Connecticut Fine Wine and Spirits, LLC v. Harris et al
Filing
91
RULING granting 38 Motion to Dismiss; granting 66 Motion to Dismiss; granting 80 Motion to Dismiss. Total Wines challenges to the post and hold provisions and minimum retail price provisions are dismissed, because these provisions constitut e hybrid restraints that receive rule of reason scrutiny and therefore cannot be preempted. Total Wines claim that the price discrimination prohibition is preempted is also dismissed, because that provision is a unilateral restraint outside the scope of the Sherman Act. Signed by Judge Janet C. Hall on 6/6/2017. (Lewis, D)
UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
DISTRICT OF CONNECTICUT
CONNECTICUT FINE WINE &
SPIRITS, LLC,
Plaintiff,
v.
JONATHAN A. HARRIS et al.,
Defendants.
:
:
:
:
:
:
:
:
CIVIL ACTION NO.
3:16–cv–1434 (JCH)
JUNE 6, 2017
RULING RE: MOTIONS TO DISMISS (DOC. NOS. 38, 66, 80)
I.
TABLE OF CONTENTS
INTRODUCTION .................................................................................................. 2
II.
BACKGROUND ................................................................................................... 3
A.
Connecticut’s Liquor Marketplace ................................................................... 3
B.
Total Wine ....................................................................................................... 6
III.
LEGAL STANDARDS ........................................................................................... 7
A.
Motions to Dismiss: Rule 12(b)(6) ................................................................... 7
B.
Sherman Act Preemption of State Statutes ..................................................... 7
IV.
DISCUSSION ..................................................................................................... 12
A.
Post and Hold Provisions .............................................................................. 15
1.
Unilateral or Hybrid Restraint ................................................................... 15
2.
Per Se Violation or Rule of Reason Analysis ........................................... 19
a.
b.
B.
Count One: Horizontal Price Fixing .................................................... 20
Count Two: Vertical Price Fixing ........................................................ 25
Minimum Retail Price Provisions ................................................................... 27
1.
Unilateral or Hybrid Restraint ................................................................... 27
2.
Per Se Violation or Rule of Reason Analysis ........................................... 29
a.
b.
C.
V.
Count One: Horizontal Price Fixing .................................................... 30
Count Two: Vertical Price Fixing ........................................................ 31
Price Discrimination Prohibition..................................................................... 36
CONCLUSION.................................................................................................... 39
1
I.
INTRODUCTION
Plaintiff Connecticut Fine Wine & Spirits, LLC (“Total Wine”) instituted this action
against defendants Jonathan A. Harris, Commissioner of the Connecticut Department of
Consumer Protection, and John Suchy, Director of the Connecticut Division of Liquor
Control (collectively, the “state defendants”), in their official capacities. Compl. (Doc.
No. 1) at 1. Total Wine alleges that certain state statutory and regulatory provisions
governing the distribution and sale of alcoholic beverages are preempted by federal
antitrust law.1 See id. ¶¶ 28, 33. Total Wine seeks declaratory and injunctive relief.
See id. ¶ 34.
Four trade associations—the Wine & Spirit Wholesalers of Connecticut
(“WSWC”), Connecticut Beer Wholesalers Association (“CBWA”), Connecticut
Restaurant Association (“CRA”), and Connecticut Package Stores Association (“CPSA”)
(collectively, the “trade associations”)—filed Motions to Intervene (Doc. Nos. 27, 30, 39,
47). The court granted the motions, see Ruling (Doc. No. 62) at 2, as well as a
subsequent Motion to Intervene (Doc. No. 69) filed by Brescome Barton, Inc.
(“Brescome” and, with the trade associations, “intervenors”), see Order (Doc. No. 75).
Harris and Suchy filed a joint Motion to Dismiss, see generally Mot. to Dismiss
(“State Defs. Mot.”) (Doc. No. 38), as did the trade associations, see generally Mot. to
Dismiss by Wine & Spirits Wholesalers of Conn., Conn. Beer Wholesalers Ass’n, Conn.
Rest. Ass’n, & Conn. Package Stores Ass’n (“Trade Ass’ns Mot.”) (Doc. No. 66).
1 The “challenged provisions” Total Wine alleges are preempted by the Sherman Act are:
(1) section 30-63 of the Connecticut General Statutes and section 30-6-B12 of the Regulations of
Connecticut State Agencies (“post and hold provisions”); (2) sections 30-68m(a)(1) and 30-68m(b) of the
Connecticut General Statutes (“minimum retail price provisions”); and (3) sections 30-63(b), 30-68k, and
30-94(b) of the Connecticut General Statutes and section 30-6-A29(a) of the Regulations of Connecticut
State Agencies (“price discrimination prohibition provisions”). See Compl. ¶¶ 12–14.
2
Brescome filed an additional Motion to Dismiss. See generally Def. Brescome Barton,
Inc.’s Mot. to Dismiss (“Brescome Mot.”) (Doc. No. 80). Each Motion to Dismiss relies
on Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 12(b)(6). See State Defs. Mot. at 1; Trade Ass’ns
Mot. at 1; Brescome Mot. at 1. Total Wine filed a consolidated opposition to the
Motions, see generally Pl.’s Consolidated Opp’n to Defs.’ & Intervenors’ Mots. to
Dismiss (“Opp’n” or “Opposition”) (Doc. No. 82), and the state defendants and
intervenors replied in a timely manner, see generally State Defs.’ Reply Mem. in Supp.
of Mot. to Dismiss (“State Defs. Reply”) (Doc. No. 84); Intervenors’ Joint Reply in Supp.
of their Mots. to Dismiss (“Intervenors Reply”) (Doc. No. 85). The court heard oral
argument on the pending Motions on May 18, 2017.
For the reasons set forth below, the Motions to Dismiss are GRANTED.
II.
BACKGROUND2
A.
Connecticut’s Liquor Marketplace
The sale of alcoholic beverages in Connecticut is prohibited, except as permitted
by Connecticut’s Liquor Control Act. Conn. Gen. Stat. § 30-74(a). “Connecticut has
what may be characterized as a tripartite pricing mechanism establishing the method by
which liquor prices are set by the manufacturer, . . . the wholesaler[,] and the retailer.”
Serlin Wine & Spirit Merchs., Inc. v. Healy, 512 F. Supp. 936, 937–38 (D. Conn. 1981).
Most relevant here are three sets of requirements: the post and hold provisions,
minimum retail price provisions, and price discrimination prohibition.
2
For the purposes of ruling on the pending Motions to Dismiss, the court accepts as true all wellpled facts in the Complaint. See Simon v. KeySpan Corp., 694 F.3d 196, 201 (2d Cir. 2012). The facts
included here are limited to those necessary to rule on the pending Motions.
3
First, Connecticut’s post and hold provisions require state-licensed
manufacturers and wholesalers to post a “bottle price” and a “case price” each month
with the Department of Consumer Protection. See Compl. ¶ 12. Posted prices are then
made available to industry participants, who may, and often do, amend their own
postings to match competitors’ lower prices. See id. ¶¶ 12, 16. Once these prices are
finalized, the manufacturer or wholesaler must maintain its posted prices for the
following month.3 See id. ¶ 12.
3
Section 30-63(c) of the Connecticut General Statutes sets forth the post and hold requirement
as follows:
For alcoholic liquor other than beer, each manufacturer, wholesaler and out-of-state shipper
permittee shall post with the department, on a monthly basis, the bottle, can and case price of
any brand of goods offered for sale in Connecticut, which price when so posted shall be the
controlling price for such manufacturer, wholesaler or out-of-state permittee for the month
following such posting. On and after July 1, 2005, for beer, each manufacturer, wholesaler and
out-of-state shipper permittee shall post with the department, on a monthly basis, the bottle, can
and case price, and the price per keg or barrel or fractional unit thereof for any brand of goods
offered for sale in Connecticut which price when so posted shall be the controlling price for such
brand of goods offered for sale in this state for the month following such posting. Such
manufacturer, wholesaler and out-of-state shipper permittee may also post additional prices for
such bottle, can, case, keg or barrel or fractional unit thereof for a specified portion of the
following month which prices when so posted shall be the controlling prices for such bottle, can,
case, keg or barrel or fractional unit thereof for such specified portion of the following month.
Notice of all manufacturer, wholesaler and out-of-state shipper permittee prices shall be given to
permittee purchasers by direct mail, Internet web site or advertising in a trade publication having
circulation among the retail permittees except a wholesaler permittee may give such notice by
hand delivery. Price postings with the department setting forth wholesale prices to retailers shall
be available for inspection during regular business hours at the offices of the department by
manufacturers and wholesalers until three o’clock p.m. of the first business day after the last day
for posting prices. A manufacturer or wholesaler may amend such manufacturer's or
wholesaler’s posted price for any month to meet a lower price posted by another manufacturer or
wholesaler with respect to alcoholic liquor bearing the same brand or trade name and of like age,
vintage, quality and unit container size; provided that any such amended price posting shall be
filed before three o’clock p.m. of the fourth business day after the last day for posting prices; and
provided further such amended posting shall not set forth prices lower than those being met. Any
manufacturer or wholesaler posting an amended price shall, at the time of posting, identify in
writing the specific posting being met. On and after July 1, 2005, all wholesaler postings, other
than for beer, for the following month shall be provided to retail permittees not later than the
twenty-seventh day of the month prior to such posting. All wholesaler postings for beer shall be
provided to retail permittees not later than the twentieth day of the month prior to such posting.
