AARP v. UNITED STATES EQUAL EMPLOYMENT OPPORTUNITY COMMISSION
Filing
47
MEMORANDUM AND OPINION denying 31 the government's motion to dismiss/motion for summary judgment, granting 35 plaintiff's cross-motion for summary judgment, and granting 29 and 32 the motions to file [29-2] under seal. See text for details. Signed by Judge John D. Bates on 8/22/17. (lcjdb2)
UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA
AARP,
Plaintiff,
v.
Civil Action No. 16-2113 (JDB)
UNITED STATES EQUAL
EMPLOYMENT OPPORTUNITY
COMMISSION,
Defendant.
MEMORANDUM OPINION
This case concerns AARP’s Administrative Procedure Act (APA) challenge to two
regulations promulgated by the U.S. Equal Employment Opportunity Commission (EEOC) related
to incentives and employer-sponsored wellness programs. See Regulations Under the Americans
with Disabilities Act (“the ADA rule”), 81 Fed. Reg. 31,126 (May 17, 2016); Regulations Under
the Genetic Information Nondiscrimination Act (“the GINA rule”), 81 Fed. Reg. 31,143 (May 17,
2016). In December 2016, this Court denied AARP’s motion for a preliminary injunction to stay
applicability of the rules, and the new regulations became applicable on January 1, 2017. See
generally AARP v. EEOC, 226 F. Supp. 3d 7 (D.D.C. 2016) (AARP I). EEOC has now filed [31]
a motion to dismiss/motion for summary judgment, and AARP has filed [35] a cross-motion for
summary judgment. For the reasons that follow, EEOC’s motion to dismiss/motion for summary
judgment will be denied, and AARP’s motion for summary judgment will be granted. 1
1
There are also two outstanding motions to seal in this case, which will likewise be granted. See ECF Nos.
29, 32. EEOC has moved to file its motion for summary judgment under seal because it identifies Declarant A’s
employer, and AARP’s original member declarations were sealed at an earlier stage of this case to protect the
declarants’ identities and personal medical information. Although originally opposed to the need for sealing, EEOC
1
I. BACKGROUND
This case deals with the incentives—financial or otherwise—that may be offered to
employees in connection with employer-sponsored wellness programs, which have become
popular in many work places in the last several years as a means of promoting employee health
and reducing healthcare costs. The central issue here results from the tension that exists between
the laudable goals behind such wellness programs, and the equally important interests promoted
by the Americans with Disabilities Act (ADA) and the Genetic Information Nondiscrimination
Act (GINA). EEOC is tasked with reconciling these competing concerns, and this case arises out
of its most recent attempt to do so.
In its previous opinion, the Court discussed at length the complex regulatory and statutory
framework that governs this case; thus, a shorter review will suffice here. See AARP I, 226 F.
Supp. 3d at 11–15. Wellness programs are regulated in part by the Health Insurance Portability
and Accountability Act (HIPAA), as amended by the Affordable Care Act (ACA), as well as by
HIPAA’s implementing regulations.
HIPAA prevents health plans and insurers from
discriminating on the basis of “any health status related factor,” but allows covered entities to offer
“premium discounts or rebates” on a plan participant’s copayments or deductibles in return for that
individual’s compliance with a wellness program. See 29 U.S.C. § 1182(b)(2)(B); 26 U.S.C. §
9802(b); 42 U.S.C. § 300gg-4(b). A “reward” or incentive may include a discount on insurance
costs or a penalty that increases the plan participant’s costs because of non-participation in the
wellness program. See 26 C.F.R. § 54.9802-1(f)(1)(i). The ACA’s amendments to HIPAA, and
the accompanying implementing regulations, allow plans and insurers to offer incentives of up to
has filed a public version of its brief with a small redaction, to which the Court cites in this opinion. See ECF No. 31.
The Court does not discuss any information in this opinion that would disclose the identity of either the declarants or
Declarant A’s employer.
2
30% of the cost of coverage in exchange for an employee’s participation in a health-contingent
wellness program, a kind of wellness program in which the reward is based on an insured
individual’s satisfaction of a particular health-related factor. See Incentives for Nondiscriminatory
Wellness Programs in Group Health Plans (“the 2013 HIPAA regulations” or “2013 HIPAA rule”),
78 Fed. Reg. 33,158, 33,180. Neither the ACA nor the 2013 HIPAA regulations impose a cap on
incentives that may be offered in connection with participatory wellness programs, which are
programs that do not condition receipt of the incentive on satisfaction of a health factor. Id. at
33,167.
However, because employer-sponsored wellness programs often involve the collection of
sensitive medical information from employees, including information about disabilities or genetic
information, these programs often implicate the ADA and GINA as well. As both the ADA and
GINA are administered by EEOC, this brings wellness programs within EEOC’s purview. The
ADA prohibits employers from requiring medical examinations or inquiring whether an individual
has a disability unless the inquiry is both job-related and “consistent with business necessity.” 42
U.S.C. § 12112(d)(4)(A). But the ADA makes some allowances for wellness programs: it provides
that an employer may conduct medical examinations and collect employee medical history as part
of an “employee health program,” as long as the employee’s participation in the program is
“voluntary”. Id. § 12112(d)(4)(B). The term “voluntary” is not defined in the statute. Similarly,
GINA prohibits employers from requesting, requiring, or purchasing “genetic information” from
employees or their family members. Id. § 2000ff-1(b). The definition of genetic information
includes an individual’s genetic tests, the genetic tests of family members such as children and
spouses, and the manifestation of a disease or disorder of a family member. See id. § 2000ff(4)(A).
