violator in the restrained market.” Glen Holly Entm’t, Inc. v. Tektronix, Inc., 352 F.3d -9- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 367, 372 (9th Cir. 2003) (citation omitted). 2 1. Exclusionary Harm 3 Plaintiffs first contend that Defendants utilize various anticompetitive practices to 4 impede their rivals, including Plaintiffs.4 Defendants argue that Plaintiffs fail to allege 5 antitrust standing because Plaintiffs’ allegations are conclusory and speculative, Plaintiffs 6 stand to gain from the challenged practices, and Plaintiffs’ injury does not flow from any 7 anticompetitive aspect of conduct prohibited under the laws. See Doc. No. 30-1 at 5-10. 8 Here, contrary to Defendants’ contention that Plaintiffs’ allegations are 9 “conclusory” and “speculative,” the Court finds that Plaintiffs have alleged with the 10 requisite specificity facts sufficient to support antitrust injury. Doc. No. 30-1 at 5; cf. 11 Twombly, 550 U.S. at 555 (noting a plaintiff cannot merely rely on “labels and 12 conclusions.”). For example, Plaintiffs allege that from 2010 to May 2015, Defendants’ 13 “restraints appreciably compromised and hindered Aya’s efforts to form a large, varied 14 pool of travelers that could compete for large contracts and compete generally in the 15 medical-traveler markets.” Id. ¶ 263. As a result, Plaintiffs “lost opportunities and 16 profits” during this five-year period of time. Id. Plaintiffs also claim they continue to 17 suffer harm after ceasing to adhere to Defendants’ no-poaching restraints because 18 “[o]ther providers continually solicit Aya’s recruits, but not AMN’s recruiters.” Id. ¶ 19 276. Thus, Defendants’ no-poaching restraints place Plaintiffs at a competitive 20 disadvantage because they must “offer inducements to their best employees to avoid 21 losing them to rivals,” while Defendants are “insulated from this competition[.]” Doc. 22 No. 31 at 9.5                                                 23 24 25 26 27 28 4 Defendants do not address Plaintiffs’ cumulative exclusionary effect argument, but rather address each of the challenged practices in isolation. 5 Defendants assert that Plaintiffs cannot show injury-in-fact, as Plaintiffs have alleged no facts to show that they suffered any loss prior to May 2015, and, after that date, Plaintiffs refused to abide by the restrictions. Doc. No. 30-1 at 3 n.4. The Court disagrees. Plaintiffs specifically allege that they lost opportunities and profits from 2010 to May 2015, and continue to suffer harm because other providers solicit Plaintiffs’ recruiters, while Defendants are immune from such solicitations. See SAC ¶¶ 263, -10- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 Moreover, Plaintiffs allege that Defendants enforce employee restraints and 2 conduct sham litigation in order to: (1) disrupt rivals’ operations and subject them to 3 unreasonable litigation costs; (2) cast a chilling effect on employees and rival providers 4 in the affected markets; and (3) force rivals to assent to unlawful demands. See id. ¶ 208. 5 Plaintiffs claim that through Defendants’ “exclusive-dealing contracts and software- 6 platform sales, AMN has foreclosed competition for 50% of all sales of medical-traveler 7 services in several of the largest, most lucrative regional submarkets[.]” Id. ¶ 229. These 8 conditions “prevent rival sellers from offering innovative or more competitive terms of 9 service and from providing more responsive service[.]” Id. ¶ 227. As such, Plaintiffs’ 10 11 allegations are sufficiently detailed. Further, Defendants’ argument that Plaintiffs stand to gain from the challenged 12 practices is unavailing. See Doc. No. 30-1 at 6-7. The Ninth Circuit has indicated that 13 “[t]here can be no antitrust injury if the plaintiff stands to gain from the alleged unlawful 14 conduct.” Am. Ad Mgmt., Inc., 190 F.3d at 1056. However, Plaintiffs expressly allege 15 that Defendants’ no-poaching restraints prevent rivals, including Plaintiffs, from offering 16 traveler pools that can meet the requirements of large customers and compete against 17 Defendants’ pool. See SAC ¶¶ 126-28, 145. Moreover, Defendants enforce their 18 employee restraints and conduct sham litigation not to improve their services, but to 19 “disrupt” their “rivals’ operations and undermine their ability to recruit qualified 20 travelers.” Id. ¶ 213. Defendants charge major hospital networks and large hospitals 21 “prices that are significantly and durably higher than competitive prices, yet [their] 22 customers largely do not turn to other providers because they believe that they require 23 access to [their] pool of medical travelers, software platforms, and subcontractor 24 network.” Id. ¶ 97. As such, the Court is “satisfied that [Plaintiffs] stand to suffer, not 25 gain,” from Defendants’ conduct. Am. Ad. Mgmt., Inc., 190 F.3d at 1056. 26                                                 27 28 276. As such, the Court finds that Plaintiffs’ allegations relating to the no-poaching restraints are sufficient to show injury-in-fact. -11- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 Finally, Defendants contend that Plaintiffs’ alleged injury does not flow from an 2 anticompetitive aspect of conduct prohibited by the antitrust laws. See Doc. No. 30-1 at 3 6. However, Plaintiffs claim that the various trade restraints “have prevented or hindered 4 other providers from developing their own competitive pools of medical-travelers.” SAC 5 ¶ 260. As a result, “AMN calls the shots, the large hospitals must submit to its pricing 6 and other terms, its employees become its captive, and numerous smaller rivals are 7 deprived of the opportunity to cobble together better prices, alternative terms and 8 alternative service arrangements for the same pool of qualified travelers.” Id. “AMN has 9 used a medley of trade restraints in ways that have harmed competition and reinforced its 10 market power.” Id. ¶ 261. “[T]he central purpose of the antitrust laws, state and federal, 11 is to preserve competition. It is competition . . . that these statutes recognize as vital to 12 the public interest.” Knevelbaard Dairies, 232 F.3d at 988. Because Plaintiffs allege that 13 Defendants’ restraints and practices “prevent competition,” Plaintiffs have sufficiently 14 demonstrated that their injury is of the type that the antitrust laws were intended to 15 prevent. Doc. No. 31 at 2. 16 In sum, Plaintiffs have sufficiently alleged that as a consequence of the alleged 17 restraints, Plaintiffs and other rival suppliers have been prevented from developing their 18 own traveler pools, and are thus unable to compete for business in the medical-traveler 19 markets. See Areeda ¶ 348a6 (“[A] rival clearly has standing to challenge the conduct of 20 rival(s) that . . . tends to exclude rivals from the market, thus leading to reduced output 21 and higher prices.”); Am. Ad. Mgmt., Inc., 190 F.3d at 1057 (“[C]onsumers and 22 competitors are most likely to suffer antitrust injury”). Accordingly, viewing these 23 allegations in the light most favorable to Plaintiffs, the Court finds that Plaintiffs have 24 satisfied the antitrust standing requirement on the basis of exclusionary harm. See 25 26 27 28                                                 6 Citations to “Areeda” refer to PHILLIP E. AREEDA & HERBERT HOVENKAMP, AN ANALYSIS OF ANTITRUST PRINCIPLES AND THEIR APPLICATION (4th ed. 2013). -12- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 Cascade Health Sols. v. PeaceHealth, 515 F.3d 883, 894 (9th Cir. 2008) (concluding that 2 a rival suffers antitrust injury when a defendant’s “[a]nticompetitive conduct . . . tends to 3 impair the opportunities of rivals and either does not further competition on the merits or 4 does so in an unnecessarily restrictive way.”); Catch Curve, Inc. v. Venali, Inc., 519 F. 5 Supp. 2d 1028, 1035-36 (C.D. Cal. 2007) (finding competitor sufficiently pleaded 6 antitrust injury where the defendant’s conduct “rendered competitors less competitive” 7 and had a “dangerous probability of stifling innovation in the market.”) (internal 8 quotation marks and alterations omitted). 9 2. Retaliatory Harm 10 Plaintiffs also assert that they have suffered retaliatory harm. Specifically, 11 Defendants have prevailed on “virtually all rival providers” to accept their no-poaching 12 restraints in exchange for spillover work. Doc. No. 31 at 13. Plaintiffs claim that they 13 have “broken ranks with this de facto employers’ cartel.” Id. As a result, Defendants 14 subjected Plaintiffs to “costly retaliatory measures to make an example[.]” Id. 15 Defendants assert Plaintiffs’ amended allegations are insufficient to sufficiently allege 16 retaliatory harm. See Doc. No. 32 at 5. 17 Plaintiffs rely primarily on a decision from the Seventh Circuit, wherein the court 18 stated that “[l]osses inflicted by a cartel in retaliation for an attempt by one member to 19 compete with the others are certainly compensable under the antitrust laws, for otherwise 20 an effective deterrent to successful cartelization would be eliminated.” Hammes v. 21 AAMCO Transmissions, Inc., 33 F.3d 774, 783 (7th Cir. 1994); see also Big Bear 22 Lodging Ass’n v. Snow Summit, Inc., 182 F.3d 1096, 1102 (9th Cir. 1999) (noting that 23 retaliation by a cartel member against one member attempting to compete is 24 compensable). The Seventh Circuit later clarified that Hammes “holds that antitrust 25 damages may result if a cartel inflicts damage on one of its own members in retaliation 26 for that member’s attempt to undercut the cartel’s prices and therefore lower consumer 27 prices.” James Cape & Sons Co. v. PCC Const. Co., 453 F.3d 396, 401 (7th Cir. 2006) 28 (emphasis added). The Seventh Circuit went on to note that in the case at bar, the heart -13- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 of the plaintiff’s claim “is that it was never a member of the cartel in the first place;” 2 thus, “[t]he Hammes case is . . . inapplicable here.” Id. 3 Here, Plaintiffs allege in their SAC that they previously were a member of 4 Defendants’ alleged employers’ cartel until they decided to compete on the merits with 5 Defendants—a point that Plaintiffs had not sufficiently clarified in the FAC. See SAC ¶¶ 6 263-73. Plaintiffs explain that after they ceased adhering to the no-poaching restraints, 7 Defendants “subjected Aya to various kinds of retaliatory conduct” including: (1) 8 terminating all subcontractor agreements with Plaintiffs; (2) interfering with Plaintiffs’ 9 dealings with existing and prospective customers; and (3) litigations “objectively baseless 10 claims” against Plaintiffs and four of Plaintiffs’ employees. Id. ¶ 281. Accordingly, in 11 light of Plaintiffs’ allegations that they were a member of Defendants’ alleged cartel, and 12 because retaliation by a cartel member against a member’s attempt to compete is 13 compensable, the Court finds that Plaintiffs have also sufficiently alleged antitrust injury 14 on the basis of retaliatory harm. See Big Bear Lodging Ass’n, 182 F.3d at 1102.7 15 B. 16 Sherman Act Section 1 and Cartwright Act Claims Plaintiffs assert two claims pursuant to Section 1 of the Sherman Act: a per se 17 claim (first cause of action) and a quick-look/rule of reason claim (second cause of 18 action). See SAC. Plaintiffs further assert a Cartwright Act claim pursuant to California 19 Business & Professions Code §§ 16720 et seq. based on the same conduct that allegedly 20 violates Section 1 of the Sherman Act (fourth cause of action).8 See id. 