Conn. Gen. Stat. § 30-63(c). Section 30-6-B12 of the Regulations of Connecticut State Agencies further
clarifies these requirements. See, e.g., Conn. Agencies Regs. § 30-6-B12(d) (allowing amendments to
posted price schedules to correct “obvious typographical errors”).
4
Second, the minimum retail price provisions require that retailers sell to
customers at or above a statutorily defined “cost.” See id. ¶ 13. Generally, a retailer’s
“cost” for a given alcoholic beverage is determined by adding the posted bottle price—
as set by the wholesaler—and a markup for shipping and delivery.4 See id.
Wholesalers occasionally lower their posted case prices for a given month, without
lowering posted bottle prices, during what are referred to as “off-post” months. See id.
Although retailers buy almost exclusively by the case, their prices remain fixed by the
minimum retail price provisions, which reference posted bottle prices, rather than posted
case prices. See id.
Finally, wholesalers must sell a given product to all retailers at the same price.5
See id. ¶ 14. Specifically, wholesalers may not offer discounts to retailers who are high
volume purchasers. See Compl. ¶ 14.
4 Section 30-68m(b) of the Connecticut General Statutes sets forth the mandate that “[n]o retail
permittee shall sell alcoholic liquor at a price below his or her cost.” “Cost” is in turn defined as follows:
(A) for alcoholic liquor other than beer, the posted bottle price from the wholesaler plus any
charge for shipping or delivery to the retail permittee’s place of business paid by the retail
permittee in addition to the posted price, and (B) for beer, the lowest posted price during the
month in which the retail permittee is selling plus any charge for shipping or delivery to the retail
permittee’s place of business paid by the retail permittee in addition to the price originally paid by
the retail permittee . . . .
Conn. Gen. Stat. § 30-68m(a)(1).
5
Section 30-68k of the Connecticut General Statutes provides:
No holder of any wholesaler's permit shall ship, transport or deliver within this state or any
territory therein or sell or offer for sale, to a purchaser holding a permit for the sale of alcoholic
liquor for on or off premises consumption, any brand of alcoholic liquor, including cordials, . . . at
a bottle, can or case price higher than the lowest price at which such item is then being sold or
offered for sale or shipped, transported or delivered by such wholesaler to any other such
purchaser to which the wholesaler sells, offers for sale, ships, transports or delivers that brand of
alcoholic liquor within this state.
Similarly, manufacturers and wholesalers are prohibited from:
(1) “discriminat[ing] in any manner in price discounts between one permittee and another on sales
or purchases of alcoholic liquors bearing the same brand or trade name and of like age, size and
5
No Connecticut agency or instrumentality actively supervises the price posting
and matching processes. See id. ¶ 21. Rather, manufacturers and wholesalers are left
to post prices as they see fit, without review by the state. See id.
B.
Total Wine
Total Wine owns and operates four retail beverage stores in Connecticut.
Compl. ¶ 1. It holds package store permits for its four retail locations. See id. ¶ 9.
Total Wine strives “to offer[ ] the nation’s best selection of alcoholic beverages, and to
hav[e] the lowest prices on wine, spirits, and beer.” See id. ¶ 7. Total Wine alleges that
the challenged provisions prevent it from using its “efficiencies” to reduce the prices at
which it sells to consumers. See id. ¶¶ 17, 22. It has not lowered its prices below its
“cost,” for fear of being subject to civil and criminal penalties. See id. ¶ 22; see also id.
¶ 15 (discussing penalties for violations of Liquor Control Act).6 As Total Wine
acknowledged at oral argument, its antitrust preemption claims are facial challenges.
quality,” or (2) “allow[ing] in any form any discount, rebate, free goods, allowance or other
inducement for the purpose of making sales or purchases.”
Conn. Gen. Stat. § 30-63(b).
Section 30-94(b) of the Connecticut General Statutes and section 30-6-A29(a) of the Regulations
of Connecticut Agencies further limit the ability of participants in Connecticut’s liquor market to offer
discounts to their customers.
The court notes that Total Wine’s Complaint includes several allegations that suggest the
Connecticut liquor regime is unfair to consumers. See, e.g., Compl. ¶ 17 (“Under this anticompetitive
regime, a retailer like Total Wine & More cannot use its market and business efficiencies to reduce the
prices offered to consumers.”). Whether or not the statutory and regulatory scheme implemented by the
State of Connecticut is wise is not a question for this court. Rather, the court can only be asked to
determine whether the challenged provisions are preempted by federal law. Arguments as to the harm
inflicted on consumers by this scheme are more appropriately directed to Connecticut’s executive and
legislative branches of government.
6
6
III.
LEGAL STANDARDS
A.
Motions to Dismiss: Rule 12(b)(6)
In ruling on a Motion to Dismiss, the court “accept[s] all factual claims in the
complaint as true and draw[s] all reasonable inferences in the plaintiff’s favor.” Simon v.
Key Span Corp., 694 F.3d 196, 201 (2d Cir. 2012) (citing Famous Horse Inc. v. 5th Ave.
Photo Inc., 624 F.3d 106, 108 (2d Cir. 2010)). “[T]he court, in judging the sufficiency of
the complaint, must accept the facts alleged and construe ambiguities in the light most
favorable to upholding the plaintiff’s claim.” Doe v. Columbia Univ., 831 F.3d 46, 48 (2d
Cir. 2016). However, the court need not “accept conclusory allegations or legal
conclusions masquerading as factual conclusions.” Faber v. Metro. Life Ins. Co., 648
F.3d 98, 104 (2d Cir. 2011) (quoting Rolon v. Henneman, 517 F.3d 140, 149 (2d Cir.
2008)). Instead, “[t]o survive dismissal, the plaintiff must provide the grounds upon
which his claim rests through factual allegations sufficient to raise a right to relief above
the speculative level.” Lanier v. Bats Exch., Inc., 838 F.3d 139, 150 (2d Cir. 2016)
(quoting ATSI Commc’ns, Inc. v. Shaar Fund, Ltd., 493 F.3d 87, 98 (2d Cir. 2007)).
“While a complaint attacked by a Rule 12(b)(6) motion to dismiss does not need
detailed factual allegations, a plaintiff’s obligation to provide the grounds of his
entitlement to relief requires more than labels and conclusions . . . .” Bell Atl. Corp. v.
Twombly, 550 U.S. 544, 555 (2007) (quotation marks and citations omitted).
B.
Sherman Act Preemption of State Statutes
Section 1 of the Sherman Act provides that “[e]very contract, combination . . . or
conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce . . . is declared to be illegal.” 15 U.S.C.
§ 1. The Supreme Court has made clear that, “[i]n determining whether the Sherman
7
Act pre-empts a state statute, [courts] apply principles similar to those . . . employ[ed] in
considering whether any state statute is pre-empted by a federal statute pursuant to the
Supremacy Clause.” Rice v. Norman Williams Co., 458 U.S. 654, 659 (1982).7 “[T]he
party asserting preemption must demonstrate an ‘irreconcilable conflict’ between the
challenged statute and the Sherman Act. Such a conflict will be found only ‘when the
conduct contemplated by the statute is in all cases a per se violation’ of the antitrust
laws.” Freedom Holdings v. Cuomo (“Freedom Holdings IV”), 624 F.3d 38, 49–50 (2d
Cir. 2010) (quoting Norman Williams, 458 U.S. at 659, 661). “A state regulatory scheme
is not pre-empted by the federal antitrust laws simply because in a hypothetical situation
a private party’s compliance with the statute might cause him to violate the antitrust
laws,” nor is it preempted solely because “the state scheme might have an
anticompetitive effect.” Norman Williams, 458 U.S. at 659. As the state defendants
pointed out at oral argument, see Hr’g Tr. (Doc. No. 89) at 11:6–11:10, whether or not
private parties are actually colluding has no import in the preemption analysis, which
focuses on the text and face of the statutes at issue.
Ordinarily, “a two-step inquiry guides analysis of” claims that state statutes are
preempted by the Sherman Act. Freedom Holdings IV, 624 F.3d at 49. At the first step,
the court must determine whether the state statutes “mandate or authorize a per se
antitrust violation.” Id. at 50 (quotation marks and citation omitted). Then, “[e]ven if
plaintiffs showed that the challenged statutes mandate or authorize a per se antitrust
7 The parties agree that Norman Williams provides at least part of the framework governing the
court’s analysis. See Mem. of Law in Supp. of Mot. to Dismiss (“State Defs. Mem. in Supp.”) (Doc.
No. 38-1) at 7; Joint Mem. of Law by Wine & Spirits Wholesalers of Conn., Conn. Beer Wholesalers
Ass’n, Conn. Rest. Ass’n, & Conn. Package Stores Ass’n in Supp. of their Mot. to Dismiss (“Trade Ass’ns
Mem. in Supp.”) (Doc. No. 66-1) at 10; Brescome Barton, Inc’s Mem. of Law in Supp. of its Mot. to
Dismiss (“Brescome Mem. in Supp.”) (Doc. No. 80-1) at 4; Opp’n at 11.
8
violation, those laws might still be saved from preemption by the doctrine of state action
immunity, if the anti-competitive conduct is both clearly articulated and affirmatively
expressed as state policy and actively supervised by the [s]tate itself.” Id. (internal
quotation marks and citations omitted). Neither the defendants nor any of the
intervenors have suggested at this time that Total Wine’s claims should be dismissed at
the second step of this analysis. See Opp’n at 12 n.4 (discussing the second step—socalled Parker immunity—and defendants’ failure to raise it as grounds for dismissal).