Like the ADA, GINA contains an exception that permits employers to collect this information as
3
part of a wellness program, as long as the employee’s provision of the information is voluntary.
Id. §§ 2000ff-1(b)(2)(A)–(B). Again, the meaning of “voluntary” is not defined in the statute.
Thus, while HIPAA and its implementing regulations expressly permit the use of incentives
in wellness programs, uncertainty existed as to whether the “voluntary” provisions of the ADA
and GINA permit the use of incentives in those wellness programs that implicate ADA- or GINAprotected information. EEOC previously took the position that in order for a wellness program to
be “voluntary,” employers could not condition the receipt of incentives on the employee’s
disclosure of ADA- or GINA-protected information. See EEOC Enforcement Guidance on
Disability-Related Inquiries and Medical Examinations, No. 915.002 (July 27, 2000), 2000 WL
33407181, at *16–17; Regulations Under the Genetic Information Nondiscrimination Act of 2008
(“the 2010 GINA rule”), 75 Fed. Reg. 68,912, 68,935 (Nov. 9, 2010), codified at 29 C.F.R. § 1635.
However, in 2016 EEOC promulgated new rules reversing this position. Those are the rules at
issue in this case. The new ADA rule provides that the use of a penalty or incentive of up to 30%
of the cost of self-only coverage will not render “involuntary” a wellness program that seeks the
disclosure of ADA-protected information. See ADA Rule, 81 Fed. Reg. at 31,133–34. Likewise,
the new GINA rule permits employers to offer incentives of up to 30% of the cost of self-only
coverage for disclosure of information, pursuant to a wellness program, about a spouse’s
manifestation of disease or disorder, which, as noted above, falls within the definition of the
employee’s “genetic information” under GINA. 2 See GINA Rule, 81 Fed. Reg. at 31,144. Unlike
the 2013 HIPAA regulations, which place caps on incentives only in health-contingent wellness
programs, the incentive limits in the new GINA and ADA rules apply both to participatory and
health-contingent wellness programs.
2
The rule does not permit employers to collect this information from the employee or the employee’s
children, only from the employee’s spouse.
4
AARP filed this suit on behalf of its members in October 2016, challenging both rules
under the APA, 5 U.S.C. §§ 702–06. AARP argues principally that the 30% incentives permitted
by the new rules are inconsistent with the “voluntary” requirements of the ADA and GINA, and
that employees who cannot afford to pay a 30% increase in premiums will be forced to disclose
their protected information when they otherwise would choose not to do so. AARP sought a
preliminary injunction, which the Court denied, finding that AARP had associational standing, but
that it had not at that stage shown either irreparable harm or a likelihood of success on the merits.
See AARP I, 226 F. Supp. 3d at 15, 20–26. Because of the short timeline on which the motion for
a preliminary injunction was briefed and decided, the administrative record was not then available
for the Court’s review. The administrative record has now been produced, EEOC has now moved
to dismiss for lack of jurisdiction, and both parties have also moved for summary judgment.
II. DISCUSSION
EEOC asks the Court to revisit its ruling regarding AARP’s standing, again challenging
AARP’s status as a membership organization, and arguing that Declarant A, the member-declarant
on whom the Court relied in finding that AARP had standing at the preliminary injunction stage,
lacks standing based on new factual information that was not previously available. See Gov’t Mot.
for Summ. J. [ECF No. 31] at 10–15. EEOC also argues that the new rules survive the deferential
standard of review afforded agency decisions in APA cases, and therefore asks for summary
judgment in its favor. See, e.g., id. at 15. AARP counters that the incentives allowed by the new
rules are inconsistent with the meaning of “voluntary” as used in the statutes, and that EEOC failed
to adequately explain its departure from its previous position on incentives. See Pl.’s Mot. for
Summ. J. [ECF No. 35-1] at 1, 24, 39. The Court will address each issue in turn.
A. STANDING
5
EEOC has filed a motion to dismiss for lack of jurisdiction under Federal Rule of Civil
Procedure 12(b)(1), arguing that AARP has not sufficiently established that it has associational
standing to bring suit on behalf of its members in this case. A plaintiff “bears the burden of
showing that he has standing for each type of relief sought.” Summers v. Earth Island Inst., 555
U.S. 488, 493 (2009). A lack of standing constitutes “a defect in [the Court’s] subject matter
jurisdiction.” Haase v. Sessions, 835 F.2d 902, 906 (D.C. Cir. 1987). In evaluating a motion to
dismiss under Rule 12(b)(1), a court must take as true all factual allegations in the complaint. See,
e.g., Jerome Stevens Pharm., Inc. v. Food & Drug Admin., 402 F.3d 1249, 1253–54 (D.C. Cir.