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 Section 1 of the Sherman Act prohibits “[e]very contract, combination in the form                                                 7 In light of the Court’s conclusion that Plaintiffs have sufficiently alleged antitrust injury, the Court need not address Plaintiffs’ third theory of antitrust injury mentioned in Plaintiffs’ opposition to the instant motion. See Doc. No. 31 at 14. 8 “[T]he analysis under California’s antitrust law mirrors the analysis under federal law because the Cartwright Act was modeled after the Sherman Act.” Cnty. of Tuolumne v. Sonora Cmty. Hosp., 236 F.3d 1148, 1160 (9th Cir. 2001). “Thus, if Plaintiffs plead a valid Sherman Act claim, they likewise plead a valid Cartwright Act claim.” In re High-Tech Emp. Antitrust Litig., 856 F. Supp. 2d 1103, 1114 (N.D. Cal. 2012). -14- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several 2 States, or with foreign nations. . . .” 15 U.S.C. § 1; see also Leegin Creative Leather 3 Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 885 (2007) (noting that § 1 of the Sherman Act 4 outlaws unreasonable restraints of trade). To establish liability under § 1, a plaintiff must 5 show: “(1) there was an agreement, conspiracy, or combination between two or more 6 entities; (2) the agreement was an unreasonable restraint of trade . . .; and (3) the restraint 7 affected interstate commerce.” Am. Ad Mgmt. Inc. v. GTE Corp., 92 F.3d 781, 788 (9th 8 Cir. 1996). Defendants focus exclusively on the second element—whether Plaintiffs 9 have sufficiently alleged an unreasonable restraint of trade. 10 “To sufficiently plead an unreasonable restraint, a plaintiff must include allegations 11 showing that the restraint will fail under one of three rules of analysis: the rule of reason, 12 per se, or quick look.” United States v. eBay, Inc., 968 F. Supp. 2d 1030, 1037 (N.D. Cal. 13 2013). First, the rule of reason is the default level of analysis, requiring courts to 14 examine “a variety of factors, including specific information about the relevant business, 15 its condition before and after the restraint was imposed, and the restraint’s history, nature, 16 and effect.” State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3, 10 (1997). “The rule of reason requires 17 the factfinder to decide whether under all the circumstances of the case the agreement 18 imposes an unreasonable restraint on competition.” Los Angeles Mem’l Coliseum 19 Comm’n v. Nat’l Football League, 726 F.2d 1381, 1387 (9th Cir. 1984) (citing Arizona v. 20 Maricopa County Medical Society, 457 U.S. 332, 343 (1982)). The purpose of the 21 analysis is to “distinguish[] between restraints with anticompetitive effect that are 22 harmful to the consumer and restraints stimulating competition that are in the consumer’s 23 best interest.” Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc., 551 U.S. at 886. 24 Second, in limited circumstances, however, such a detailed inquiry under the rule 25 of reason analysis is unnecessary, where the restraint at issue is “so plainly 26 anticompetitive that no elaborate study of the industry is needed to establish their 27 illegality.” Texaco, Inc. v. Dagher, 547 U.S. 1, 5, 8 (2006) (quoting Nat’l Soc. Of Prof’l 28 Eng’rs v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 692 (1978)). A restraint will only be considered -15- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 per se unreasonable if it “always or almost always tend[s] to restrict competition and 2 decrease output” and lacks redeeming value. Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc., 551 3 U.S. at 886 (internal quotations omitted). Such restraints are illegal per se, and once 4 established, do not require any industry analysis otherwise required under the rule of 5 reason. 6 Third, “[f]alling between the rule of reason and per se condemnation, the ‘quick 7 look’ analysis is an abbreviated form of the rule of reason that may be used when ‘an 8 observer with even a rudimentary understanding of economics could conclude that the 9 arrangements in question could have an anticompetitive effect on customers and 10 markets.” eBay, 968 F. Supp. 2d at 1037 (citing Cal. Dental Ass’n v. Fed. Trade 11 Comm’n, 526 U.S. 756, 770 (1999)). 12 Defendants argue that the Court should dismiss Plaintiffs’ claims arising under 13 Section 1 of the Sherman Act because Plaintiffs’ allegations are insufficient to state a 14 claim under all three rules of analysis. See Doc. No. 30-1 at 10, 17. The Court addresses 15 Plaintiffs’ per se claims before turning to Plaintiffs’ quick-look and/or rule of reason 16 claims. 17 1. Per Se Claims 18 Plaintiffs allege that Defendants’ conduct constitutes two separate per se violations 19 of Section 1 of the Sherman Act. SAC ¶¶ 295-97. First, Plaintiffs claim that Defendants’ 20 no-poaching restraints are unlawful per se. See id. ¶ 295. Second, Plaintiffs contend that 21 Defendants have prevailed on at least one rival to accept a unilateral no-hire agreement, 22 which is also unlawful per se. See id. ¶ 296. “By enforcing these restraints, AMN has 23 established and operated a non-reciprocal employers’ cartel in the medical-traveler 24 markets.” Id. ¶ 297. Defendants argue that the no-poaching restraints and alleged 25 employers’ cartel do not fall within the per se category; thus, Plaintiffs’ first cause of 26 action should be dismissed with prejudice. See Doc. No. 30-1 at 10. 27 28 A. No-Poaching Restraints Plaintiffs allege that Defendants require their subcontractor providers and -16- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 software-platform providers “to accept unilateral no-poaching agreements[.]” SAC ¶ 2 123. The no-poaching restraints “forbid the rival providers in perpetuity to initiate job 3 offers or otherwise solicit any of AMN’s designated ‘employees,’ no matter how or 4 where employed, and even when not currently on assignment for AMN.” Id. (emphasis 5 in original). “Although these restraints appear in contracts that memorialize legitimate 6 business collaborations, they are not ‘ancillary’ to the collaborations in question.” Doc. 7 No. 31 at 17. 8 9 Defendants assert that the alleged no-poaching restrictions must be analyzed under the rule of reason standard for three reasons. See Doc. No. 30-1 at 11. First, the no- 10 poaching restraints are part of vertical agreements. See id. Second, “the rule of reason is 11 the standard for testing restrictive covenants ancillary to a legitimate transaction.” Id. 12 Third, “[c]ourts do not apply the per se standard in cases where the economic impact of 13 the practice is not immediately obvious.” Id. at 15. The Court proceeds by: (i) analyzing 14 the character of the subcontractor agreements; and (ii) analyzing the character of the no- 15 poaching restraints. 16 17 i. Characterizing the Subcontractor Agreements Defendants argue that the subcontractor agreements are “collaboration 18 agreements” which are which are part of “essentially vertical arrangements[.]” Id. at 15, 19 11. In their SAC, Plaintiffs argue that the subcontractor agreements are properly 20 characterized as joint ventures.9 See SAC ¶¶ 136-145. As the parties acknowledge, the 21 characterization of the agreements in question impacts which rule of analysis applies. 22 “[T]he Supreme Court has distinguished between agreements made up and down a                                                 23 24 25 26 27 28 9 In opposition to the instant motion, Plaintiffs indicate that they have “always acknowledged that the agreements between AMN and its subcontractors/rival providers can be characterized as vertical arrangements[.]” Doc. No. 31 at 19. However, Plaintiffs explain in their SAC that a joint venture “is any agreement, vertical or horizontal, by which two independent businesses collaborate on a commercial venture in order to develop or furnish products and/or services.” SAC ¶ 136 n.7 (emphasis added). As such, the Court does not read Plaintiffs’ statement as an admission that Plaintiffs believe the agreements in question are in fact, vertical agreements. See also Doc. No. 17 at 2 (“AMN and rival providers participate in legitimate joint-ventures[.]”). -17- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 supply chain, such as between a manufacturer and a retailer (‘vertical agreements’), and 2 agreements made among competitors (‘horizontal agreements’).” In re Musical 3 Instruments & Equip. Antitrust Litig., 798 F.3d 1186, 1191 (9th Cir. 2015). A horizontal 4 agreement or restraint is “[a]n agreement among competitors on the way in which they 5 will compete with one another.” Nat’l Collegiate Athletic Ass’n v. Bd. Of Regents of the 6 Univ. of Okla., 468 U.S. 85, 99 (1984) (hereinafter “NCAA”); see also Bus. Elecs. Corp. 7 v. Sharp Elecs. Corp., 485 U.S. 717, 730 (1988) (“Restraints imposed by agreement 8 between competitors have traditionally been denominated as horizontal restraints”). 9 Unlike horizontal agreements among competitors, “vertical agreements between actual or 10 would-be suppliers and customers are everywhere.” Areeda ¶ 1437a. “[B]y definition 11 vertically related firms exist in a buyer-seller relationship, and agreements are essential to 12 buying and selling.” Areeda ¶ 1902d. A third category, referred to as a joint venture, is 13 “a form of organization in which two or more firms agree to cooperate in producing some 14 input that they would otherwise have produced individually, acquired on the market, or 15 perhaps done without.” Areeda ¶ 2100(a). Importantly, “Section 1 prohibits agreements 16 that unreasonably restrain trade, no matter the configuration they take or the labels we 17 give them.” In re Musical Instruments, 798 F.3d at 1192. 