Similarly, neither the defendants nor the intervenors have suggested at this time that
any of the challenged provisions might be saved by the Twenty-first Amendment. Cf.
Costco Wholesale Corp. v. Maleng, 522 F.3d 874, 901–04 (9th Cir. 2008) (discussing
permissibility of Washington’s post and hold provisions under Twenty-first Amendment).
Therefore, the court’s analysis in this Ruling focuses solely on the first step of the above
inquiry: determining whether the state statutes “mandate or authorize a per se antitrust
violation.” Freedom Holdings IV, 624 F.3d at 49 (quotation marks and citation omitted).
In determining whether there is an irreconcilable conflict between the state and
federal statutes, the court must determine whether the challenged state statutes qualify
as unilateral or hybrid restraints. “[R]estraints ‘unilaterally imposed by government . . .
to the exclusion of private control’ do not violate the antitrust laws.” Freedom Holdings
IV, 624 F.3d at 50 (quoting Fisher v. City of Berkeley, Cal., 475 U.S. 260, 266 (1986));
see also Fisher, 475 U.S. at 267 (characterizing unilateral restraints as “outside the
purview of § 1” of Sherman Act). “Where, however, state law does not regulate
unilaterally but, rather, grants private actors a degree of regulatory control over
competition, the statute may be preempted as a ‘hybrid’ restraint on trade.” Freedom
9
Holdings IV, 624 F.3d at 50 (citing, inter alia, 324 Liquor Corp. v. Duffy, 479 U.S. 335,
345–46 & n.8 (1987)).
If the statute qualifies as a hybrid restraint, the court then must determine
whether the conduct envisioned by the statute constitutes a per se violation of the
Sherman Act, or instead would receive rule of reason scrutiny. See Norman Williams,
458 U.S. at 661. “[A] state statute, when considered in the abstract, may be
condemned under the antitrust laws only if it mandates or authorizes conduct that
necessarily constitutes a violation of the antitrust laws in all cases, or if it places
irresistible pressure on a private party to violate the antitrust laws in order to comply
with the statute.” Id. In other words, if a state statute “mandates or authorizes conduct”
that is a per se violation of the Sherman Act, it is preempted; however, if the “activity
addressed by the statute does not fall into that category, and therefore must be
analyzed under the rule of reason, the statute cannot be condemned in the abstract.”
Id. (noting that rule of reason analysis “requires an examination of the circumstances
underlying a particular economic practice, and therefore does not lend itself to a
conclusion that a statute is facially inconsistent with federal antitrust laws”).
The trade associations insist that the court must invert the analytical framework
set out above and instead consider whether the state statutes constitute a unilateral
restraint only after determining that they “present a potential per se violation in all
cases.” Trade Ass’ns Mem. in Supp. at 13.8 The trade associations cite only one
8 The state defendants—who also ask the court to uphold the challenged provisions—appear to
disagree with the trade associations’ argument that the court can only determine if the challenged
statutes are unilateral or hybrid restraints after evaluating whether they are per se violations of the
Sherman Act. See State Defs. Mem. in Supp. at 4 (“The Challenged Provisions are Unilateral Restraints
Imposed by the State of Connecticut and May Not be Preempted.”), 7 (“Federal Preemption May Not be
Founded Upon Conduct Analyzed Under a Rule of Reason Standard.”).
10
case—from the Sixth Circuit—in support of this assertion. See id. (citing Tritent Int’l
Corp. v. Kentucky, 467 F.3d 547, 555, 559 (6th Cir. 2006)). The trade associations’
argument on this point is unconvincing for at least three reasons.
First, it makes little sense to reach the question of whether a given restraint
would be a per se violation of the Sherman Act before determining whether or not it is
unilateral and thus entirely outside the scope of federal antitrust law.
Second, whatever the law may be in the Sixth Circuit, the trade associations’
preferred analytical framework is not mandated by relevant Second Circuit precedent.
See Freedom Holdings IV, 624 F.3d at 52–53 (characterizing issue of whether
“challenged statutes are unilateral acts of a state falling outside of federal antitrust law”
as “the threshold question at trial”); Freedom Holdings, Inc. v. Spitzer (“Freedom
Holdings I”), 357 F.3d 205, 223–26 (2d Cir. 2004) (concluding that complaint sufficiently
alleged that challenged statutes were hybrid restraints, before addressing other aspects
of “the first question[: ] whether the scheme alleged to have been created . . . would
constitute a per se violation of federal antitrust law if brought about by an agreement
among private parties”).
Third, notwithstanding the Sixth Circuit’s interpretation of Supreme Court
precedent as requiring “that the Rice preemption analysis—that is, whether the state
statute at issue mandates or authorizes unlawful anticompetitive behavior—must
precede the analysis under the hybrid-restraint theory,” other circuit courts have
reached the opposite conclusion. See, e.g., Costco Wholesale Corp. v. Maleng, 522
F.3d 874, 892–96 (9th Cir. 2008) (determining first that Washington’s post and hold law
was hybrid restraint, and then that it was per se violation of Sherman Act); TFWS, Inc.
11
v. Schaefer (“TFWS I”), 242 F.3d 198, 207 (4th Cir. 2001) (“Our analysis under
[section] 1 has two steps. We first decide whether the regulatory system at issue is a
‘unilateral restraint’ or a ‘hybrid restraint.’ Second, if it is a hybrid restraint, we must
decide whether it involves a per se violation of [section] 1.” (citations omitted)). The
Ninth and Fourth Circuits offer a more persuasive reading of the relevant Supreme
Court precedent in this regard.
In sum, therefore, the court’s preemption analysis has two steps. First, the court
must determine whether the challenged statutes impose unilateral or hybrid restraints.
If they impose unilateral restraints, they are not preempted, and the court’s inquiry is at
an end. However, if the state statutes are hybrid restraints, the court must determine
whether they are per se violations of the Sherman Act, and thus preempted, or subject
to rule of reason analysis and not preempted.
IV.
DISCUSSION
Before engaging in the preemption analysis outlined above, the court must first
determine whether the challenged provisions are to be analyzed individually and in turn,
or collectively. The defendants and intervenors made clear at oral argument that they
believe the statutes should be evaluated separately, while Total Wine urged the court to
read them together. Here, there can be little doubt that the three challenged sets of
provisions function, at least to some extent, together to effectuate the legislature’s policy
goals. See Trade Ass’ns Mem. in Supp. at 8 (“The common purpose of this trio of
alcohol beverage pricing statutes is to preclude wholesalers from discriminating in
prices among retailers.”); Opp’n at 1 (“[T]hree aspects of the [Liquor Control] Act, taken
together, serve to effectively compel industry-wide horizontal and vertical price fixing
12
among alcohol wholesalers and retailers in Connecticut . . . .”). However, several
factors inform the court’s conclusion that the challenged statutes should be analyzed
individually rather than collectively.
First, federalism principles undergirding the preemption doctrine counsel in favor
of addressing the statutes in turn. “In determining whether the Sherman Act pre-empts
a state statute, [federal courts] apply principles similar to those which [they] employ in
considering whether any state statute is pre-empted by a federal statute pursuant to the
Supremacy Clause.” Norman Williams, 458 U.S. at 659. Federal courts frequently note
that, while they do not hesitate to find state law preempted when the Supremacy Clause
so requires, their analysis includes “due regard for the presuppositions of our embracing
federal system, including the principle of diffusion of power not as a matter of doctrinaire
localism but as a promoter of democracy.” City of Milwaukee v. Illinois & Michigan, 451
U.S. 304, 316 (1981) (quoting San Diego Bldg. Trades Council v. Garmon, 359 U.S.
236, 243 (1959)). “[B]ecause the States are independent sovereigns in our federal
system, [federal courts] have long presumed that Congress does not cavalierly preempt state law causes of action.” Wurtz v. Rawlings Co., LLC, 761 F.3d 232, 238 (2d
Cir. 2014) (quoting Medtronic, Inc. v. Lohr, 518 U.S. 470, 485 (1996)). In this case, the
caution with which federal courts properly approach claims that state laws should be
struck down as preempted is best given effect by addressing each provision separately.
In doing so, the court will give “due regard” for the policy judgments of the people of the
state of Connecticut by addressing the provisions individually, in an effort to strike down
no more of state law than is required by the Supremacy Clause.
13
Moreover, the framework by which the court analyzes antitrust preemption claims
requires that the court classify the challenged provisions as unilateral or hybrid
restraints, and, if hybrid, whether they are horizontal or vertical restraints, subject to per
se scrutiny or a rule of reason analysis. Application of the Second Circuit and Supreme
Court precedents cited by all parties in this case is impossible if the court is required to
evaluate the entire corpus of challenged provisions together. It makes little sense, for
example, to conceive of the post-and-hold provisions as having vertical effect, whereas
the minimum retail price provisions clearly do have vertical effect. Total Wine’s
suggested way to resolve this issue—by concluding that the combination of statutes are
hybrid, horizontal and vertical restraints, subject to per se scrutiny—is unconvincing.
The antitrust preemption analysis outlined above is more appropriately performed on
each challenged provision in turn, with the court determining whether each one conflicts
with the Sherman Act.