2005). However, in considering jurisdiction, the court “may also consider matters outside the
pleadings, and may rest its decision on its own resolution of disputed facts.” Advance Am. v. Fed.
Deposit Ins. Corp., —F. Supp. 3d—, 2017 WL 2869918, at *2 (D.D.C. July 5, 2017) (citing
Herbert v. Nat’l Acad. of Sci., 974 F.2d 192, 197 (D.C. Cir. 1992)).
In order to successfully assert associational standing, AARP must show that: (1) at least
one of its members would have standing to sue in his or her own right; (2) the interests it seeks to
protect are germane to its purpose; and (3) neither the claim asserted nor the relief requested
requires the participation of an individual member of the organization in the suit. Hunt v. Wash.
State Apple Advert. Comm’n, 432 U.S. 333, 342–43 (1977). As noted above, the Court found in
its previous opinion that AARP has standing to bring this suit. See AARP I, 226 F. Supp. 3d at
16–20. However, EEOC asks the Court to revisit its finding that AARP is a “membership
organization” that may assert associational standing, and also raises arguments based on new
information about Declarant A that it claims undermines Declarant A’s standing. See Gov’t Mot.
for Summ. J. at 10–15. The Court will accordingly revisit these issues.
1. Membership organization
6
EEOC contends that AARP does not have “members” on whose behalf it can assert
associational standing. The Court analyzed this issue at length in its previous opinion, and
observed that the associational standing caselaw is unclear as to what, exactly, constitutes a
“membership” organization. AARP I, 226 F. Supp. 3d at 16. In Hunt, the Supreme Court
identified several criteria that should be used to determine whether a non-membership organization
sufficiently represents its constituents’ interests to be able to bring suit on their behalf. These
“indicia of membership” are: whether the members play a role in selecting the organization’s
leadership, guiding the organization’s activities, and financing the organization’s activities. Hunt,
432 U.S. at 344–45. Some courts have held that these criteria do not apply to “traditional”
membership organizations, but no court has precisely defined what that means. See, e.g., Brady
Campaign to Prevent Gun Violence v. Salazar, 612 F. Supp. 2d 1, 29 (D.D.C. 2009) (“The inquiry
into indicia of membership . . . is necessary only when an organization is not a “traditional
membership organization.” (internal quotation marks omitted)). The Court therefore assumed in
its previous opinion that the Hunt indicia of membership criteria applied here and found that AARP
satisfies these indicia of membership. EEOC challenges this finding, but presents no new facts or
law that would call the Court’s previous decision into question. See Gov’t Mot. for Summ. J. at
10–13.
EEOC argues first that AARP is not a membership organization because it has no
“members” within the meaning of D.C. law governing non-profit corporations. See id. at 10 (citing
D.C. Code § 29-401.02(24)). But EEOC cites no authority suggesting that state corporations law
is dispositive or even relevant to the associational standing inquiry. See, e.g., Citizens Coal
Council v. Matt Canestrale Contracting, Inc., 40 F. Supp. 3d 632, 640 (W.D. Pa. 2014) (noting that
lack of voting rights was not sufficient to defeat associational standing); Concerned Citizens
7
Around Murphy v. Murphy Oil USA, Inc., 686 F. Supp. 2d 663, 675 (E.D. La. 2010) (noting that
“[c]orporate formalities and formal membership structure are not constitutional requirements for
associational standing”). The Court will not disturb its prior ruling on this basis.
EEOC next argues that AARP has not shown that it is a membership organization because
it has not shown that Declarant A serves on AARP’s Board of Directors, serves on a policy
committee, or has ever completed an AARP survey, factors that the Court previously identified in
finding that AARP satisfied the indicia of membership criteria. See AARP I, 226 F. Supp. 3d at
17; see also Gov’t Mot. for Summ. J. at 11–12. Unless Declarant A can show that he participates
in these activities, the argument goes, he is not a member and AARP has failed to show that it has
associational standing. See U.S. Chamber of Commerce v. EPA, 642 F.3d 192, 199 (D.C. Cir.
2011) (“When a petitioner claims associational standing, it is not enough to aver that unidentified
members have been injured. Rather, the petitioner must specifically identify members who have
suffered the requisite harm.” (emphasis added) (internal citation and quotation marks omitted)).
But EEOC’s argument appears to go more towards how active a member Declarant A is in AARP,
not whether he is a member. Declarant A has as much right to participate in the activities that the
Court identified as any other member of AARP, and courts do not appear to analyze to what extent
an identified member partakes in membership activities in determining whether an organization
has associational standing.