18 Here, taking Plaintiffs’ allegations as true, the Court finds that the subcontractor 19 agreements entered into by Defendants and various rival providers can plausibly be 20 characterized as joint ventures. Notably, Plaintiffs allege that “AMN prevails on its 21 subcontractors (rival providers) to accept its trade restraints because many depend upon it 22 for ‘spillover’ assignments (assignments that AMN refers to another provider when its 23 own travelers are otherwise engaged)[.]” SAC ¶ 119. Unlike agreements made up and 24 down a supply chain between buyers and sellers, Defendants use their no-poaching 25 restraints in their “contracts with virtually all other providers, thereby compromising their 26 ability to compete freely to hire qualified travelers and sell medical-traveler services to 27 hospitals.” Id. ¶ 143. Further, “in a purely vertical contract the parties to the agreement 28 are not competitors.” Areeda ¶ 1902d. Plaintiffs explain that in order to remain in -18- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 business, “[m]any of the rival providers depend on AMN’s spillover assignments and/or 2 software platform assignments and could not survive without them.” SAC ¶ 144 n.8. 3 Accordingly, the Court finds that Plaintiffs have sufficiently alleged that the 4 agreements in question can plausibly be characterized as joint ventures. Therefore, 5 dismissal on the basis that the subcontractor agreements are vertical agreements is 6 improper. 7 ii. Joint Venture Analysis 8 Defendants contend that courts “have always evaluated restraints related to 9 collaborations, joint ventures or transactions under the rule of reason.” Doc. No. 30-1 at 10 13. Plaintiffs, in opposition, claim that legitimate joint venture agreements sometimes 11 include naked10 restraints of trade—i.e., restraints within legitimate joint venture 12 agreements that (1) foreclose some form of direct competition between the parties, but (2) 13 are not reasonably ancillary to their lawful joint-venture. Doc. No. 31 at 17. As 14 explained in Plaintiffs’ opposition to Defendants’ previous motion to dismiss, “a naked 15 restraint, even though included in a legitimate joint-venture agreement, can be 16 condemned as a per se violation of Section 1.” Doc. No. 17 at 7; see also In re ATM Fee 17 Antitrust Litig., 554 F. Supp. 2d 1003, 1012 (N.D. Cal. 2008) (citing NCAA, 468 U.S. at 18 113-15). 19 “Antitrust law doesn’t frown on all joint ventures among competitors—far from it. 20 If a joint venture benefits consumers and doesn’t violate any applicable per se rules, it 21 will often be perfectly legal.” Freeman v. San Diego Ass’n of Realtors, 322 F.3d 1133, 22 1157 (9th Cir. 2003). “When a plaintiff challenges the joint venture itself, the venture 23 must be judged under the rule of reason standard.” In re ATM Fee Antitrust Litig., 554 F. 24 Supp. 2d at 1012 (citing Dagher, 547 U.S. at 6 n.1). However, “[w]hen a plaintiff 25 challenges a provision or practice of the venture as anticompetitive, then per se review 26                                                 27 28 10 “Naked” restraints have “no purpose except stifling of competition.” White Motor v. United States, 372 U.S. 253, 263 (1963). -19- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 2 may be appropriate depending on the circumstances.” Id. Specifically, when a plaintiff challenges a particular restraint of a joint venture that 3 is not economically integrated (i.e., where individual firms function as an economic unit 4 or single entity),11 the analytical framework is as follows: first, courts consider whether 5 the challenged restraint is a core activity or function of the joint venture (if yes, rule of 6 reason applies); second, if not, courts consider whether the restraint is of a type that is 7 potentially subject to per se treatment (if not, rule of reason applies); third, if the restraint 8 is of a type potentially subject to per se treatment, courts consider whether the restraint is 9 necessary or reasonably ancillary to achieving a procompetitive objective of the joint 10 venture (if yes, rule of reason applies; if not, per se rule applies). See id. at 1012-1016; 11 see also Med. Ctr. at Elizabeth Place, LLC v. Premier Health Partners, No. 12-CV-26, 12 2017 WL 3433131, at *14 (S.D. Ohio Aug. 9, 2017) (diagraming analytical framework 13 for joint venture analysis). “Thus, the Supreme Court permits plaintiffs to disaggregate 14 particular conduct from the venture as a whole, and submit that conduct to individual 15 scrutiny.” In re ATM Fee Antitrust Litig., 554 F. Supp. 2d at 1012; see also Areeda ¶ 16 2100(f) (explaining the disaggregation of joint venture provisions). 17 Here, Plaintiffs challenge the no-poaching provisions of the subcontractor 18 agreements—not the joint ventures themselves. In fact, Plaintiffs refer to the joint 19 ventures as “legitimate business collaborations.” Doc. No. 31 at 17. As such, Plaintiffs 20 seek to disaggregate specific conduct from the ventures as a whole, and submit that 21 conduct to scrutiny by the Court. Contrary to Defendants’ contention, “[t]he Court 22 cannot therefore hold that because the [no-poaching restraints were] established through a 23 joint venture, ergo rule of reason applies.” In re ATM Fee Antitrust Litig., 554 F. Supp. 24 2d at 1012. “Rather, the Court must go further, and inquire into the nature of the venture 25 and the role of the restraint.” Id. 26 ///                                                 27 28 11 The parties do not argue that Defendants and their rivals function as a unit or single entity. -20- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 2 a. Core Function of Joint Ventures The Supreme Court has indicated that the per se standard is not appropriate if a 3 plaintiff challenges “the core activity of the joint venture itself[.]” Dagher, 547 U.S. at 7. 4 In Dagher, the plaintiffs challenged two oil companies’ agreement to set a unified price 5 for their gasoline, a practice identified as the venture’s core activity. See id. at 6-7. Thus, 6 the Supreme Court applied the rule of reason analysis. See id. 7 Here, though not specifically addressed by either party, Plaintiffs do not challenge 8 the core function of the joint ventures. As noted above, Plaintiffs concede that the 9 various agreements are “legitimate” and ensure that the staffing needs of hospitals are 10 met. Doc. No. 31 at 17. Plaintiffs instead challenge the no-poaching restraints, included 11 in these legitimate agreements, as “unlawful restraints of competition between rival 12 employers[.]” Id. As such, the Court proceeds to analyze the character of the no- 13 poaching restraints. 14 b. Characterizing the No-Poaching Restraints 15 Plaintiffs allege that the no-poaching restraints are horizontal restraints of trade 16 because they permanently eliminate one kind of direct rivalry between competitors. See 17 Doc. No. 31 at 19. 18 Horizontal market allocation agreements typically constitute a per se violation of 19 Section 1. See United States v. Topco Assocs., 405 U.S. 596, 608 (1972); United States v. 20 Brown, 936 F.2d 1042, 1044-45 (9th Cir. 2001) (“A market allocation agreement between 21 two companies at the same market level is a classic per se antitrust violation.”). “An 22 agreement among employers that they will not compete against each other for the 23 services of a particular employee or prospective employee is, in fact, a service division 24 agreement, analogous to a product division agreement.” Areeda ¶ 2013b. “Such 25 arrangements must be distinguished from noncompetition agreements that prevent an 26 employee from seeking employment from a rival for a given period after the employee’s 27 present employment relationship is terminated. These arrangements are purely vertical, 28 for they involve a single employer’s agreement with one or more employees.” Id. -21- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 Here, the Court finds that Plaintiffs’ allegations concerning the no-poaching 2 restraints are sufficient to allege that the restraints are of a type that are subject to per se 3 treatment. See Med. Ctr. at Elizabeth Place, LLC, 2017 WL 3433131, at *14. For 4 example, Plaintiffs allege that Defendants collaborate with smaller, rival providers of 5 medical travelers to deliver their services, which are governed by the subcontractor 6 agreements. SAC ¶ 123. Although the subcontractor agreements are “legitimate,” 7 Plaintiffs claim that the non-poaching restraints are not reasonably ancillary to the 8 agreements in which they appear. Id. ¶ 133. The no-poaching restraints “permanently 9 prevent nearly all of AMN’s direct competitors in the United States from soliciting any of 10 its numerous employees for any purpose.” Id. ¶ 134. These restraints are non-reciprocal; 11 thus, Defendants are immune from these indefinite restraints. See id. Plaintiffs explain 12 that Defendants’ no-poaching restraints result in an agreement among rivals about how 13 they will compete for employees. 14 Accordingly, in disaggregating the no-poaching restraints from the joint ventures, 15 the Court finds that Plaintiffs’ allegations, taken as true, are sufficient to allege a type of 16 restraint subject to per se treatment. See eBay, 968 F. Supp. 2d at 1039. Thus, dismissal 17 on this basis is inappropriate. 18 19 c. Whether the No-Poaching Restraints are Reasonably Ancillary to a Procompetitive Business Purpose 20 Defendants contend the no-poaching restraints are ancillary to legitimate business 21 transactions, and thus must be analyzed under the rule of reason standard. See Doc. No. 22 30-1 at 11. In opposition, Plaintiffs assert that the restraints, “as worded and enforced, 23 vastly exceed any possible scope or purpose of the collaborations in question and exist to 24 prevent AMN’s rivals from ever approaching anyone in its pool, even after the 25 collaborations in question have ended.” Doc. No. 31 at 19. Moreover, in their SAC, 26 Plaintiffs provide the following hypothetical of Defendants’ no-poaching restraints: 27 28 Suppose a rival provider agrees one time to act as AMN’s subcontractor. To -22- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 do so, it must sign one of AMN’s standard subcontractor agreements, which invariably include AMN’s unilateral No-Poaching Restraint. Suppose AMN gives this rival only one assignment, say in 2010, and the rival performs it by sending a single traveler to a remote hospital in the Kansas prairie. Shortly afterwards, AMN terminates the agreement, or perhaps the rival does so. The rival thereafter remains expressly forbidden to initiate at any time in the future an employment discussion for any purpose with any of AMN’s 8000 travelers or 2500 recruiters and other professionals, who are scattered across the United States. AMN, in contrast, labors under no reciprocal restraint. 