These two justifications for analyzing the challenged provisions separately are
further buttressed by the fact that the Connecticut legislature has codified its preference
that the invalidity of certain portions of state statutes should, as a general matter, not
infect other portions of that statute. Conn. Gen. Stat. § 1-3 (“If any provision of any act
passed by the general assembly or its application to any person or circumstances is
held invalid, such invalidity shall not affect other provisions or applications of such act.”).
“To overcome the presumption of severability, a party must show that the portion
declared invalid is ‘so mutually connected and dependent on the remainder of the
statute as to indicate an intent that they should stand or fall together’ and that the
interdependence is such that the legislature would not have adopted the statute without
14
the invalid portion.” Payne v. Fairfield Hills Hosp., 215 Conn. 675, 685 (1990) (quoting
State v. Menillo, 171 Conn. 141, 145 (1976)). Relatedly, the challenged provisions are
each codified in separate sections or subsections of the Connecticut General Statutes,
see supra at Part II.A, further supporting the view that the challenged provisions should
be analyzed separately.
Thus, the court concludes, in light of federalism concerns animating preemption
analyses as well as the necessity of categorizing the challenged provisions for the
antitrust inquiry the court must undertake here, that the challenged provisions should be
addressed individually, rather than collectively.
A.
Post and Hold Provisions
First, the court turns to the post and hold provisions. For the reasons set forth in
detail below, the court concludes: (1) that Total Wine has plausibly alleged that the post
and hold provisions are a hybrid restraint, but (2) that the Complaint does not plausibly
allege, under controlling Second Circuit law, that post and hold provisions constitute per
se violations of the Sherman Act. Therefore, Total Wine’s claims that the post and hold
provisions are preempted are dismissed.
1.
Unilateral or Hybrid Restraint
As noted above, see supra Part III.B, unilateral restraints are “imposed by
government . . . to the exclusion of private control,” Freedom Holdings IV, 624 F.3d
at 50 (quoting Fisher, 475 U.S. at 266), while hybrid restraints “grant[ ] private actors a
degree of regulatory control over competition,” id. “[T]he federal antitrust laws may
preempt state laws that authorize or compel private parties to engage in anticompetitive
behavior.” Freedom Holdings I, 357 F.3d at 223–24 (discussing 324 Liquor, 479 U.S. at
15
345–46 & n.8). “As Judge Boudin of the First Circuit has artfully noted, ‘[w]hat is
centrally forbidden is state licensing of arrangements between private parties that
suppress competition—not state directives that by themselves limit or reduce
competition.’” Costco Wholesale Corp., 522 F.3d at 889 (quoting Mass. Food Ass’n v.
Mass. Alcoholic Beverages Control Comm’n, 197 F.3d 560, 566 (1st Cir. 1999)).
Given the somewhat opaque language that characterizes the definitions of
unilateral and hybrid restraints, the best way to determine how to classify the provisions
at issue in this case would appear to be by comparison with the provisions at issue in
Fisher v. City of Berkeley, Cal., 475 U.S. 260 (1986), and 324 Liquor Corp. v. Duffy, 479
U.S. 335 (1987).9 The Supreme Court held that the ordinance discussed in Fisher was
a unilateral restraint, 475 U.S. at 269–70, while the statute analyzed in 324 Liquor was a
hybrid restraint, 479 U.S. at 345 n.8.
In Fisher, the challenged City of Berkeley ordinance “place[d] strict rent controls
on all real property that [was] being rented or [was] available for rent for residential use
in whole or in part, . . . establish[ing] a base rent ceiling reflecting the rents in effect at
the end of May 1980.” 475 U.S. at 262 (quotation marks and citations omitted). A
landlord who did not “adhere to the maximum allowable rent set under the Ordinance
9 The intervenors suggest that the court ignore 324 Liquor. They argue that “324 Liquor was, in
all respects relevant to this motion, abrogated by” Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc.,
551 U.S. 877 (2007), because 324 Liquor “was decided at a time when resale price maintenance was still
deemed per se unlawful under the Sherman Act . . . .” Intervenors Reply at 2. Accepting the intervenors’
contention that “Leegin announced that a categorical rule of reason applied to all vertical restraints, and
expressly overturned Dr. Miles,” id. at 2, overturning Dr. Miles had no effect on the 324 Liquor court’s
determination that the provisions there qualified as hybrid restraints, see 324 Liquor, 479 U.S. at 345 n.8.
In the wake of the Court’s opinion in Fisher—which was less than one year old when 324 Liquor was
decided—the Supreme Court could not have held the New York provisions at issue in 324 Liquor were
inconsistent with the Sherman Act absent a conclusion that they constituted a hybrid restraint. See
Fisher, 475 U.S. at 267–68 (contrasting hybrid restraints with “unilateral action outside the purview of § 1”
of the Sherman Act).
16
[could] be fined by the [Rent Stabilization] Board, sued by his tenants, or have rent
legally withheld from him.” Id. at 262–63.
The Court distinguished the ordinance at issue in Fisher from the restraints it had
previously determined were hybrid in Schwegmann Brothers v. Calvert Distillers Corp.,
341 U.S. 384 (1951), and in California Retail Liquor Dealers Ass’n v. Midcal Aluminum,
Inc. (“Midcal”), 445 U.S. 97 (1980). Unlike the hybrid restraints in Schwegmann and
Midcal, Berkeley’s ordinance “place[d] complete control over maximum rent levels
exclusively in the hands of the Rent Stabilization Board. Not just the controls
themselves but also the rent ceilings they mandate[d] [had] been unilaterally imposed
on landlords by the city.” Fisher, 475 U.S. at 269.
By contrast, in 324 Liquor, the Supreme Court invalidated parts of New York’s
liquor pricing system, having determined that the challenged provisions constituted a
hybrid restraint. See Freedom Holdings I, 357 F.3d at 223–24 (discussing and
interpreting 324 Liquor). New York statutes required liquor wholesalers to “file, or ‘post,’
monthly price schedules with the State Liquor Authority,” in which the wholesalers
reported the bottle and case prices they would charge retailers. See 324 Liquor, 479
U.S. at 337–38. Retailers were not permitted to sell below “cost,” which was statutorily
defined by reference to the posted bottle price. See id. at 338–39. “Each wholesaler
[set] its own ‘posted’ prices; [New York did] not control month-to-month variations in
posted prices.” Id. at 345. In 324 Liquor, “[t]he only private acts involved were the
individual determinations of each wholesaler as to what bottle price to post.” See
Freedom Holdings I, 357 F.3d at 224.
17
The post and hold provisions at issue here are remarkably similar to the statutes
that the Supreme Court concluded constituted a hybrid restraint in 324 Liquor. The
Connecticut post and hold provisions, much like the New York statutes analyzed in 324
Liquor, require wholesalers to post their prices which, in turn, set lower bounds on the
prices to be charged by retailers. Unlike Berkeley’s involvement in the rent-stabilization
ordinance challenged in Fisher, Connecticut does not set the posted prices themselves,
but merely “police[s] the procedures of posting and the adherence to the posted
prices . . . which are left exclusively . . . within the control of the particular wholesaler.”
See Costco Wholesale Corp., 522 F.3d at 894 (citing Midcal, 445 U.S. at 105, and 324
Liquor, 479 U.S. at 345). The decision-making authority afforded to liquor wholesalers
by Connecticut’s post and hold provisions is more than sufficient for those provisions to
qualify as a hybrid restraint, in light of the hybrid restraint identified in 324 Liquor.
The trade associations and Total Wine disagree as to the relevance of the
Second Circuit’s decision in Battipaglia v. New York State Liquor Authority, 745 F.2d
166 (2d Cir. 1984), to the question of whether the post and hold provisions are a hybrid
restraint. On one hand, the trade associations claim that Battipaglia “analyzed New
York’s substantively identical post and hold statute as if the conduct at issue were
unilaterally mandated by state statute.” Trade Ass’ns Mem. in Supp. at 27. On the
other hand, Total Wine disputes this characterization of Battipaglia, emphasizing that it
was issued before 324 Liquor and that, “even applying pre-324 Liquor law, Battipaglia
effectively held that the post-and-hold statute at issue was hybrid, and not unilateral.”
Opp’n at 14 n.6 (citing Battipaglia, 745 F.2d at 172). Notably, the state defendants have
not argued that Battipaglia is relevant to the question of whether the challenged
18
provisions are hybrid or unilateral restraints. See generally State Defs. Mem. in Supp.
at 6–7.
Total Wine comes closer to the mark: Battipaglia is, indeed, of little relevance in
determining whether the post and hold provisions are a hybrid restraint. Judge
Friendly—writing for the panel majority in Battipaglia—did not have reason to address
the question directly, because the Supreme Court only adopted the unilateral and hybrid
restraint construct two years after Battipaglia, in Fisher. See Fisher, 475 U.S. at 267–68
(citing Rice v. Norman Williams Co., 458 U.S. 654, 665–66 & n.1 (1982) (Stevens, J.,
concurring in judgment)). As such, and contrary to the trade associations’ argument,
see Trade Ass’ns Mem in Supp. at 29, Battipaglia neither compels nor suggests a
conclusion that the post and hold statute is a unilateral restraint.
Given the similarity between the statutory scheme at issue in 324 Liquor and the
Connecticut post and hold provisions at issue here, the court concludes that the post
and hold provisions are best characterized as a hybrid restraint.
2.