However, the Court acknowledges, as it did in its previous opinion, that whether AARP
satisfies the indicia of membership criteria is a close question here. See AARP I, 226 F. Supp. 3d
at 17–18. AARP’s members play less of a role in the running of the organization than do members
of organizations who, for example, directly elect their leadership and hold regular general
membership meetings. See, e.g., ACLU of Nebraska, https://www.aclunebraska.org/en/2017-
8
board-director-elections (noting that “[a]ll ACLU members in Nebraska have been mailed a ballot
for
our
Board
of
Directors
Election”);
Constitution
of
the
NAACP,
at
3–4,
http://www.naacp.org/wp-content/uploads/2016/11/Constitution-eff.-Oct-2016-1.pdf. But AARP
members are not akin to Netflix subscribers, i.e., mere “customers,” as EEOC suggests, nor does
AARP fit the mold of those organizations whom courts have consistently found may not assert
associational standing. See, e.g., Gettman v. Drug Enf’t Admin., 290 F.3d 430, 435 (D.C. Cir.
2002) (readers of magazine were not members for associational standing purposes); Fund
Democracy LLC v. SEC, 278 F.3d 21, 25–26 (D.C. Cir. 2002) (past work with groups of individual
investors did not render the investors “members” of Fund Democracy); Am. Legal Found. v. FCC,
808 F.2d 84, 89–90 (D.C. Cir. 1987) (viewers who regularly watch the news were not members of
media watchdog group for associational standing purposes); Conservative Baptist Ass’n of Am. v.
Shinseki, 42 F. Supp. 3d 125, 134 (D.D.C. 2014) (individual members of congregation were not
members of an association made up exclusively of churches); Wash. Legal Found. v. Leavitt, 477
F. Supp. 2d 202, 210–11 (D.D.C. 2007) (members of a mailing list, without more, did not constitute
members for purposes of associational standing). AARP lies somewhere in between these two
poles.
But as the Court previously recognized, the associational standing cases are not specific
about what it means for members to “play a role in” the leadership of an organization, the financing
of an organization, or in guiding the activities of an organization. AARP members play a role in
all of these activities, even if they could play a stronger role, and EEOC has once again failed to
point to any cases that would suggest that what AARP members do is insufficient to establish
associational standing. Without more, the Court is wary of a ruling that would bar not only AARP
from asserting associational standing, but also bar other repeat litigators whom courts have
9
routinely held are able to assert associational standing as “traditional membership organizations.”
See, e.g., Friends of the Earth, Inc. v. Laidlaw Envt’l Servs. (TOC), Inc., 528 U.S. 167, 181–84
(2000); Am. Trucking Ass’n v. Fed. Motor Carrier Safety Admin., 724 F.3d 243, 247 (D.C. Cir.
2013); WildEarth Guardians v. Jewell, 738 F.3d 298, 305–07 (D.C. Cir. 2013). Accordingly, the
Court will not disturb its prior ruling regarding AARP’s status as a membership organization.
2. Individual member’s standing to sue
In order to assert associational standing, AARP must show that one of the members it
purports to represent would have individual standing to challenge the ADA rule and the GINA
rule. See Nat’l Biodiesel Bd. v. EPA, 843 F.3d 1010, 1015 (D.C. Cir. 2016). The Court previously
found that Declarant A would have standing with respect to both rules. AARP I, 226 F. Supp. 3d
at 18–19. EEOC now argues that Declarant A would not have standing to sue, based on new
information about the collective bargaining agreement between Declarant A’s union and his
employer. EEOC has learned that the agreement in force for 2015–17 provided that the employer
would pay an additional one percent of health insurance premiums for individuals who disclose
confidential health information through completing a health risk assessment, and an additional one
percent for those individuals who participate in biometric screenings. See Gov’t Mot. for Summ.
J. at 13–14. That agreement also included a disease management program for one disease, in
which all plan participants were eligible to participate, but Declarant A’s spouse does not have the
condition covered under the original agreement. 3 However, the agreement stated that additional
disease management programs were under consideration.
After the current round of briefing ended, EEOC learned that this collective bargaining
agreement was renewed through 2020. See Notice of Factual Development [ECF No. 41-1] at 2;
3
EEOC thus appears to be incorrect when its states in its brief that the original agreement did not provide
for spousal incentives. See Gov’t Mot. for Summ. J. at 15.
10
Hrg. Tr. [ECF No. 45] at 37:10–13. The renewed agreement took effect on July 1, 2017 and
maintains the incentive levels for completing the HRA and participating in biometric screening,
but now adds incentives for plan participants, including spouses, to participate in additional disease
management programs for certain diseases. Those who participate will have their co-payments
waived on certain medications. Declarant A’s spouse informed AARP counsel that she has one of
the conditions covered by the new incentive program. See Pl.’s Resp. to Notice of Factual
Development [ECF No. 42] at 1–2; see also Hrg. Tr. at 11:19–13:8, 29:25–30:4.
With respect to the ADA rule, EEOC argues that because Declarant A’s collective
bargaining agreement only imposes incentives of 2%, Declarant A may not challenge the “full
extent” of the ADA rule, which allows incentives of up to 30%. EEOC additionally points out that
AARP has conceded that some level of incentives would be permissible, i.e., consistent with the
ADA’s voluntariness requirement. See Gov’t Reply [ECF No. 38] at 11. Therefore, Declarant A
would at most only be able to challenge a 2% incentive limit.