8 9 SAC ¶ 132. 10 The Court’s determination that Plaintiffs have sufficiently alleged that the no- 11 poaching restraints, considered in isolation, are of a type subject to per se treatment “does 12 not in and of itself indicate that per se treatment is imminent.” eBay, 968 F. Supp. 2d at 13 1039. In order to make a rule determination, the Court must determine whether no- 14 poaching restraints are ancillary to a procompetitive business purpose. See id. (citing 15 Broad. Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broad. Sys., Inc., 441 U.S. 1, 19-22 (1979)); see also 16 Areeda ¶ 2013a (explaining that if agreements among employers not to compete for 17 employees “are ‘naked’ and not immunized, they are illegal per se. . . .”). “[A] 18 challenged restraint must have a reasonable procompetitive justification, related to the 19 efficiency-enhancing purposes of the joint venture[.]” Major League Baseball Props., 20 Inc. v. Salvino, Inc., 542 F.3d 290, 339 (2d Cir. 2008) (Sotomayor, J., concurring in the 21 judgment). “If none exists, the challenged restraint must be evaluated on its own and 22 may be per se illegal even if the remainder of the joint venture is entirely lawful.” Id. 23 Additionally, “[t]o be ancillary, and hence exempt from the per se rule, an 24 agreement eliminating competition must be subordinate and collateral to a separate, 25 legitimate transaction,” i.e., the restraint “serves to make the main transaction more 26 effective in accomplishing its purpose.” Rothery Storage & Van Co. v. Atlas Van Lines, 27 Inc., 792 F.2d 210, 224 (D.C. Cir. 1986). “If [the restraint] is so broad that part of the 28 restraint suppresses competition without creating efficiency, the restraint is, to that extent, -23- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 not ancillary.” Id. As the Third Circuit has indicated, 2 3 4 5 6 [t]he quintessential example of an ancillary restraint is a restrictive agreement that is an integral part of a joint venture. An agreement by two competing manufacturers to price a product identically, for instance, would be ancillary if manufacture of the product were a collaborative effort between the two firms and the pricing agreement could reasonably be viewed as a necessary condition of the joint venture, which increased output. 7 8 In re Ins. Brokerage Antitrust Litig., 618 F.3d 300, 345 (3d Cir. 2010); see also Freeman, 9 322 F.3d at 1151. The doctrine of ancillary restraints “seeks to distinguish between those 10 restraints that are intended to promote the efficiencies of a joint venture and those that are 11 simply unrelated.” Salvino, Inc., 542 F.3d at 338-39.12 12 Moreover, the Court is mindful that the joint guidelines announced by the 13 Department of Justice, Antitrust Division and the Federal Trade Commission in October 14 2016, make clear that an agreement made between rival employers not to solicit one 15 another’s employees will be prosecuted as a criminal violation of Section 1 if it “is 16 separate from or not reasonably necessary to a larger legitimate collaboration between the 17 employers.” Joint Guidelines of the Department of Justice, Antitrust Division and the 18 Federal Trade Commission (October 2016). 19 20 Plaintiffs urge the Court to follow the district court’s ruling in eBay. There, the government alleged that eBay and Intuit entered into a no-solicitation/no-hire agreement 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28                                                 12 The Court notes that Defendants assert that Plaintiffs have “no response to NCAA . . ., where the Supreme Court applied the rule of reason, even though the challenged provision restrained the ability of the members to compete on both price and output and was not ‘necessary’ to market the product.” Doc. No. 32 at 7. As explained by the court in In re ATM Fee Antitrust Litig., however, “the Ninth Circuit has since limited the reach of the NCAA decision” in Freeman. 554 F. Supp. 2d at 1015. The Ninth Circuit has imposed “an additional burden on defendants, who must now prove not only that their venture requires horizontal restraints, but also that the particular restraint challenged is ancillary to the venture’s legitimate aspects.” Id.; see also Freeman, 322 F.3d at 1157. For the reasons discussed below, the Court is unable to determine at this stage of the proceedings whether the challenged restraints are ancillary to the venture’s legitimate aspects. -24- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 with each other. See 968 F. Supp. 2d at 1038. The alleged agreement arose out of 2 conversations between eBay executives and Scott Cook, founder of Intuit, who also 3 served on eBay’s board. See id. at 1033-34. The court found that the government had 4 sufficiently alleged a horizontal market allocation agreement. Id. at 1039. The 5 defendants argued that the agreement, though horizontal, was ancillary to a legitimate 6 procompetitive business purpose (i.e., Mr. Cook’s service on eBay’s board), and 7 therefore not amenable to per se treatment. Id. The government argued the agreement 8 constituted a naked restraint of trade. Id. The court noted that just because the 9 government labeled the agreement as “naked” did not make it so; but by the same token, 10 the defendants’ claim that the agreement is ancillary similarly does not make it so. Id. 11 The court declined to determine at the pleading stage whether to apply the per se or rule 12 of reason analysis. The court stated, “[t]hough the parties supply substantial legal 13 argument to support their respective positions, they do so without the benefit of 14 discovery, and thus without sufficient factual evidence to support their contentions.” Id. 15 at 1039-40. Thus, taking the plaintiff’s allegations as true, the court could not determine 16 as a matter of law that per se treatment would be inappropriate. Id. 17 Here, the Court finds the district court’s reasoning in eBay to be persuasive. 18 Defendants assert that the alleged agreement in eBay did not involve “any form or joint 19 venture, sub-contract or collaboration.” Doc. No. 32 at 7. While the alleged agreement 20 did not involve a joint venture, the defendants in eBay did claim that the challenged 21 restraint was ancillary to procompetitive business purposes. See 968 F. Supp. 2d at 1039. 22 Further, a plaintiff challenging a provision or practice of a joint venture can disaggregate 23 such conduct and challenge it in isolation. See In re ATM Litig., 554 F. Supp. 2d at 1012. 24 In doing so, courts “must consider the reasonably anticipated impact of the particular 25 agreement under scrutiny—measured, of course, against the environment created by the 26 joint venture. If the reasonably intended impact of an agreement is to reduce market 27 output, then that agreement is naked notwithstanding its association with other productive 28 joint activity.” Areeda ¶ 1908b. -25- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 Defendants further argue that Plaintiffs essentially admit “that this type of restraint 2 would be ancillary (and judged by the rule of reason) if it were only narrower in scope 3 and duration.” Doc. No. 30-1 at 13 (emphasis in original). Defendants are unable “to 4 find even a single case holding that a non-solicitation covenant included in a subcontract 5 or joint venture arrangement (of any scope of duration) is per se unlawful.” Id. 6 (emphasis in original). However, courts have addressed the scope of restraints within the 7 context of a larger agreement. In Hanger v. Berkley Group, Inc., the district court 8 distinguished In re High-Tech Emp. Antitrust Litig., 856 F. Supp. 2d 1103 (N.D. Cal. 9 2012), and eBay. No. 13-CV-113, 2015 WL 3439255, at *7 (W.D. Va. May 28, 2015). 10 The Hanger court noted that the challenged restraint at issue is “one piece of a global 11 settlement agreement” (“GSA”), and “[i]t is clear from the terms of the GSA and the 12 context in which it arose that [the challenged restraint] exists to keep the parties from 13 becoming embroiled in future lawsuits[.]” Id. The court examined the language of the 14 challenged restraint, which unlike In re High-Tech Emp. Antitrust Litig. and eBay, “did 15 not contain a blanket, no cold calling or no solicitation agreement.” Id. Instead, the 16 language reflected an agreement to “honor each other’s non-competition, non-solicitation 17 and confidentiality agreements of which they have actual knowledge that are contained in 18 written agreements that have not been held unenforceable by a court of competent 19 jurisdiction as to the particular employee.” Id. The court made a point to note that 20 “because the restrictive covenants in the Berkley Group employment contracts are 21 narrowly drawn in terms of substantive scope, time and geography, the alleged restraint 22 posed by the GSA is correspondingly narrow.” Id. (emphasis added). 23 Unlike Hanger, Plaintiffs allege that the no-poaching restraints last in perpetuity, 24 thereby surviving termination of the joint venture agreements. SAC ¶ 123. The restraints 25 bar rivals forever from soliciting any of Defendants’ employees—including recruiters, 26 corporate employees, and medical travelers, despite the fact that the purpose of these 27 subcontractor agreements is for rival providers to send their medical travelers to 28 Defendants’ customers. See id. ¶¶ 124-28. Lastly, Plaintiffs allege that the no-poaching -26- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 restraints apply to all of Defendants’ “designated ‘employees,’ no matter how or where 2 employed, and even when not currently on assignment for AMN[,]” while Defendants are 3 not bound by the same restraint. Id. ¶ 123 (emphasis added). 