Per Se Violation or Rule of Reason Analysis
Total Wine’s Complaint includes two counts. Count One alleges that the
“challenged provisions facilitate and impel horizontal price-fixing among Connecticut
wholesalers,” and are preempted by the Sherman Act. See Compl. ¶ 25–28. Count
Two alleges that “the challenged provisions facilitate and impel vertical price-fixing and
resale price maintenance among Connecticut manufacturers, wholesalers, and
retailers,” and thus are preempted by the Sherman Act. See id. ¶ 29–33. Total Wine
has made clear that these counts should be interpreted as they are most logically read:
to raise claims that “each of the three challenged provisions authorizes, mandates or
19
otherwise pressures industry participants to engage in horizontal price fixing (Count
One) and industry-wide vertical price fixing (Count Two) . . . .” Opp’n at 25 (second
emphasis added).
Determinations of whether alleged Sherman Act violations will receive per se
scrutiny or rule of reason analysis rely in large part on whether the challenged restraint
relates to horizontal or vertical price fixing. See Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v.
PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 888 (2007) (noting that Supreme Court has “rejected the
approach of reliance on rules governing horizontal restraints when defining rules
applicable to vertical ones”). In challenging the post and hold provisions as both
horizontal and vertical restraints, Total Wine has alleged that liquor wholesalers collude
with other wholesalers, on the one hand, and with manufacturers and retailers, on the
other. Therefore, the court will separately analyze Total Wine’s allegations that the post
and hold provisions mandate or authorize horizontal and vertical price fixing.
a.
Count One: Horizontal Price Fixing
The case law setting out the standard to be applied to Total Wine’s allegations
that the post and hold provisions mandate or authorize unlawful horizontal price fixing
appears to this court as less than clear. Although the Second Circuit’s ruling in
Battipaglia is directly on point, Total Wine urges this court to read 324 Liquor and
Freedom Holdings I as implicitly abrogating Battipaglia. See Opp’n at 26–29. That
invitation is not without some appeal. To determine whether Battipaglia remains good
law—and whether the post and hold provisions are subject to rule of reason analysis
under it, rather than a per se rule—a more detailed analysis of Battipaglia is necessary.
20
The post and hold provisions at issue in Battipaglia are substantively identical to
Connecticut’s post and hold provisions challenged in this case: liquor wholesalers had
to file price schedules for their sales to retailers to which they then had to adhere for a
month, although they were given an opportunity to amend their initial, posted prices to
meet lower prices filed by competing wholesalers. See Battipaglia, 745 F.2d at 168. In
the portion of the opinion relevant to this case, Judge Friendly, writing for a divided
panel, held that New York’s post and hold provisions were not in direct conflict with the
Sherman Act. See id. at 174–75. As noted above, see Part IV.A.1, supra, Judge
Friendly did not perform the now-required analysis—originally set out in Fisher, 475
U.S. at 267–68 (citing Rice v. Norman Williams Co., 458 U.S. 654, 665–66 & n.1 (1982)
(Stevens, J., concurring in judgment))—of whether the provisions were unilateral or
hybrid restraints. Instead, the court grounded its holding that the plaintiff “failed to make
out a case of facial invalidity” because New York’s post and hold provisions were
subject to rule of reason analysis, see Battipaglia, 745 F.2d at 174–75, in a
determination that is now the second step of the antitrust preemption analysis, see
supra Part III.B.
The Battipaglia court made clear several times in its opinion that it was aware of
the New York law’s requirements that wholesalers both post and hold to their
announced prices. See, e.g., id. at 175 (“[The New York statute] requires only that,
having announced a price independently chosen by him, the wholesaler should stay
with it for a month.”). The court assumed arguendo that “an exchange of price
information and price adherence compelled by a state are to be treated for the purpose
of antitrust preemption analysis, as if they were voluntary.” Id. at 174. It then concluded
21
that the rule of reason nevertheless provided the appropriate analytical framework. See
id. at 174. Curiously, in reaching its conclusion that the New York law was not a per se
violation of the Sherman Act, the court relied on cases that applied rule of reason
scrutiny to arrangements by which competitors only shared price information, rather
than grappling with the additional complexity stemming from the state’s requirement that
wholesalers hold their posted prices. See, e.g., id. at 174 (“The Supreme Court has
never held that the exchange of price information, in the language of Norman Williams,
‘necessarily constitutes a violation of the antitrust laws in all cases.’”).
In dissent, Judge Winter acknowledged that “arrangements that merely call for
the exchange of price information are subject to rule of reason, rather than per se,
analysis.” Id. at 179. However, he pointed out that, contrary to what one might believe
based on the relevant portion of the majority opinion, “the challenged legislation not only
mandates the exchange of price information but also requires adherence to publicly
announced prices until thirty days after notice is given of a new price.” Id. Agreements
to adhere to announced prices had “been uniformly held illegal without regard to [their]
reasonableness.” Id. (citing Sugar Inst. v. United States, 297 U.S. 553, 601 (1936)).
Indeed, other circuit courts to address this issue have agreed with Judge Winter. See
Costco Wholesale Corp., 522 F.3d at 895–896 (“The Supreme Court has held that an
agreement to adhere to posted prices is a per se violation without regard to its
reasonableness.” (citing, inter alia, Catalano, Inc. v. Target Sales, Inc., 446 U.S. 643,
649 (1980); Sugar Inst., 297 U.S. at 601)); TFWS I, 242 F.3d 198, 209 (4th Cir. 2001)
(“If liquor wholesalers entered into private agreements to accomplish what is required
(and allowed) under the Maryland scheme, a per se Sherman Act violation would
22
result. . . . Maryland’s post-and-hold regime is subject to § 1 as a hybrid restraint, and
we hold that it is illegal per se.”). Also in agreement is the leading antitrust treatise.
See 1 Phillip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 217b2 (4th ed. 2013)
(“Given the great danger that agreements to post and adhere will facilitate horizontal
collusion, the dissent’s position [in Battipaglia] is more consistent with [Supreme Court
precedent].”).
While this court might be inclined to agree with the analysis of Judge Winter, it is
ultimately bound by the Second Circuit’s holding in Battipaglia. It cannot distinguish the
statute in Battipaglia from the one at issue in this case in any meaningful way. This
court thus concludes that the post and hold provisions are subject to rule of reason
analysis, because Connecticut’s post and hold provisions are in all material respects
identical to those upheld by the Second Circuit in Battipaglia. They are therefore not
preempted by the Sherman Act.
Total Wine argues, as it must, that the legal foundations supporting Battipaglia
have been so eroded in the intervening years as to permit this court to reach a different
conclusion than did Judge Friendly, in writing for the majority in Battipaglia. See United
States v. Moore, 949 F.2d 68, 71 (2d Cir. 1991) (noting that “prior opinions of a panel of
[the Second Circuit] are binding upon [future panels] in the absence of a change in the
law by higher authority or . . . in banc proceeding[s] (or [their] equivalent) . . .”).
However, neither 324 Liquor nor Freedom Holdings I, both cited by Total Wine,
undermines Battipaglia’s holding in the ways Total Wine suggests.
First, 324 Liquor analyzed “a regime of resale price maintenance [imposed] on all
New York liquor retailers” as a vertical restraint. See 479 U.S. at 341–42. Indeed, the
23
Supreme Court’s references to the dangers of “[m]andatory industrywide resale price
fixing” are repeatedly contextualized by reference to the wholesaler–retailer relationship.
This language has little, if any, relevance to the question of whether Connecticut’s post
and hold provisions, when viewed as horizontal restraints, are per se violations of the
Sherman Act.10 Thus, 324 Liquor simply does not overrule Battipaglia’s determination
that post and hold provisions substantially identical to the ones at issue and analyzed as
horizontal restraints are subject to rule of reason scrutiny.
Nor does Freedom Holdings I implicitly abrogate Battipaglia. Total Wine insists
that framing the analysis as the court did in Freedom Holdings I—asking whether
“[e]ach of the three challenged statutes ‘contemplate[s]’ conduct that, ‘if done by private
agreement,’ would constitute horizontal price fixing”—provides adequate grounds for a
conclusion that the post and hold provisions should be considered per se violations of
the Sherman Act. See Opp’n at 26–29 (quoting Freedom Holdings I, 357 F.3d at 225).11
10 Total Wine suggests that the Ninth and Fourth Circuits have correctly understood 324 Liquor as
mandating a determination that post and hold provisions are horizontal restraints that constitute per se
violations of the Sherman Act. See Opp’n at 28–29. Whatever the relevance of 324 Liquor to other parts
of those courts’ decisions, neither opinion cited or referenced 324 Liquor in determining that post and hold
provisions are per se violations of the Sherman Act. See Costco Wholesale Corp., 522 F.3d at 895–96;
TFWS, Inc. v. Schaefer (“TFWS I”), 242 F.3d 198, 209–10 (4th Cir. 2001). As such, Total Wine’s
suggestion that 324 Liquor was relevant to these determinations rings hollow.
Total Wine is correct, however, that after Battipaglia, “the Supreme Court has made it clear that
an actual ‘contract, combination or conspiracy’ need not be shown for a state statute to be preempted by
the Sherman Act.” Freedom Holdings I, 357 F.3d 205, 223 n.17 (citing 324 Liquor, 479 U.S. at 345–46
n.8). Despite contrary suggestions from the defendants, see, e.g., State Defs. Mem. in Supp. at 12
(discussing Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 907 (2007)), subsequent
Supreme Court decisions do not undermine the Second Circuit’s interpretation of 324 Liquor in Freedom
Holdings I.