But the government’s approach—parsing standing to challenge the rule by the particular
incentive level—makes little sense. Under EEOC’s approach, only someone whose employer has
adopted an incentive level of 30% would have standing to challenge the rule. See Gov’t Reply at
11. Yet the provision of the ADA rule that AARP—with the help of Declarant A—challenges
permits employers to offer incentives (or impose penalties) of up to 30% of the cost of self-only
coverage. EEOC does not appear to disagree that Declarant A would have standing to challenge
“part” of the rule, because his employer does impose a 2% incentive for participation in its wellness
program. But it is unclear to the Court how Declarant A could challenge part of the rule without
challenging all of it. Presumably, if the Court were to find that a 2% incentive limit was arbitrary
and capricious or otherwise inconsistent with the ADA, the 30% incentive limit created by the rule
11
would also have to fall. It therefore makes sense to allow Declarant A to challenge the rule even
though his employer has not, at this time, taken advantage of the “full extent” of the rule.
In short, Declarant A has suffered an injury in being required to pay more for his health
insurance than he otherwise would pay because he has declined to disclose information about his
medical conditions to his employer as part of his employer’s wellness program. This injury is
traceable to the ADA rule because the rule makes legal Declarant A’s employer’s use of incentives
in its wellness program, which was illegal—or at the very least legally uncertain—before the rule
was promulgated. See Animal Legal Def. Fund v. Glickman, 154 F.3d 426, 440–44 (D.C. Cir.
1998) (en banc). The Court may remedy this injury by enjoining enforcement of the rule.
Declarant A therefore has amply demonstrated that he would have standing to challenge the ADA
rule.
With respect to the GINA rule, the Court previously held that, once permitted to do so,
Declarant A’s employer was likely to adopt incentives for the collection of spousal information,
and that Declarant A had therefore shown a sufficient likelihood of injury. AARP I, 226 F. Supp.
3d at 18–19; see also Stillwell v. Office of Thrift Supervision, 569 F.3d 514, 519 (D.C. Cir. 2009)
(“[W]hen an agency adopts a rule with the purpose and substantially probable effect of
economically helping regulated Party A and hindering Party B, Party B ordinarily will have
standing to challenge the rule.”). In its briefs on the motion for summary judgment, EEOC has
argued that Declarant A does not have standing to challenge the GINA rule because Declarant A’s
employer is constrained by the collective bargaining agreement and cannot unilaterally adopt
incentives for spousal information. See Gov’t Reply at 10.
However, it is not clear that information about the 2015–17 bargaining agreement would
have altered the Court’s previous decision. The bargaining agreement came up for renewal at the
12
end of the 2016–17 school year. See Gov’t Mot. for Summ. J. at 14; Hrg. Tr. at 29:25–30:4. The
Stillwell principle still appears to apply: once able to adopt programs that collected spousal
information under the GINA rule, Declarant A’s employer was likely to do so in the renewed
collective bargaining agreement—and indeed the old agreement indicated that the employer was
considering adding new disease management programs that would cover all plan participants,
including spouses. Moreover, the new information about the renewed collective bargaining
agreement indicates that the Court’s prediction has been borne out. In renewing the agreement,
Declarant A’s employer adopted incentives for spouses to participate in additional disease
management programs, and Declarant A’s spouse apparently suffers from at least one of the
covered conditions. See Pl.’s Resp. to Notice of Factual Development at 1–2; see also Hrg. Tr. at
12:4–13:8.
Declarant A will therefore be required to disclose either his spouse’s health
information, or forgo the incentive in the form of the co-payment waiver. Although there is
uncertainty about the exact contours of this program, a disease management program must involve
the disclosure of at least some information about an individual’s manifestation of the disease in
order to “manage” it. The employer’s new program thus appears to fall within the scope of the
GINA rule. The new information about the collective bargaining agreement (both the past
agreement and the version that took effect on July 1, 2017) therefore provides no basis for the
Court to reconsider its conclusion that Declarant A has standing with respect to the GINA rule.
*
*
*
As the government does not dispute the Court’s previous findings with respect to the last
two factors of the associational standing inquiry—whether this suit is germane to AARP’s purpose
and whether this suit requires the participation of an individual AARP member—the Court will
not rehash those issues here. Having considered EEOC’s new arguments and information with
13
respect to AARP’s status as a membership organization and Declarant A’s individual standing to
sue, the Court concludes that there is no basis on which to disturb its previous findings regarding
AARP’s associational standing. Accordingly, the Court finds that AARP has associational
standing to challenge both the ADA rule and the GINA rule on behalf of its members, and EEOC’s
motion to dismiss for lack of jurisdiction is therefore denied.
B. SUMMARY JUDGMENT
“Summary judgment is the proper mechanism for deciding, as a matter of law, whether an
agency action is supported by the administrative record and consistent with the APA standard of
review.” Blue Ocean Inst. v. Gutierrez, 585 F. Supp. 2d 36, 41 (D.D.C. 2008). Because of the
court’s limited review under the APA, the summary judgment standard of Rule 56(a) does not
apply when motions for summary judgment are sought in agency review cases. See Fulbright v.