4 In disaggregating the alleged no-poaching restraints here, the Court is unable to 5 determine with certainty whether the restraints are ancillary to procompetitive business 6 purposes, or “so broad that part of the restraint suppresses competition without creating 7 efficiency.” Rothery Storage & Van Co., 792 F.2d at 224; see also Blackburn v. 8 Sweeney, 53 F.3d 825, 828-29 (7th Cir. 1995) (noting that the defendants’ argument that 9 the advertising agreement is “a legitimate covenant not to compete, ancillary to the 10 dissolution of the partnership, is further undermined by the Agreement’s infinite duration. 11 . . . There is no time limit attached to the advertising restrictions. . . . The restriction on 12 advertising is thus naked, not ancillary, and per se illegal to boot.”); United States v. 13 Addyston Pipe & Steel Co., 85 F. 271, 282 (6th Cir. 1898), modified and aff’d, 175 U.S. 14 211 (1899) (“[I]f the restraint exceeds the necessity presented by the main purpose of the 15 contract, it is void . . . .”). As a result, the Court is unable to determine at this stage in the 16 litigation “the level of analysis to apply.” eBay, 968 F. Supp. 2d at 1040. “The court 17 must instead make that determination based on factual evidence relating to the 18 agreement’s formation and character.” Id. The parties do not have the benefit of 19 discovery or factual evidence to support their contentions. The decision about which rule 20 to apply “is more appropriate on a motion for summary judgment.” In re High-Tech 21 Emp. Antitrust Litig., 856 F. Supp. 2d at 1122; see also Areeda ¶ 305e (“Often, however, 22 the decision about which rule is to be employed will await facts that are developed only 23 in discovery.”) (emphasis added). 24 Accordingly, taking Plaintiffs’ allegations as true, the Court finds that Plaintiffs 25 have sufficiently pleaded the existence of a restraint on trade of a type that is subject to 26 per se treatment. See eBay, 968 F. Supp. 2d at 1040. Thus, the Court is unable to 27 determine as a matter of law that per se treatment will be inappropriate with respect to the 28 no-poaching restraints in the context of the joint ventures. See id. -27- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 B. No-Hire Agreement & Employers’ Cartel 2 Plaintiffs further allege that Defendants’ unilateral no-hire agreement with Host is 3 unlawful per se under Section 1 of the Sherman Act. See SAC ¶ 296. Plaintiffs believe 4 “Host acquiesced in AMN’s demand because it required spillover work from AMN in 5 order to develop its business and remain commercially viable.” Id. ¶ 166. Plaintiffs 6 claim that Defendants also “proposed various no-hire agreements to Aya at different 7 times from 2014 to 2016, but Aya rejected each proposal.” Id. ¶ 146. Plaintiffs allege 8 that in order to “retaliate” against them for refusing the no-hire offers and breaching the 9 no-poaching restraints, Defendants filed “objectively baseless claims” against Plaintiffs 10 in state court, terminated their subcontractor agreements with Aya, and temporarily 11 withdrew Plaintiffs’ access to “certain accounts on one of [Defendants’] software 12 platforms.” Id. ¶ 155. Defendants then offered to “drop” their lawsuit against Plaintiffs 13 “if in exchange Aya would agree to . . . enforce . . . an agreement not to hire specified 14 employees for a five-year term.” Id. ¶ 156. Plaintiffs believe that Defendants have 15 proposed “and possibly concluded no-hire agreements with other providers.” Id. By 16 enforcing their no-poaching restraints and no-hire agreement, Defendants have 17 “established and operated a non-reciprocal employers’ cartel in the medical-traveler 18 markets.” Id. ¶¶ 297. 19 Defendants assert that Plaintiffs fail to “identify what the unidentified members of 20 the ‘cartel’ agreed to and when and how they came to such an agreement, which types of 21 employees supposedly were involved, or any other factual information.” Doc. No. 30-1 22 at 16. A close reading of the SAC reveals that Plaintiffs are not relying on the formation 23 of an employers’ cartel as the basis for their per se claims. Rather, Plaintiffs assert that 24 the no-poaching restraints and no-hire agreement are each independently unlawful per se 25 under Section 1. See SAC ¶¶ 296-97. Thus, Plaintiffs’ failure to identify the members of 26 27 28 -28- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 this alleged cartel is irrelevant to the inquiry at bar.13 The questions before the Court are 2 similar to those raised in the previous section—whether the alleged no-hire agreement is 3 the type of restraint potentially subject to per se treatment, and whether the no-hire 4 agreement is plausibly necessary or ancillary to achieving a procompetitive business 5 purpose. See In re ATM Fee Antitrust Litig., 554 F. Supp. 2d at 1014. Aside from 6 summarily stating Plaintiffs’ allegations describe “just a two-party subcontract agreement 7 between AMN and Host Healthcare,” Defendants do not address either question. Doc. 8 No. 30-1 at 16. 9 Here, similar to no-poaching restraints, the Court finds that Plaintiffs’ allegations 10 concerning the no-hire agreement with Host, and proposed no-hire agreements with 11 Plaintiffs, are sufficient to allege that the restraints are of a type that are subject to per se 12 treatment. See eBay, 968 F. Supp. 2d at 1039 (finding that the government’s allegations 13 regarding eBay’s no-solicitation/no-hire agreement are sufficient to state a horizontal 14 market allocation agreement); see also Areeda ¶ 2013b (“An agreement among 15 employers that they will not compete against each other for the services of a particular 16 employee or prospective employee is, in fact, a service division agreement, analogous to 17 a product division agreement.”). Moreover, Plaintiffs assert that Defendants’ “no-hire 18 agreements are not reasonably ancillary to any collaboration to which they might refer. 19 Rather, they are naked restraints of trade that are unlawful per se under Section 1.” Id. ¶ 20 147. However, just because Plaintiffs label the restraints as “naked” does “not make it 21 so.” eBay, 968 F. Supp. 2d 1030 at 1039. For the reasons set forth in the previous 22 section, the Court is unable to determine with certainty, whether the no-hire restraints are 23 ancillary to procompetitive business purposes in the context of the joint ventures. See 24                                                 25 26 27 28 13 The Court notes that in the FAC, Plaintiffs specifically alleged that the “employers’ cartel constitutes an ongoing, per se violation of Section 1[.]” FAC ¶ 239. This allegation differs from the SAC, wherein Plaintiffs claim that by enforcing the no-poaching restraints and no-hire agreement, Defendants have “established and operated a non-reciprocal employers’ cartel in the medical-traveler markets.” SAC ¶ 297. Plaintiffs do not allege in the SAC, unlike in the FAC, that the alleged employers’ cartel in and of itself constitutes a per se violation of Section 1. -29- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 2 Rothery Storage & Van Co., 792 F.2d at 224. Accordingly, taking Plaintiffs’ allegations as true, the Court finds that Plaintiffs 3 have sufficiently pleaded the existence of a restraint on trade of a type that is subject to 4 per se treatment. Thus, the Court is unable to determine as a matter of law that per se 5 treatment will be inappropriate with respect to the no-hire restraints. See eBay, 968 F. 6 Supp. 2d at 1040. 7 2. Quick-Look/Rule of Reason Claim 8 In the alternative, Plaintiffs assert that “[i]f for any reason AMN’s No-Poaching 9 Restraints” and no-hire restraints “are not unlawful per se under Section 1, they 10 nevertheless unreasonably restrain trade and violate Section 1 under the quick-look 11 standard and/or the rule-of-reason standard.” SAC ¶¶ 316, 317. Additionally, all of 12 Defendants’ agreements, including the software platform agreements, employee 13 restraints, and exclusive dealing agreements, “unreasonably restrain trade in the medical- 14 traveler markets. Cumulatively, they have permitted AMN to perpetuate and enlarge its 15 market power, which it has exercised by charging supracompetitive prices and imposing 16 onerous trade restraints on all market participants in the medical-traveler markets.” Id. ¶ 17 318. Defendants assert any quick-look claim fails for the same reasons Plaintiffs’ per se 18 claim fails. See Doc. No. 30-1 at 17 n.20. Defendants further contend that a rule-of- 19 reason claim fails because Plaintiffs fail to properly define the relevant markets and plead 20 facts showing harm to competition. See id. at 18-19. 21 As noted above, courts use the quick-look analysis when “an observer with even a 22 rudimentary understanding of economics could conclude that the arrangements in 23 question could have an anticompetitive effect on customers and markets.” Cal Dental 24 Ass’n, 526 U.S. at 770. Moreover, “[w]here a practice has obvious anticompetitive 25 effects . . . there is no need to prove that the defendant possesses market power. Rather, 26 the court is justified in proceeding directly to the question of whether the procompetitive 27 justifications advanced for the restraints outweigh the anticompetitive effects under a 28 ‘quick look’ rule of reason.” Law v. Nat’l Collegiate Athletic Ass’n, 134 F.3d 1010, 1020 -30- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 (10th Cir. 1998). 2 Under the “rule of reason” analysis, the factfinder “must analyze the anti- 3 competitive effects along with any pro-competitive effects to determine whether the 4 practice is unreasonable on balance.” Bhan, 929 F.2d at 1413. This analysis employs 5 shifting burdens of proof. First, a plaintiff “must show that the activity is the type that 6 restrains trade and that the restraint is likely to be of significant magnitude. Ordinarily, a 7 plaintiff to do this must delineate a relevant market and show that the defendant plays 8 enough of a role in that market to impair competition significantly.” Id. (internal 9 citations omitted). Second, if the plaintiff makes the above showing, the burden shifts to 10 the defendant to justify the restraint by showing that the restraint furthers a legitimate 11 commercial purpose. See id. Third, the plaintiff “must then try to show that any 12 legitimate objectives can be achieved in a substantially less restrictive manner.” Id. 13 “Finally, the court must weigh the harms and benefits to determine if the behavior is 14 unreasonable on balance.” Id. 15 Here, Defendants’ arguments rest on the assumption that the Court should apply a 16 rule of reason analysis. However, as discussed in the previous section, the Court need not 17 decide which standard applies at this time. “Indeed, that decision is more appropriate on 18 a motion for summary judgment.” In re High-Tech Emp. Antitrust Litig., 856 F. Supp. 2d 19 at 1122. Plaintiffs have sufficiently pleaded the existence of restraints on trade of types 20 that are subject to per se treatment. As such, Plaintiffs have also sufficiently pleaded “the 21 existence of the type of restraint that may fall under the ambit of the quick look” and 22 rule-of-reason standards. eBay, 968 F. Supp. 2d at 1040. “[T]he Court need not engage 23 in a market analysis until the Court decides whether to apply a per se or rule of reason 24 analysis.” In re High-Tech Emp. Antitrust Litig., 856 F. Supp. 2d at 1122. Because the 25 Court cannot “at this early stage make a determination as to which rule will apply,” the 26 Court cannot find as a matter of law that the quick-look and/or rule of reason standards 27 will not apply to the challenged restraints in this case. eBay, 968 F. Supp. 2d at 1040. 