11
Relatedly, the state defendants contend that Total Wine was required to plead “enough factual
matter (taken as true) to suggest that an agreement was made,” in the wake of Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly,
550 U.S. 544 (2007). See State Defs. Mem. in Supp. at 14 (quoting Twombly, 550 U.S. at 556).
However, Twombly was not a preemption case; rather, it involved allegations of wholly private antitrust
violations, see Twombly, 550 U.S. at 550–51. As such, Twombly is of limited relevance, apart from its
elucidation of Rule 8’s pleading standard. Total Wine does not dispute that “plaintiffs [must] plausibly
plead, and prove, an actual agreement to fix or control prices” in antitrust cases related to private
24
However, this language in Freedom Holdings I does not undermine Battipaglia because
Judge Friendly assumed, without deciding, “that an exchange of price information and
price adherence compelled by the state are to be treated, for the purpose of antitrust
preemption analysis, as if they were voluntary,” i.e. by private agreement. 745 F.2d at
174 (emphasis added). Far from undermining Battipaglia, Freedom Holdings I is
consistent with it.
Thus, Battipaglia remains good law, insofar as the Second Circuit determined
that post and hold provisions, as horizontal restraints, are subject to rule of reason
analysis. Whether or not this court would reach a different conclusion if it were writing
on a blank slate is immaterial: Battipaglia constitutes binding precedent. In light of the
foregoing, the Complaint does not sufficiently allege that the post and hold provisions
are horizontal restraints preempted by the Sherman Act.
b.
Count Two: Vertical Price Fixing
Next, the court addresses Total Wine’s contention that the post and hold
provisions authorize or compel vertical price fixing in violation of the Sherman Act. See
Opp’n at 25 (“The Complaint alleged that each of the three challenged provisions
authorizes, mandates or otherwise pressures industry participants to engage in
horizontal price fixing (Count One) and industry-wide vertical price fixing (Count Two),
both of which are per se illegal.”). Notwithstanding Total Wine’s insistence that the post
and hold provisions can be interpreted as vertical restraints that are preempted by the
Sherman Act, nothing in the Complaint plausibly supports such a claim.
conduct. Opp’n at 21. Freedom Holdings I, by contrast, makes clear that no actual agreement needs to
be pleaded or shown for a plaintiff to succeed on a preemption claim. See 357 F.3d at 223 n.17.
25
Total Wine’s Opposition makes clear that the touchstone of Count Two is vertical
resale price maintenance. The cases to which Total Wine points the court relate to
statutory schemes or private claims much like the minimum retail price provisions. See,
e.g., Opp’n at 33 (citing and discussing 324 Liquor Corp. v. Duffy, 479 U.S. 335 (1987),
and Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877 (2007)).
Total Wine attempts to bridge the gap between the post and hold provisions—
most logically read as authorizing, if any, horizontal price-fixing—and the minimum retail
price provisions—most logically read as authorizing, if any, vertical price-fixing—when it
explains: “the minimum retail price provisions, especially in conjunction with the postand-hold regime, create irresistible pressure on retailers to collude ‘vertically’ with
wholesalers to decide what wholesalers should post as the minimum ‘bottle’ price in any
given month.” See Opp’n at 36. Even here, where Total Wine comes closest to
clarifying how the post and hold provisions might constitute a vertical restraint, its
arguments are grounded in the minimum retail price provisions. This makes perfect
sense, as the post and hold provisions by themselves contemplate no interaction
between actors at different tiers of Connecticut’s liquor market; the minimum retail price
provisions, by contrast, explicitly tie together the prices posted by wholesalers and
those charged by retailers.
Therefore, absent any plausible allegation that the post and hold provisions are
vertical restraints, the court need not evaluate whether this restraint is subject to rule of
reason analysis or is a per se violation of the Sherman Act. Insofar as Count Two
articulates a claim relating to the post and hold provisions, it is dismissed.
26
B.
Minimum Retail Price Provisions
Next, the court analyzes the minimum retail price provisions. Again, the court
concludes that Total Wine has plausibly alleged that they are a hybrid restraint, but not
that they are per se violations of the Sherman Act. As was the case with the post and
hold provisions, Total Wine’s claims challenging the minimum retail price provisions are
dismissed for failure to state a claim.
1.
Unilateral or Hybrid Restraint
The parties disagree as to whether the minimum retail price provisions qualify as
a unilateral or hybrid restraint. Compare State Defs. Mem. in Supp. at 5, and Trade
Ass’ns Mem. in Supp. at 25–26, and Brescome Mem. in Supp. at 13–15, with Opp’n at
16–17. To reiterate, unilateral restraints are “imposed by government . . . to the
exclusion of private control,” Freedom Holdings IV, 624 F.3d at 50 (quoting Fisher, 475
U.S. at 266), whereas hybrid restraints “grant[ ] private actors a degree of regulatory
control over competition,” id.
The court’s discussion above summarized Fisher, 475 U.S. 260 (1986), and 324
Liquor, 479 U.S. 335 (1987), in some detail. See supra Part IV.A.1. Though the court
does not repeat it here, that analysis informs the court’s efforts to answer the question
of whether the minimum retail price provisions are best characterized as a unilateral or
hybrid restraint. The Supreme Court’s decision in 324 Liquor is of particular importance,
as Connecticut’s minimum retail price provisions are remarkably similar to the New York
statute challenged in that case. The New York statute “impose[d] a regime of resale
price maintenance on all New York liquor retailers.” 324 Liquor, 479 U.S. at 341.
Connecticut’s liquor retailers are similarly bound by the bottle prices posted by
27
wholesalers. See Conn. Gen. Stat. § 30-68m(a)(1) (defining “cost” in part by reference
to “bottle price”).12 There is no reason to believe that the portion of 324 Liquor
classifying New York’s statute as a hybrid restraint, see 479 U.S. at 345 n.8, is no
longer good law, even though its holding that the statute authorized per se violations of
the Sherman Act has been overruled, see infra Part IV.B.2.b.
Nor do the cases cited by the trade associations compel a contrary
determination. See Trade Ass’ns Mem. in Supp. at 26–27. In Serlin Wine & Spirit
Merchants, Inc. v. Healy, 512 F. Supp. 946 (D. Conn. 1981), the court had no occasion
to opine on whether the challenged liquor pricing scheme was a unilateral or hybrid
restraint, because its ruling preceded both Fisher and 324 Liquor. Those two cases—
which are, of course, binding on this court—significantly altered the analytical
framework courts apply when addressing Sherman Act preemption claims. Next, the
Seventh Circuit’s opinion in Flying J, Inc. v. Van Hollen, 621 F.3d 658 (7th Cir. 2010),
explicitly distinguished the challenged motor vehicle fuel minimum markup from the
liquor minimum markup ruled invalid in 324 Liquor. The Seventh Circuit pointed out
that, “[a]lthough New York’s scheme [in 324 Liquor] involved a minimum markup just
12 The intervenors contend that Connecticut’s Liquor Control Act is not “functionally identical” to
the New York scheme analyzed in 324 Liquor, because the latter “allowed wholesalers to manipulate
bottle prices untethered to any case prices, effectively controlling resale prices for the same month.” See
Intervenors Reply at 4 n.3. The portion of 324 Liquor that the intervenors cite for this proposition, see id.
(citing 324 Liquor, 479 U.S. at 341), offers no support for their characterization of the scheme at issue in
324 Liquor. Indeed, it appears that New York’s scheme did tether bottle prices to case prices, at least to
some extent, see 324 Liquor Corp., 479 U.S. at 338 (“The [New York State Liquor Authority], however,
has promulgated a rule stating that for cases containing 48 or fewer bottles, the posted bottle price
multiplied by the number of bottles in a case must exceed the posted case price by a ‘breakage’
surcharge of $1.92.” (citations omitted)), much like Connecticut’s Liquor Control Act does, see Conn.
Gen. Stat. § 30-68m(a)(3) (computing bottle price by adding “an amount that is not less than” a statutory
minimum, to quotient determined by dividing case price by number of units or bottles). Therefore, to
suggest that Connecticut’s statutory regime meaningfully differs from New York’s scheme analyzed in 324
Liquor on the grounds that bottle prices in Connecticut are tethered to case price is not helpful.
28
like Wisconsin requires for motor vehicle fuel, the unique nature of New York’s scheme
authorized wholesalers to manipulate the prices to which the markup was applied.”
Flying J, 621 F.3d at 665 (citing 324 Liquor, 479 U.S. at 348–50); see also id. at 666
(“The great vice of the New York scheme was . . . that the wholesalers could sell to the
retailers at one price and force the retailers to apply the minimum markup to another.”
(citing 324 Liquor, 479 U.S. at 345 n.6)). Clearly then, the Seventh Circuit’s opinion in
Flying J cannot be read to support a determination that Connecticut’s minimum retail
price provisions—which share the same “great vice” as New York’s scheme—are a
unilateral restraint.13
Because 324 Liquor determined that a very similar statute was a hybrid restraint,
the court concludes that Connecticut’s minimum retail price provisions also constitute a
hybrid restraint.
2.
Per Se Violation or Rule of Reason Analysis
Having determined that the minimum retail price provisions are a hybrid restraint,
the court must next determine whether they authorize or compel per se violations of the
Sherman Act or instead qualify for rule of reason analysis. The court will again address
Total Wine’s claims that the minimum retail price provisions authorize or compel
impermissible horizontal and vertical price fixing. See Opp’n at 25.