McHugh, 67 F. Supp. 3d 81, 89 (D.D.C. 2014) (citing Coe v. McHugh, 968 F. Supp. 2d 237, 239
(D.D.C. 2013)). Under the APA, courts must set aside agency action that is “arbitrary, capricious,
an abuse of discretion, or otherwise not in accordance with law.” 5 U.S.C. § 706. Although the
scope of review under this standard is narrow, courts must consider “whether the agency acted
within the scope of its legal authority, whether the agency has explained its decision, whether the
facts on which the agency purports to have relied have some basis in the record, and whether the
agency considered the relevant factors.” Fund for Animals v. Babbitt, 903 F. Supp. 96, 105
(D.D.C. 1995) (citing Marsh v. Or. Nat. Res. Council, 490 U.S. 360, 378 (1989)). In short, a court
must be sure that the agency “has examine[d] the relevant data and articulate[d] a satisfactory
explanation for its action including a rational connection between the facts found and the choice
made.” U.S. Chamber of Commerce v. SEC, 412 F.3d 133, 140 (D.C. Cir. 2005) (alterations in
original) (internal quotation marks omitted) (quoting Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Ass’n v. State Farm
14
Mut. Auto Ins. Co., 463 U.S. 29, 43 (1983)). Agency actions that are not “the product of reasoned
decisionmaking” must be overturned. Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Ass’n, 463 U.S. at 52. Here, EEOC
argues that both the ADA rule and the GINA rule survive this deferential standard of review.
AARP generally makes the same two arguments with respect to both rules: first, that the level of
incentives is inconsistent with the meaning of the term “voluntary” as used in the statutes; and
second, that EEOC failed to adequately explain its decision to reverse its stance on incentives and
adopt the 30% incentive levels.
Both parties agree that EEOC’s interpretation of the term “voluntary” in both the ADA and
GINA should be reviewed under the two-step analysis set forth in Chevron U.S.A., Inc. v. Natural
Resources Defense Council, Inc., 467 U.S. 837 (1984). 4 Under that analysis, a court first
determines whether “Congress has directly spoken to the precise question at issue”; if so,
Congress’s meaning must control, and the agency receives no deference. Id. at 842–43. But if
instead the statute is silent or ambiguous as to the specific issue, the court must determine whether
the agency’s interpretation is based on a permissible construction of the statute. Id. at 843.
4
After some consideration, the Court has concluded that the parties are correct, and that it is more appropriate
to consider the central issue in this case—whether AARP has adequately explained its decision to permit incentives
of up to 30% of the cost of coverage—solely under Chevron, rather than to consider the use of incentives generally
under Chevron and then analyze the 30% incentive level separately under the APA’s more general arbitrary and
capricious standard. EEOC has defined the term “voluntary” in both the ADA and GINA to permit incentives of up
to 30%; in other words, the 30% level is an intrinsic part of the agency’s chosen definition of the term. Thus, this is
a matter solely of interpretation, rather than a question of interpretation and then separately of the agency’s application
of that interpretation to a specific situation. Compare Humane Soc’y of the United States v. Zinke, No. 15-5041, 2017
WL 3254932, at *13–16 (D.C. Cir. Aug. 1, 2017) (analyzing under Chevron the agency’s decision to interpret the
term “range” as a species’ current range rather than its historical range, and then analyzing under the arbitrary and
capricious standard the agency’s conclusions about the specific threatened status of gray wolves within their current
range), with Se. Ala. Med. Ctr. v. Sebelius, 572 F.3d 912, 919–920 (D.C. Cir. 2009) (analyzing under Chevron whether
the agency adequately explained its decision to define language in the Medicare statute about “the proportion . . . of
hospitals’ costs which are attributable to wages and wage-related costs,” 42 U.S.C. § 1395ww(d)(3)(E), to include
postage costs).
15
1.
Chevron step one and the definition of “voluntary”
Although the parties likewise agree that both statutes are ambiguous about the meaning of
“voluntary,” and that the issue here is about whether the agency’s rules survive Chevron step two,
the Court will nevertheless briefly consider Chevron step one, i.e., whether the meaning of
“voluntary” as used in the ADA and GINA is ambiguous. See Hrg. Tr. at 16:22–17:2, 28:20–23,
46:6–7. The ADA provides that a “covered entity may conduct voluntary medical examinations,
including voluntary medical histories, which are part of an employee health program.” See 42
U.S.C. § 12112(d)(4)(B).
Likewise, GINA permits a covered entity to collect the genetic
information of an employee where “health or genetic services are offered by the employer,
including such services offered as part of a wellness program,” so long as the employee “provides
prior, knowing, voluntary, and written authorization.” Id. §§ 2000ff-1(b)(2)(A)–(B). Neither the
ADA nor GINA offers a definition of the term “voluntary,” or explains what it means to participate
in a “voluntary” medical examination or to voluntarily provide medical information in order to
participate in a wellness program. Furthermore, nothing in either statute directly prohibits the use
of incentives in connection with wellness programs; indeed, neither statute speaks to the level of
permissible incentives at all. However, because the word “voluntary” is used in very similar
contexts in both statutes—i.e., the voluntary disclosure of protected medical information—the
meaning of the word as used in both the ADA and GINA is presumably the same. See, e.g.,
Erlenbaugh v. United States, 409 U.S. 239, 244 (1972); United States v. Villanueva-Sotebo, 515
F.3d 1234, 1248 (D.C. Cir. 2008).