28 /// -31- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 3. Summary 2 In sum, taking Plaintiffs’ allegations as true, which the Court must do at this stage 3 of the proceedings, the Court finds that Plaintiffs have sufficiently pleaded the existence 4 of restraints on trade of types that are subject to per se treatment. See id. The Court, 5 however, “cannot determine with certainty the nature of the restraint[s], and by extension, 6 the level of analysis to apply.” Id. Accordingly, the Court DENIES Defendants’ motion 7 to dismiss Plaintiffs’ first, second, and fourth causes of action. 8 C. 9 Sherman Act Section 2 Claim In their third cause of action, Plaintiffs assert an attempted monopolization claim 10 under Section 2 of the Sherman Act. Plaintiffs allege that through Defendants’ 11 anticompetitive practices, Defendants “intended to acquire monopoly power in the 12 medical-traveler markets.” SAC ¶ 330. 13 “To establish a Sherman Act § 214 violation for attempted monopolization, a 14 private plaintiff seeking damages must demonstrate four elements: (1) specific intent to 15 control prices or destroy competition; (2) predatory or anticompetitive conduct directed at 16 accomplishing that purpose; (3) a dangerous probability of achieving ‘monopoly power’; 17 and (4) causal antitrust injury.” Rebel Oil Co., 51 F.3d at 1432-33 (citing McGlinchy v. 18 Shell Chem. Co., 845 F.2d 802, 811 (9th Cir. 1988)). 19 Defendants argue the Court should dismiss Plaintiffs’ Section 2 claim for three 20 reasons: (1) Plaintiffs fail to plead well-defined relevant markets; (2) Plaintiffs fail to 21 allege exclusionary conduct; and (3) Plaintiffs fail to plead facts showing a dangerous 22 probability that Defendants will succeed in becoming a monopoly. See Doc. No. 30-1 at 23 21-23. Because the Court has already concluded that Plaintiffs have sufficiently alleged 24 exclusionary conduct with respect to antitrust standing, the Court proceeds to address 25 26 27 28                                                 14 Section 2 of the Sherman Act provides, “[e]very person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire with any person or persons, to monopolize ... trade shall be guilty” of an antitrust violation. 15 U.S.C. § 2. -32- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 Defendants’ remaining arguments regarding the relevant markets and probability of 2 success in becoming a monopoly. 3 1. Well-Defined Relevant Markets 4 Plaintiffs assert that they have properly pled the markets, explaining why there is 5 no “reasonably interchangeable substitute” for medical-traveler services and “why these 6 services are sold in both a national market and various regional submarkets.” Doc. No. 7 31 at 21. Defendants argue that Plaintiffs fail to sufficiently define the relevant service 8 and geographic markets. See Doc. No. 30-1 at 18. The Court addresses the relevant 9 markets in turn. 10 11 A. Service Market With respect to the service market, Defendants contend that “medical-traveler 12 services” is “vague on its face” and ambiguous. Doc. No. 30-1 at 18. “[C]ircumstantial 13 evidence of market power requires that the plaintiff, at the threshold, define the relevant 14 market.” Rebel Oil Co., 51 F.3d at 1434. “[A] ‘market’ is the group of sellers or 15 producers who have the ‘actual or potential ability to deprive each other of significant 16 levels of business.’” Id. (quoting Thurman Indus., Inc. v. Pay ‘N Pak Stores, Inc., 875 17 F.2d 1369, 1374 (9th Cir. 1989)). “The goods and services that sellers or producers offer 18 provide the best indicia of who competes in the same market. Thus, a product market is 19 typically defined to include the pool of goods or services that qualify as economic 20 substitutes because they enjoy reasonable interchangeability and use of cross-elasticity of 21 demand.” Thurman Indus., Inc., 875 F.2d at 1374. “Market definition is crucial. 22 Without a definition of the relevant market, it is impossible to determine market share.” 23 Rebel Oil Co., 51 F.3d at 1434. 24 Here, the Court finds that Plaintiffs have sufficiently defined the relevant service 25 market as “[t]he provision of travelers.” SAC ¶ 53. For example, Plaintiffs expressly 26 allege that “[t]ravelers are licensed nurses and medical technicians who travel from place 27 to place in order to perform temporary assignments at understaffed hospitals.” Id. ¶ 31. 28 The travelers work for staffing companies, such as AMN and Aya, “which make all -33- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 necessary arrangements for them, and which charge fees to the hospitals for their 2 services.” Id. The “medical-traveler services constitute a relevant service market: when 3 hospitals require these services, there is no other service that they can use instead, since 4 by definition they use the services of travelers only when their staffing needs cannot be 5 met by their own employees or locally available temporary employees.” Id. ¶ 51. “There 6 is no other service, nor any other kind of employee that can fulfill the hospitals’ 7 requirement for travelers under such circumstances.” Id. 8 9 Further, unlike Queen City Pizza, Inc. v. Domino’s Pizza, Inc., a case relied upon by Defendants, where the Third Circuit determined that “the dough, tomato sauce, and 10 paper cups . . . used by Domino’s stores are interchangeable with dough, sauce and cups 11 available from other suppliers and used by other pizza companies” (124 F.3d 430, 438 12 (3d Cir. 1997)), Plaintiffs assert that there is “no cross-elasticity of demand for medical- 13 traveler services and any other service” (SAC ¶ 52). “If a hypothetical monopolist were 14 to make all sales of medical-traveler services, it could raise its prices by a statistically 15 significant amount for a non-transitory period without losing so many sales as to make 16 the price-increase unprofitable[.]” SAC ¶ 52. “Hospitals would find themselves largely 17 constrained to submit to the monopolist’s price increase and to continue employing 18 travelers at the higher prices for want of any suitable alternative.” Id. Such allegations 19 are sufficient at this stage of the proceedings. 20 Defendants also claim there is “ambiguity throughout the SAC as to whether the 21 purported service market for medical services provided by the ‘medical travelers’ 22 includes services provided by those who recruit ‘medical travelers.’” Doc. No. 30-1 at 23 18. The Court disagrees. While Plaintiffs explain that providers of travelers “employ 24 professional recruiters” whose work “is indispensable to medical-traveler providers[,]” 25 Plaintiffs clearly articulate that the relevant service market consists of the sale of 26 medical-traveler services to understaffed hospitals. SAC ¶¶ 49, 51-53. 27 Accordingly, because the relevant market includes the groups of sellers “who have 28 actual or potential ability to deprive each other of significant levels of business[,]” and in -34- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 viewing the allegations in the light most favorable to Plaintiffs, the Court finds that 2 Plaintiffs have sufficiently defined the relevant service market. Thurman Indus., Inc., 3 875 F.2d at 1374; see also Image Technical Servs., Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 125 F.3d 4 1195, 1203 (9th Cir. 1997) (“Ultimately what constitutes a relevant market is a factual 5 determination for the jury.”). 6 7 B. Geographic Markets Regarding the relevant geographic markets, Defendants assert Plaintiffs’ 8 submarket allegations are vague and insufficient to support a claim. See Doc. No. 30-1 at 9 19. “In defining the relevant market, a court must look at the ‘full range of selling 10 opportunities reasonably open to [competitors], namely all the product and geographic 11 sales they may readily compete for.’” Stewart v. Gogo, Inc., No. 12-cv-5164 EMC, 2013 12 WL 1501484, at *4 (N.D. Cal. Apr. 10, 2013) (quoting Omega Envtl., Inc. v. Gilbarco, 13 Inc., 127 F.3d 1157, 1162 (9th Cir. 1997)). The Supreme Court has indicated that 14 “within this broad market, well-defined submarkets may exist which, in themselves, 15 constitute product markets for antitrust purposes.” Brown Shoe Co. v. U.S., 370 U.S. 16 294, 325 (1962). “The boundaries of such a submarket may be determined by examining 17 such practical indicia as industry or public recognition of the submarket as a separate 18 economic entity, the product’s peculiar characteristics and uses, unique production 19 facilities, distinct customers, distinct prices, sensitivity to price changes, and specialized 20 vendors.” Id.15 21 Here, Plaintiffs allege that the “provision of travelers is a service that is provided in 22 a nationwide market across the United States and in various regional submarkets.” SAC 23 ¶ 58. Defendants take issue with only the alleged regional submarkets. Plaintiffs explain 24 that some providers, including AMN and Aya, dispatch travelers to perform assignments 25                                                 26 27 28 15 “Although Brown Shoe involved the challenge of a merger under Section 7 of the Clayton Act, courts have recognized that its submarket analysis is equally applicable to claims brought under the Sherman Act.” In re Live Concert Antitrust Litig., 863 F. Supp. 2d 966, 984-85 (C.D. Cal. 2012) (citing Thurman Indus., Inc., 875 F.2d at 1375 n.1). -35- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 at hospitals across the country. Id. ¶ 59. Additionally, there are “various submarkets (or 2 smaller markets) for medical-traveler services[.]” Id. ¶ 60. Contrary to Defendants’ 3 argument that Plaintiffs’ allegations are “conclusory” or “not sufficiently definite” (Doc. 4 No. 30-1 at 19), Plaintiffs assert that each submarket “has distinctive regulatory 5 requirements imposed by state, county and/or municipal authorities” (SAC ¶ 60(1)). 