13
The final case cited by the trade associations—Little Rock School District v. Borden, Inc.,
No. LR-76-C-41, 1980 WL 1882 (E.D. Ark. Aug. 5, 1980)—is easily distinguished. First, as was the case
with Serlin, the court’s opinion in Little Rock School District preceded both Fisher and 324 Liquor.
Second, like the markup scheme upheld in Flying J, the markup challenged in Little Rock School District
did not allow “wholesalers [to] sell to the retailers at one price and force the retailers to apply the minimum
markup to another,” Flying J, 621 F.3d at 666. See Little Rock Sch. Dist., 1980 WL 1882, at *1 (“[The]
Arkansas statute establishe[d] that it is a criminal violation to price milk at less than cost plus four per
cent.” (citation omitted)).
29
a.
Count One: Horizontal Price Fixing
Total Wine’s Complaint alleges that the minimum retail price provisions “facilitate
and impel horizontal price-fixing among Connecticut wholesalers and are hybrid, per se
restraints of trade.” See Compl. ¶ 26. Yet, as was the case with Total Wine’s
allegations that the post and hold provisions authorized or mandated vertical price
fixing, see supra Part IV.A.2.b, Total Wine has not plausibly alleged that the minimum
retail price provisions authorize or mandate horizontal price fixing.
The bulk of Total Wine’s response to arguments for dismissal of the horizontal
price fixing claim focuses, quite logically, on the post and hold provisions. There is
comparatively little discussion of the minimum retail price provisions. See generally
Opp’n at 25–32. Total Wine has not plausibly alleged that the minimum retail price
provisions authorize or mandate any horizontal activity among wholesalers. The closest
Total Wine comes to putting forth an explanation for its horizontal price fixing claim
regarding the minimum retail price provisions is its argument that “it would be per se
illegal for alcohol wholesalers in Connecticut to privately agree (a) to collectively set the
prices, each month, at which they would sell their products to retailers, and then hold
(i.e. fix) those prices, and not compete on price, for a full month; (b) to also collectively
set and hold minimum retail prices for those products and (c) to refuse to afford volumebased discounts to any retailers.” See id. at 26–27 (final emphasis added). It is clear
that Total Wine’s horizontal price fixing claim is grounded in the requirement that
wholesalers “set and hold . . . prices,” rather than the requirement that retailers refrain
from selling their products below their statutorily defined “cost.”
30
The minimum retail price provisions dictate the relationship between the prices
set by wholesalers and retailers, but clearly do not mandate or authorize any horizontal
activity by wholesalers. Total Wine’s dogged claims to the contrary are unavailing: it
has not plausibly alleged that the minimum retail price provisions mandate or authorize
horizontal price fixing of any kind. As such, the court grants the defendants’ and
intervenors’ Motions to Dismiss Count One, insofar as that count challenges the
minimum retail price provisions.
b.
Count Two: Vertical Price Fixing
Next, the court turns to Total Wine’s claim that the minimum retail price
provisions mandate or authorize vertical price fixing among manufacturers, wholesalers,
and retailers. See Compl. ¶¶ 29–33.14 The defendants and intervenors argue that the
Supreme Court’s opinion in Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551
U.S. 877 (2007), mandates that this court apply rule of reason analysis to the
challenged, vertical restraints. See, e.g., State Defs. Reply at 5–6; Intervenors Reply
at 2–4, 9–10. Total Wine retorts that 324 Liquor—which held that similar arrangements
were per se violations of the Sherman Act—remains good law, as Leegin did not
overturn 324 Liquor and thus does not govern the court’s determination in this case.
See Opp’n at 33–37.
In Leegin, the Supreme Court held that its opinion in “Dr. Miles [Medical Co. v.
John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.S. 373 (1911)] should be overruled and that vertical
14 Notwithstanding Total Wine’s references to manufacturers in Count Two, the minimum retail
price provisions operate only in the context of the relationships between wholesalers—who set the bottle
price—and retailers—who are not permitted to sell below “cost.” See Conn. Gen. Stat. §§ 30-68m(a)(1),
30-68m(a)(3), 30-68(b).
31
price restraints are to be judged by the rule of reason.” 551 U.S. at 882. For nearly a
century, Dr. Miles had mandated that resale price maintenance agreements were per se
illegal, rather than subject to rule of reason analysis. See id. In overturning Dr. Miles,
the Supreme Court remarked that “it cannot be stated with any degree of confidence
that resale price maintenance ‘always or almost always tend[s] to restrict competition
and decrease output.’” Id. at 894 (quoting Bus. Elecs. Corp. v. Sharp Elecs. Corp., 485
U.S. 717, 723 (1988)). Moreover, “[t]he Court’s treatment of vertical restraints has
progressed away from Dr. Miles’ strict approach . . . [and] from the opinion’s rationales.”
Id. at 900. The Supreme Court concluded with the broad pronouncement that “the
Court’s decision in Dr. Miles . . . is now overruled. Vertical price restraints are to be
judged according to the rule of reason.” Id. at 907.
Despite this lack of equivocation in the Court’s Leegin opinion, Total Wine
suggests that 324 Liquor still mandates a conclusion that the minimum retail price
provisions are per se unlawful. See Opp’n at 33. Total Wine’s attempts to buttress this
argument are unpersuasive.
First, Total Wine believes that, because Leegin did not specifically mention 324
Liquor, 324 Liquor remains good law. See id. (“Nowhere in Leegin did the Supreme
Court suggest it was overruling 324 Liquor.”). This justification for continuing to apply
324 Liquor is entirely unconvincing. Leegin repeatedly made clear that it overruled Dr.
Miles. See, e.g., 551 U.S. at 882, 900, 902, 907. Though the Supreme Court did not
explicitly note all of its prior decisions that relied on Dr. Miles—and explicitly note that
those decisions were also overruled, insofar as they relied on Dr. Miles—it is absolutely
clear that such holdings are no longer good law. 324 Liquor explicitly relied on Dr.
32
Miles, among other cases, as support for its starting premise that “[r]esale price
maintenance [had] been a per se violation of § 1 of the Sherman Act ‘since the early
years of national antitrust enforcement.’” 324 Liquor, 479 U.S. at 341 (quoting
Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Svc. Corp., 465 U.S. 752, 761 (1984)) (citing Dr. Miles, 220
U.S. at 404–09). This now-overruled premise was essential to the 324 Liquor Court’s
conclusion that the New York statute it analyzed was per se illegal. See id. at 342–43
(discussing Cal. Retail Liquor Dealers Ass’n v. Midcal Aluminum, Inc., 445 U.S. 97
(1980), which invalidated a California statute because “it mandated resale price
maintenance, an activity that has long been regarded as a per se violation of the
Sherman Act” (quoting Rice v. Norman Williams Co., 458 U.S. 654, 659–60 (1982))).
Therefore, 324 Liquor does not bind this court to a determination that vertical resale
price maintenance schemes are per se illegal.
Second, Total Wine asserts that Leegin is inapposite because “the leather
manufacturer in Leegin was the only company at its ‘tier’ in the market that was a party
to the price maintenance agreement. The agreement was purely vertical; there was not
even a theoretical risk of horizontal collusion.” Opp’n at 33. This attempt to distinguish
324 Liquor from Leegin is, again, unconvincing.
Total Wine attempts to carve out exceptions to Leegin’s holding that “[v]ertical
price restraints are to be judged according to the rule of reason,” see 551 U.S. at 907,
for “industry-wide restraints” and for restraints with “both vertical and horizontal
components,” see Opp’n at 33–34. However, neither carve out has any basis in Leegin.
Whatever the force of 324 Liquor’s logic regarding the economic impact of “[m]andatory
industrywide resale price fixing,” see Opp’n at 34 (quoting 324 Liquor, 479 U.S. at 341–
33
42), Leegin makes clear that 324 Liquor’s reliance on the holding in Dr. Miles—that
vertical price restraints are per se illegal—is no longer valid. Similarly, in the portion of
Leegin that Total Wine interprets as “[taking] pains to identify several facts that were not
present” in Leegin, see Opp’n at 35 (citing Leegin, 551 U.S. at 897–98), the Court was
simply identifying factors for lower courts to consider when they undertook the rule of
reason analysis that the Court mandated in that case, see Leegin, 551 U.S. at 897 (“If
the rule of reason were to apply to vertical price restraints, courts would have to be
diligent in eliminating their anticompetitive uses from the market. This is a realistic
objective, and certain factors are relevant to the inquiry.”). There is thus no suggestion
in Leegin that the Supreme Court’s broad pronouncements should be limited to the facts
of the case, or that this court should not apply rule of reason analysis to the minimum
retail price provisions at issue here.
Nor do the lower court cases cited by Total Wine offer support for its contention
that the minimum retail price provisions are per se unlawful. For example, the Seventh
Circuit’s opinion in Toys “R” Us v. Federal Trade Commission, 221 F.3d 928 (7th Cir.