“When Congress has not supplied a definition, we generally give a statutory term its
ordinary meaning.” Yates v. United States, 135 S. Ct. 1074, 1091 (2015) (Kagan, J., dissenting)
(citing Schindler Elevator Corp. v. United States ex rel. Kirk, 131 S. Ct. 1885, 1891 (2011)). The
16
word “voluntary” has several definitions, a few of which could be applicable here. Webster’s New
International Dictionary includes definitions such as “proceeding from the will, or from one’s own
choice or full consent,” “unconstrained by interference; unimpelled by another’s influence,” and
“acting or done of one’s own free will without valuable consideration.”
Webster’s New
International Dictionary 2858 (2d ed. 1934). The definitions in the third edition are largely
unchanged. See Webster’s New International Dictionary 2564 (3d ed. 1961). Black’s Law
Dictionary gives similar definitions: “done by design or intention,” “unconstrained by interference;
not impelled by outside influence,” and “without valuable consideration.” Voluntary, Black’s Law
Dictionary (10th ed. 2014). The exact meaning of the term “voluntary” in the statutes thus appears
to be ambiguous: voluntary could mean something along the lines of “free from coercion,” or it
could mean “without valuable consideration.” In defining “voluntary” to permit a 30% incentive
level, the agency has clearly chosen an interpretation consistent with the former, rather than the
latter, understanding of the term. Because the statutes are ambiguous and this interpretation is
within the range of interpretations possible under the statutes, the Court will move on to Chevron
step two. See, e.g., Village of Barrington v. Surface Transp. Bd., 636 F.3d 650, 660 (D.C. Cir.
2011).
2.
Chevron step two
At this stage of the analysis, the Court will defer to the agency’s chosen interpretation of
the meaning of “voluntary” if the agency has offered a reasoned explanation for its decision. Id.
In the D.C. Circuit, “[a] ‘reasonable’ explanation of how an agency’s interpretation serves the
statute’s objectives is the stuff of which a ‘permissible’ construction is made…; an explanation
that is ‘arbitrary, capricious, or manifestly contrary to the statute,’ however, is not.” Northpoint
Tech. Ltd. v. FCC, 412 F.3d 145, 151 (D.C. Cir. 2005) (internal citation omitted) (quoting
17
Chevron, 467 U.S. at 844).
The agency’s interpretation need not be “the only possible
interpretation, nor even the interpretation deemed most reasonable by the courts.” Entergy Corp.
v. Riverkeeper, Inc., 556 U.S. 208, 218 (2009). Again, the court is “principally concerned with
ensuring that [the agency] has ‘examined the relevant data and articulated a satisfactory
explanation for its action including a rational connection between the facts found and the choice
made,’ that the [a]gency’s ‘decision was based on a consideration of the relevant factors,’ and that
the [a]gency has made no ‘clear error of judgment.’” Bluewater Network v. EPA, 370 F.3d 1, 11
(D.C. Cir. 2004) (quoting Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Ass’n, 463 U.S. at 43). As the Court noted above,
the real point of contention in this case is whether the agency’s decision to interpret the term
“voluntary” to permit a 30% incentive level is reasonable and whether the agency has offered an
adequate explanation for that interpretation.
a.
The ADA rule
AARP does not dispute that some level of incentives may be permissible under the statutes,
see Hrg. Tr. at 21:21–22:6, 60:3–6; rather, it argues that the incentive level that EEOC chose is an
unreasonable interpretation of the term “voluntary,” see id. at 22:7–23. AARP argues that the 30%
level is inconsistent with the “ordinary meaning” of voluntary because this incentive is too high to
give employees a meaningful choice regarding whether or not to participate in wellness programs
that require the disclosure of ADA-protected information. See Pl.’s Mot. for Summ. J. at 25–30.
AARP also argues that EEOC did not adequately justify the reversal of its longstanding policy that
prohibited the use of incentives, and did not adequately explain how it determined that the 30%
incentive level is a good measure of whether the disclosure of protected medical information is
voluntary. Id. at 31–38.
EEOC, for its part, offers three reasons why it reversed its previous interpretation that
18
“voluntary” precluded the use of incentives and has now determined that the term permits
incentives of up to 30% of the cost of self-only coverage. It argues principally that it adopted this
new interpretation to harmonize its regulations with the HIPAA regulations governing wellness
programs and to induce more individuals to participate in wellness programs, as that was the goal
expressed by Congress in the ACA. See Gov’t Mot. for Summ. J. at 18 (citing ADA Rule, 81 Fed.
Reg. at 31,129); see also Hrg. Tr. at 41:1–6, 42:4–43:5. Second, it states that the 30% incentive
level is a reasonable interpretation of “voluntary” based on “current insurance rates,” and third,
based on a comment letter submitted by the American Heart Association which endorsed the 30%
level. See Gov’t Mot. for Summ. J. at 18–21; ADA Rule, 81 Fed. Reg. at 31,133; see also Hrg.