6 “Many travelers are qualified to render services only in certain regions” and “the pool of 7 available travelers largely varies from region to region.” SAC ¶ 60(2). Moreover, in 8 each regional submarket, “hospitals pay distinct prices for traveler services, have distinct 9 staffing requirements, and must address unique seasonal and fluctuating circumstances.” 10 Id. ¶ 60(3). Further, “[i]t is within the different regional submarkets that providers 11 compete with one another to furnish travelers to hospitals.” Id. ¶ 64. The Court finds 12 that Plaintiffs have sufficiently alleged how the provision of services can vary in the 13 numerous submarkets due to state, county and/or municipal regulatory requirements, 14 individual preferences, distinct prices, and the unique circumstances of hospitals across 15 the country. See DocMagic, Inc. v. Ellie Mae, Inc., 745 F. Supp. 2d 1119, 1135 (N.D. 16 Cal. 2010) (noting that “there is no contradiction between the existence of a national . . . 17 market and the simultaneous existence of local . . . markets that compete only at the 18 regional level.”). 19 Accordingly, the Court finds that taking Plaintiffs’ allegations as true, Plaintiffs 20 have sufficiently defined the relevant geographic markets: a national market for the 21 provision of travelers, as well as various regional submarkets for the provision of these 22 services. See Newcal Indus., Inc. v. Ikon Office Solution, 513 F.3d 1038, 1051 (9th Cir. 23 2008) (finding that the plaintiff’s complaint “sufficiently alleges that IKON customers 24 constitute a submarket according to all of those practical indicia” outlined by the 25 Supreme Court in Brown Shoe). 26 27 28 2. Dangerous Probability of Success Plaintiffs claim “there exists a dangerous probability that [Defendants] will succeed in the effort unless there is an antitrust intervention.” SAC ¶ 330. -36- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 “To establish a dangerous probability of success, plaintiffs must . . . (1) [ ] define 2 the relevant market and (2) [ ] demonstrate that substantial barriers to entry protect that 3 market.” United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34, 81 (D.C. Cir. 2001); see also 4 Spectrum Sports, Inc. v. McQuillan, 506 U.S. 447, 455-56 (1993) (indicating that a 5 court’s evaluation of an attempted monopolization claim must include a definition of the 6 relevant market and the defendant’s market share). “The determination whether a 7 dangerous probability of success exists is a particularly fact-intensive inquiry.” Microsoft 8 Corp., 253 F.3d at 80. The Sherman Act does not specify which activities constitute an 9 attempted monopolization; thus, “the court ‘must examine the facts of each case, mindful 10 that the determination of what constitutes an attempt, as Justice Holmes explained, ‘is a 11 question of proximity and degree.’” Id. (quoting United States v. Am. Airlines, Inc., 743 12 F.2d 1114, 1118 (5th Cir.1984); Swift & Co. v. United States, 196 U.S. 375, 402 (1905)). 13 Plaintiffs allege Defendants are “the dominant provider of the relevant service (the 14 provision of travelers).” SAC ¶ 331. Defendants make or control “at least 37% of all 15 sales” nationally, and in some regional submarkets, Defendants make or control “at least 16 50% of all sales.” Id. ¶¶ 67-68. Defendants contend that Plaintiffs allegations 17 concerning market power and barriers to entry are insufficient to state a claim for 18 attempted monopolization. See Doc. No. 30-1 at 23. The Court addresses Defendants’ 19 arguments in turn. 20 21 A. Market Power Defendants first argue that Plaintiffs’ market power allegations “are obviously 22 padded” and insufficient. Id. The Ninth Circuit has indicated that “[m]arket power may 23 be demonstrated through either of two types of proof.” Rebel Oil Co., 51 F.3d at 1434. 24 The first type of proof is “direct evidence of the injurious exercise of market power.” Id. 25 “The more common type of proof is circumstantial evidence pertaining to the structure of 26 the market.” Id. “To demonstrate market power circumstantially, a plaintiff must: (1) 27 define the relevant market, (2) show that the defendant owns a dominant share of that 28 market, and (3) show that there are significant barriers to entry and show that existing -37- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 competitors lack the capacity to increase their output . . . .” Id. “Measurement of market 2 share is necessary to determine whether the defendant possesses sufficient leverage to 3 influence marketwide output.” Id. at 1437. “Market power need not be pled with 4 specificity, and whether a defendant actually possesses market power is a factual 5 question.” DocMagic, 745 F. Supp. 2d at 1136 (citing Newcal, 513 F.3d at 1045, 1051). 6 The Ninth Circuit has held that in an attempt-to-monopolize claim, a “market share of 44 7 percent is sufficient as a matter of law to support a finding of market power, if entry 8 barriers are high and competitors are unable to expand their output[.]” Rebel Oil Co., 51 9 F.3d at 1438. The Ninth Circuit, however, cautioned that “[c]ourts should be ‘wary of 10 the numbers game of market percentage’ when considering attempt-to-monopolize 11 claims.” Id. n.10 (quoting Dimmitt Agri Indus., Inc. v. CPC Int’l Inc., 679 F.2d 516, 533 12 n.18 (5th Cir. 1982)). 13 Here, Plaintiffs plead circumstantial evidence that Defendants already “wield[] 14 monopoly power in six regional submarkets and ha[ve] come dangerously close in 15 several others.” Doc. No. 31 at 25. Specifically, Plaintiffs allege Defendants are the 16 “dominant provider of medical-traveler services” in the country. SAC ¶ 66. Nationally, 17 Defendants make or control “at least 37% of all sales.” Id. ¶ 67. In the following 18 regional submarkets, Defendants make or control at least 50% of all sales: (1) the Greater 19 Los Angeles Metropolitan Area; (2) the San Francisco Bay Area; (3) the Greater 20 Washington, D.C. Metropolitan Area; (4) the Greater Baltimore Metropolitan Area; (5) 21 the Greater Richmond Metropolitan Area; and (6) the Greater Norfolk Metropolitan Area. 22 Id. ¶ 68. Moreover, in other regional submarkets, Defendants make or control “a 23 commanding percentage of overall sales: Hawaii (87% market foreclosure); Nebraska 24 (83%); Maine (83%); Vermont (80%); Arkansas (73%); Montana (67%); Nevada (64%); 25 and New Hampshire (61%).” Id. ¶ 69. 26 Defendants contend that the market share percentages are based on Plaintiffs’ 27 internal market analysis—not third-party industry data—and that the percentages are 28 “padded” to account for sales that Defendants control. See Doc. No. 30-1 at 23. -38- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 Defendants do not point to, nor is the Court aware of, any binding authority requiring a 2 plaintiff to present third-party industry data at this stage of the litigation in asserting an 3 attempt-to-monopolize claim. Moreover, Plaintiffs expressly state that they have 4 “adjusted each stated market share downward by 5%” to “compensate for possible error.” 5 SAC ¶ 79. Plaintiffs indicate that their internal market analysis is what they can “provide 6 at present without the benefit of discovery.” Id. ¶ 82. As such, the Court finds that 7 Plaintiffs have provided sufficient factual allegations describing Defendants’ position to 8 plausibly conclude that Defendants have “sufficient leverage to influence marketwide 9 output.” Rebel Oil Co., 51 F.3d at 1437. 10 11 B. Entry Barriers Defendants next argue that Plaintiffs fail “to show that there are any legally 12 significant barriers to entry or expansion by competing firms.” Doc. No. 30-1 at 23. 13 Entry barriers are “additional long-run costs that were not incurred by incumbent firms 14 but must be incurred by new entrants,” or “factors in the market that deter entry while 15 permitting incumbent firms to earn monopoly returns.” L.A. Land Co. v. Brunswick 16 Corp., 6 F.3d 1422, 1427-28 (9th Cir.1993). “A mere showing of substantial or even 17 dominant market share alone” is insufficient if the plaintiff has not shown that rivals 18 cannot enter the market and that existing competitors could not expand in response to 19 higher prices. Rebel Oil Co., 51 F.3d at 1439; see also Spectrum Sports, 506 U.S. at 456 20 (“In order to determine whether there is a dangerous probability of monopolization, 21 courts have found it necessary to consider . . . the defendant’s ability to lessen or destroy 22 competition in that market.”). “The main sources of entry barriers are: (1) legal license 23 requirements; (2) control of an essential or superior resource; (3) entrenched buyer 24 preferences for established brands; (4) capital market evaluations imposing higher capital 25 costs on new entrants; and, in some situations, (5) economies of scale.” Rebel Oil Co., 51 26 F.3d at 1439. In assessing entry barriers, courts focus on the ability not to constrain those 27 already in the market, but “those who would enter but are prevented from doing so.” Id. 28 (quoting United States v. Syufy Enter., 903 F.2d 659, 672 n.21 (9th Cir. 1990)). -39- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 Here, the Court finds Plaintiffs’ allegations regarding barriers to entry are 2 sufficient at this stage of the litigation. Plaintiffs assert that Defendants protect their 3 position in the affected markets by utilizing numerous barriers to entry and expansion. 4 See SAC ¶ 106. Specifically, Plaintiffs allege the following market barriers: (1) the 5 nursing shortage; (2) Defendants’ trade restraints and alleged anticompetitive conduct; 6 (3) brand recognition; (4) regulatory and administrative expertise; and (5) capital 7 requirements. See id. at ¶¶ 106-115. 