2000), issued seven years before Leegin, actually undermines Total Wine’s invitation to
distinguish “vertical price fixing that also involves horizontal collusion [as] fundamentally
different from the type of agreement at issue in Leegin,” see Opp’n at 35. In Toys “R”
Us, the court’s very first words noted that “antitrust laws . . . have long drawn a sharp
distinction between contractual restrictions that occur up and down a distribution
chain—so-called vertical restraints—and restrictions that come about as a result of
agreements among competitors, or horizontal restraints.” 221 F.3d at 930. Despite the
fact that “[t]he agreements took the form of a network of vertical agreements between
34
TRU and the individual manufacturers,” see id., the Seventh Circuit ultimately affirmed
the FTC’s conclusion “that the essence of the agreement network TRU supervised was
horizontal,” see id. at 936. Thus, the Seventh Circuit’s conclusion did not rest on a
classification of the vertical restraints as “inextricably tied” to the horizontal restraints.
See Opp’n at 36. Rather, the Seventh Circuit fit the conspiracy in Toys “R” Us—which
had both vertical and horizontal elements—into just one of those two categories: having
determined that their “essence . . . was horizontal,” the court then applied per se
scrutiny to the arrangements. See Toys “R” Us, 221 F.3d at 936.15
Here, the court—much like the Toys “R” Us court—has classified the minimum
retail price provisions as just one of the two types of restraints. The court determined
that the Complaint did not plausibly allege that the minimum retail price provisions
mandated or authorized horizontal price fixing, but rather that the provisions could be
challenged regarding their vertical characteristics. See supra Parts IV.B.2.a & IV.B.2.b.
However, in the wake of Leegin, these types of vertical restraints are subject to rule of
reason scrutiny, see Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc., 551 U.S. at 907, and thus are
not preempted. Therefore, Total Wine’s Complaint fails to state a claim of vertical price
fixing, with respect to the minimum retail price provisions. Insofar as Count Two
challenges the minimum retail price provisions, it is dismissed.
15 Similarly, though the conspiracy in United States v. Apple Inc., 952 F. Supp. 2d 638
(S.D.N.Y. 2013), had horizontal and vertical elements, the primary issue was the manner in which the
“vertical actor [was] alleged to have participated in an unlawful horizontal agreement.” See 952 F. Supp.
2d at 690–91 (emphasis added).
35
C.
Price Discrimination Prohibition
Finally, the court addresses the lawfulness of the price discrimination prohibition
challenged by Total Wine. The price discrimination prohibition mandates that
wholesalers sell a given product to all retailers at the same price. See Conn. Gen. Stat.
§ 30-68k. As described in the following discussion, the court concludes: (1) that Total
Wine has not plausibly alleged that the price discrimination prohibition is a hybrid
restraint, but is instead a unilateral restraint outside the scope of the Sherman Act; and
(2) having determined that the price discrimination prohibition is a unilateral restraint,
the court need not undertake the inquiry of whether it is per se illegal or would be
subject to rule of reason analysis.
As was the case with each of the previously discussed provisions, the parties
dispute whether the price discrimination prohibition is a unilateral or hybrid restraint.
Compare State Defs. Mem. in Supp. at 4–5, and Trade Ass’ns Mem. in Supp. at 25–26,
and Brecome Mem. in Supp. at 13–15, with Opp’n at 17–19. The court will not repeat
its analysis of the framework governing this question. See supra Part IV.A.1. That
discussion is incorporated here by reference. Briefly, however, the relevant case law
provides that unilateral restraints are those “imposed by government . . . to the
exclusion of private control,” Freedom Holdings IV, 624 F.3d at 50 (quoting Fisher, 475
U.S. at 266), while hybrid restraints “grant[ ] private actors a degree of regulatory control
over competition,” id.
Again, the court believes this question is best approached by using the Supreme
Court’s decisions in Fisher v. City of Berkeley, California, 475 U.S. 260 (1986), and 324
Liquor Corp. v. Duffy, 479 U.S. 335 (1987), as guideposts. Unlike the post and hold
36
provisions and the minimum retail price provisions, the price discrimination prohibition is
more like the restraint at issue in Fisher than the one analyzed in 324 Liquor. The city
ordinance upheld in Fisher set a ceiling, capping the rents that residential landlords
could charge. See 475 U.S. at 262. The court noted that Berkeley’s ordinance
“place[d] complete control over maximum rent levels exclusively in the hands of the
Rent Stabilization Board. Not just the controls themselves but also the rent ceilings they
mandate[d] [had] been unilaterally imposed on landlords by the city.” Fisher, 475 U.S.
at 269. By contrast, in 324 Liquor, wholesalers were obligated by statute to post their
own monthly price schedules, but New York did not monitor or regulate those posted
prices. See 324 Liquor, 479 U.S. at 345.
Here, the price discrimination prohibition does not “grant[ ] private actors a
degree of regulatory control over competition,” such that the prohibition is a hybrid
restraint. See Freedom Holdings IV, 624 F.3d at 50 (citing, inter alia, 324 Liquor, 479
U.S. at 345–46 & n.8). Instead, Connecticut simply prohibits liquor wholesalers from
charging different prices to different retailers. Although wholesalers may choose what
price they will charge all retailers, they are prohibited from charging different prices.
Total Wine is incorrect that the price discrimination prohibition is a hybrid
restraint, let alone “a quintessential hybrid restraint.” Opp’n at 17. In support of this
contention, Total Wine first claims that, “[t]o constitute a unilateral restraint, a statute
must lodge exclusive authority to set prices with public officials.” Opp’n at 17–18 (citing
Midcal, 445 U.S. at 105–06).16 This statement is squarely at odds with Fisher, where
16
The section of Midcal to which Total Wine cites offers no support for its assertion: Total Wine
points the court to a section of the decision discussing Parker immunity, not the distinction between
unilateral and hybrid restraints. See Midcal, 445 U.S. at 105–06.
37
the city ordinance bestowed on local officials the authority to set a ceiling on rents to be
charged, but certainly did not lodge exclusive authority to set prices with them. See
Fisher, 475 U.S. at 262–63.
The Fourth Circuit’s view that a similar price discrimination prohibition was
inseparable from Maryland’s post and hold provisions is also unpersuasive. See Opp’n
at 18 (quoting TFWS, Inc. v. Schaefer (“TFWS I”), 242 F.3d 198, 209 (4th Cir. 2001);
TFWS, Inc. v. Franchot (“TFWS II”), 572 F.3d 186, 193 (4th Cir. 2009)). Maryland
apparently did not raise the issue of severance in its initial appeal. See TFWS II, 572
F.3d at 193. That being the case, the Fourth Circuit was bound in the later appeal by its
conclusion in the first appeal that the price discrimination prohibition was so wrapped up
in the hybrid post and hold provisions as to also be a hybrid restraint. See id. at 193–94
(“Maryland presents its argument for severance of its volume discount ban as though for
review in the first instance, and does not attempt to meet the high burden of showing
that our holding in TFWS I was clearly erroneous and would work a manifest injustice.”).
By contrast, the state defendants here have raised the issue of severability in briefing
their Motion to Dismiss. See State Defs. Reply at 3–4 (“[A] court must look at each
specific state law separately . . . .”).
As the state defendants point out, the challenged provisions “act separately and
address different conduct.” See State Defs. Reply at 4. The fact that the challenged
provisions are all related does not mandate a conclusion that, having determined that
two of them are hybrid restraints, the third is as well. In Costco Wholesale Corp., the
Ninth Circuit was unpersuaded that other challenged provisions of Washington’s liquor
regulations needed to “be considered part-and-parcel of the posting scheme . . . .” 522
38
F.3d at 897–98. Indeed, relying in part on principles of severability, the court
determined that the Washington provisions analogous to Connecticut’s price
discrimination prohibition were a unilateral restraint. See id. at 898–99.17
Ultimately, the fact that the challenged provisions govern related aspects of the
liquor market does not render them analytically inseparable. Analyzing the price
discrimination prohibition on its own, the court concludes that Total Wine has not
plausibly alleged that the prohibition is a hybrid rather than a unilateral restraint. That
being the case, it need not proceed to the second step of the preemption analysis and
decide whether the restraint is a per se violation of the Sherman Act: because the price
discrimination prohibition is a unilateral restraint, it is entirely outside the scope of the
Sherman Act. See supra Part III.B. Therefore, the state defendants’ and intervenors’
Motions to Dismiss Total Wine’s challenge to the price discrimination prohibition are
granted.
V.
CONCLUSION
For the reasons set forth above, the Motions to Dismiss (Doc. Nos. 38, 66, 80)
are GRANTED. Total Wine’s challenges to the post and hold provisions and minimum
retail price provisions are dismissed, because these provisions constitute hybrid
restraints that receive rule of reason scrutiny and therefore cannot be preempted. Total
Wine’s claim that the price discrimination prohibition is preempted is also dismissed,
because that provision is a unilateral restraint outside the scope of the Sherman Act.
17 Admittedly, the Ninth Circuit’s analysis relied in part on its conclusion that the post and hold
provisions were preempted by the Sherman Act. See Costco Wholesale Corp., 522 F.3d at 898. Most
relevantly here, however, the Ninth Circuit did not view the challenged restraints as impossible to
separate from one another, as Total Wine suggests the court should consider the challenged provisions
in this case.
39
SO ORDERED.
Dated at New Haven, Connecticut this 6th day of June, 2017.
_/s/ Janet C. Hall_________
Janet C. Hall
United States District Judge
40
Disclaimer: Justia Dockets & Filings provides public litigation records from the federal appellate and district courts. These filings and docket sheets should not be considered findings of fact or liability, nor do they necessarily reflect the view of Justia.
Why Is My Information Online?