8 9 With respect to the alleged trade restraints, Defendants note that rival providers, like Plaintiffs, can and do expand their capacity by subcontracting with other providers, 10 and that Plaintiffs’ business is experiencing growth. See Doc. No. 30-1 at 24. Thus, 11 Defendants assert the trade restraints do not constitute a barrier to entry. Defendants’ 12 argument, however, is misplaced as Plaintiffs allege that due to Defendants’ trade 13 restraints, “potential entrants and existing rivals cannot develop their own comparable 14 pools to compete against AMN.” SAC ¶ 110 (emphasis added). Additionally, as noted 15 previously, Plaintiffs and other rivals “have been prevented or greatly hindered . . . from 16 developing their own traveler pools and deploying them in order to compete for the large 17 hospitals’ business and to compete in general in the medical-traveler markets.” Id. ¶ 4. 18 Regarding brand recognition, Defendants assert that “it is well-established that 19 reputation is not an entry barrier.” Doc. No. 30-1 at 24. The case relied upon by 20 Defendants pre-dates the Ninth Circuit’s decision in Rebel Oil Co., which makes clear 21 that “entrenched buyer preferences for established brands” is a market barrier. 51 F.3d at 22 1439. Additionally, at the hearing on Defendants’ motion to dismiss Plaintiffs’ FAC, 23 Plaintiff’s counsel explained to the Court that Defendants have “a highly recognized 24 brand[.]” Doc. No. 21 at 24. “In order to enter this market, you [the sellers of traveler 25 services] have to develop a sufficiently trusted brand so that hospitals [the buyers] will 26 hire your medical travelers[.]” Id. 27 28 Further, Plaintiffs sufficiently allege that providers of medical-traveler services require a certain level of expertise in order to perform their operations (SAC ¶ 113), and -40- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 that the provision of medical-traveler services “requires substantial capital funding” so 2 that providers can “continually pay [their] travelers for their work months before being 3 paid by hospital customers for services rendered” (Id. at ¶ 114). Plaintiffs also assert that 4 the nursing shortage constitutes a market barrier. See id. ¶ 107-108. Plaintiffs recognize 5 that the nursing shortage is the result of: (1) accredited nursing schools being unable to 6 accommodate all qualified applicants; and (2) many qualified nurses retiring. Id. ¶ 107. 7 However, Plaintiffs indicate that the nursing shortage affects both potential entrants and 8 existing competitors. See id. Therefore, the Court finds that Plaintiffs have plausibly 9 alleged that there are “factors in the market that deter entry while permitting incumbent 10 firms to earn monopoly returns.” L.A. Land Co., 6 F.3d at 1427-28. 11 3. Summary 12 In sum, the Court finds that Plaintiffs have sufficiently defined the relevant service 13 market and geographic markets, and that Plaintiffs have sufficiently alleged a dangerous 14 probability that Defendants will succeed in becoming a monopoly. Accordingly, the 15 Court DENIES Defendants’ motion to dismiss Plaintiffs’ third cause of action. 16 D. 17 Tortious Interference with Prospective Economic Relations Claim In their fifth cause of action, Plaintiffs contend that Defendants, through use of 18 their various trade restraints, “deliberately and effectually interfered with Aya’s 19 prospective relationships with recruiters, travelers, hospitals and vendor-managers.” 20 SAC ¶ 349. As a consequence, Defendants “successfully interfered with [Aya’s] 21 prospective commercial relationships, which Aya seeks to establish and requires in order 22 to remain a viable competitor in the affected markets.” Id. ¶ 351. Defendants argue 23 dismissal of Plaintiffs’ tortious interference claim is appropriate because the relationships 24 Plaintiffs allege Defendants interfered with are “undefined, conclusory and speculative in 25 26 27 28 -41- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 2 nature.” Doc. No. 15-1 at 23.16 The California Supreme Court set forth the standard for determining whether a 3 plaintiff has stated a claim for tortious interference with prospective business relations in 4 Buckaloo v. Johnson, 537 P.2d 865 (Cal. 1975). The elements for such a claim are: “(1) 5 an economic relationship between the plaintiff and some third party, with the probability 6 of future economic benefit to the plaintiff; (2) the defendant’s knowledge of the 7 relationship; (3) intentional acts on the part of the defendant designed to disrupt the 8 relationship; (4) actual disruption of the relationship; and (5) economic harm to the 9 plaintiff proximately caused by the acts of the defendant.” Korea Supply Co. v. Lockheed 10 Martin Corp., 29 Cal. 4th 1134, 1153 (2003) (internal citations and quotation marks 11 omitted). 12 Here, Plaintiffs’ allegations of tortious interference are insufficient to state a claim. 13 For example, Plaintiffs allege that Defendants have “disrupted relationships that Aya has 14 tried to develop with various recruiters, travelers, hospitals, and vendor-managers.” SAC 15 ¶ 350. However, while Plaintiffs need not provide the actual names of such individuals 16 and/or companies, Plaintiffs “must allege a relationship with ‘a specific, alebit unnamed’ 17 third party.” R Power Biofuels, LLC v. Chemex LLC, No. 16-cv-716-LHK, 2016 WL 18 6663002, at *16 (N.D. Cal. Nov. 11, 2016) (quoting Ramona Manor Convalescent Hosp. 19 v. Care Enterps., 177 Cal. App. 1120, 1133 (Ct. App. 1986)). Moreover, “it is essential 20 that the Plaintiff allege facts showing that Defendant interfered with Plaintiff’s 21 relationship with a particular individual.” Damabeh v. 7-Eleven, Inc., No. 12-cv-1739- 22 LHK, 2013 WL 1915867, at *10 (N.D. Cal. May 8, 2013). Because Plaintiffs fail to 23 provide any details about the relationships with specific individuals and/or companies, 24 and because it is impossible to determine how many such relationships existed, the Court 25 26 27 28                                                 16 Defendants also argue that dismissal is appropriate because Plaintiffs’ claim is predicated on antitrust violations, which Plaintiffs have “failed to plead sufficiently.” Id. However, for the reasons set forth above, the Court disagrees and finds Defendants’ argument unpersuasive. -42- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 finds that Plaintiffs fail to state a claim for tortious interference with prospective 2 economic advantage. 3 Accordingly, the Court DISMISSES Plaintiffs’ fifth cause of action for tortious 4 interference with prospective economic relations with leave to amend. 5 E. 6 UCL Claim Finally, Plaintiffs allege a cause of action for violations of California’s UCL 7 because through Defendants’ “anticompetitive practices,” Defendants have “employed 8 conduct that is unfair, unlawful and/or deceptive.” SAC ¶ 355. 9 California’s UCL prohibits “any unlawful, unfair or fraudulent business act or 10 practice and unfair, deceptive, untrue or misleading advertising.” Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code 11 § 17200. The UCL provides a separate theory of liability under each of the three prongs: 12 “unlawful,” “unfair,” and “fraudulent.”17 Stanwood v. Mary Kay, Inc., 941 F. Supp. 2d 13 1212, 1222 (C.D. Cal. 2012) (citing Lozano v. AT & T Wireless Servs., Inc., 504 F.3d 14 718, 731 (9th Cir. 2007)). 15 With respect to the “unlawful” prong, for the reasons discussed above, the Court 16 finds Plaintiffs sufficiently allege conduct that falls within the unlawful prong of the 17 UCL. Section 17200 “borrows” violations from other laws by making them 18 independently actionable as unfair competitive practices. Korea Supply Co., 29 Cal. 4th 19 at 1143. Because Plaintiffs allege unlawful conduct under Section 1 and Section 2 of the 20 Sherman Act, Plaintiffs also adequately allege a violation of the UCL’s unlawful prong. 21 With respect to the “unfair” prong, the California Supreme Court has adopted the 22 following test in the antitrust context: “[w]hen a plaintiff who claims to have suffered 23 injury from a direct competitor’s ‘unfair’ act or practice invokes section 17200,” unfair in 24 25 26 27 28                                                 17 The Court notes that in the SAC, Plaintiffs claim Defendants have “employed conduct that is unfair, unlawful and/or deceptive.” SAC ¶ 355. The Court does not construe Plaintiffs’ SAC as asserting a claim under the UCL’s fraudulent prong, especially in light of the fact that Plaintiffs do not mention “fraud” or “fraudulent” conduct in support of this cause of action, nor do Plaintiffs respond to Defendants’ arguments regarding the fraudulent prong of the UCL. -43- 17cv205-MMA (MDD) 1 section 17200 means “conduct that threatens an incipient violation of an antitrust law, or 2 violates the policy or spirit of one of those laws because its effects are comparable to or 3 the same as a violation of the law, or otherwise significantly threatens or harms 4 competition.” Cel-Tech Commc’ns, Inc. v. L.A. Cellular Tel. Co., 973 P.2d 527, 544 5 (Cal. 1999). Here, as discussed in great detail above, Plaintiffs have sufficiently alleged 6 conduct that “threatens or harms competition.” Id. Plaintiffs allege Defendants’ trade 7 restraints have an exclusionary effect on Defendants’ rivals: “the rivals cannot solicit any 8 of AMN’s employees, and AMN’s recruiters, who are best placed to solicit these 9 employees, dare not leave AMN to work for any rival.” SAC ¶ 219. Moreover, 10 Defendants have utilized “unlawful trade restraints and baseless litigation to prevent and 11 discourage [their] rivals from seeking to make hires from this pool. [Their] purpose is to 12 remain the only provider that can offer such as pool.” Id. at ¶ 221. Thus, Plaintiffs also 13 sufficiently allege a violation of the UCL’s unfair prong. 14 15 Accordingly, the Court DENIES Defendants’ motion to dismiss Plaintiffs’ sixth cause of action. 16 17 CONCLUSION Based on the foregoing, the Court GRANTS IN PART and DENIES IN PART 18 Defendants’ motion to dismiss Plaintiffs’ SAC. The Court DISMISSES Plaintiffs’ 19 tortious interference with prospective economic relations claim without prejudice. 20 Plaintiffs may file a third amended complaint that cures the deficiencies addressed herein 21 with respect to the tortious interference with prospective economic relations claim on or 22 before June 29, 2018. 23 IT IS SO ORDERED. 24 25 26 27 28 Dated: June 19, 2018 _____________________________ HON. MICHAEL M. ANELLO United States District Judge -44- 17cv205-MMA (MDD)

Disclaimer: Justia Dockets & Filings provides public litigation records from the federal appellate and district courts. These filings and docket sheets should not be considered findings of fact or liability, nor do they necessarily reflect the view of Justia.


Why Is My Information Online?