Tr. at 41:1–42:7.
The determination as to what level of incentive is “coercive” is exactly the kind of agency
judgment to which the courts should give some deference. “Voluntariness” is a matter of degree,
and the agency is far better suited than the courts to determine what incentive level adequately
balances the goals of the ADA, yet helps to achieve some consistency across federal regulations.
But in order to receive this deference, the agency’s chosen interpretation must be reasonable and
must be supported by the administrative record. Having now had the opportunity to review the
administrative record in this case, the Court concludes that the agency has not provided a reasoned
explanation for its interpretation. EEOC determined that incentives greater than 30% of the cost
of coverage would render the disclosure of protected medical information pursuant to a wellness
program “involuntary” under the ADA, but an incentive of 30% or less would not. But the Court
can find nothing in the administrative record that explains the agency’s conclusion that the 30%
incentive level is the appropriate measure for voluntariness.
i. Consistency with HIPAA
19
EEOC depends heavily on the argument that it adopted the 30% incentive level in order to
harmonize its regulations with HIPAA. See Hrg. Tr. at 41:1–6, 42:25. In the abstract, this may
be a reasonable goal. But there are two problems with the agency’s underlying reasoning on this
point. The first is that Congress chose the 30% number in a different context: HIPAA is intended
to prevent insurance discrimination, and unlike the ADA—or GINA—does not contain an explicit
“voluntary” requirement with respect to wellness programs. While EEOC has chosen to adopt the
30% incentive level as a proxy for voluntariness in the ADA rule, the 30% incentive cap in HIPAA
is not intended to serve as a proxy for or interpretation of the term “voluntary.” HIPAA’s nondiscrimination provisions are designed to prevent health plans and insurers from denying
individuals coverage or benefits, or imposing increased costs, based on a health factor. See, e.g.,
2013 HIPAA Rule, 78 Fed. Reg. at 33,158–59.
Incentives in health-contingent wellness
programs—which require a participant to satisfy a particular health standard—are the exception
to this rule; insurers and health plans are essentially allowed to discriminate based on a health
factor in certain limited circumstances. Id. HIPAA has no need to limit incentives in participatory
wellness programs, however, because those programs do not require participants to achieve a
particular health standard; thus, such programs do not risk discrimination based on a health factor,
which is HIPAA’s chief concern. Whether an individual’s participation in a wellness program is
voluntary is not an issue under that statute. The regulations are clear, moreover, that compliance
with HIPAA does not guarantee compliance with other federal non-discrimination statutes,
including the ADA and GINA. Id. at 33,168. Thus, HIPAA does not address, for example,
whether employers can require participation in certain wellness programs or require the disclosure
of certain information pursuant to a wellness program.
But the ADA does address this, at least with respect to disability information. The ADA
20
is designed to prevent discrimination in employment, and the “voluntary” provision of the ADA—
like the “voluntary” provision of GINA—is designed to prevent employers from forcing
employees to disclose health information that might enable employers to discriminate against
them. Permitting the use of incentives in wellness programs does not create an exception to the
anti-discrimination provisions of the ADA. Rather, it constitutes an interpretation of an explicit
statutory requirement: that an employee’s decision to disclose ADA-protected information to an
employer be “voluntary.” The purpose of a statute, and the way in which a proposed rule furthers
the purposes of a statute, is critical to the Chevron step two analysis, see Northpoint Tech., 412
F.3d at 151, and EEOC does not appear to have considered the purpose of the ADA vis-à-vis
HIPAA here, or the way in which the 30% incentive level operates in the context of the ADA.
EEOC does not explain why it makes sense to adopt wholesale the 30% level in HIPAA, which
was adopted in a different statute based on different considerations and for different reasons, into
the ADA context as a permissible interpretation of the term “voluntary”—a term not included in
the relevant provisions of HIPAA—beyond stating that this interpretation “harmonizes” the
regulations.
This brings us to the second problem with EEOC’s justification based on HIPAA: the
interpretation the agency adopted—the 30% incentive level—is actually not consistent with
HIPAA, as both AARP and multiple comment letters in the administrative record point out. The
majority of wellness programs are participatory, rather than health-contingent, see AR 7557 (at
large firms, only 5% of wellness programs were health contingent in 2015); Hrg. Tr. at 24:4–12,
43:12–17, and the HIPAA regulations place no cap on participatory wellness programs, see 2013
HIPAA Rule, 78 Fed. Reg. at 33,180. It is only health-contingent wellness programs that are
subject to the 30% cap under HIPAA, yet the ADA rule extends this cap to both participatory and
21
health-contingent wellness programs. Thus, the ADA rule is actually inconsistent with the HIPAA
regulations for the majority of wellness programs. The HIPAA regulations also calculate the 30%
incentive level differently: that level is based on the total cost of coverage, which includes the cost
of family coverage, rather than the cost of self-only coverage that the ADA rule adopts. See 2013
HIPAA Rule, 78 Fed. Reg. at 33,162 (“If, in addition to employees, any class of
dependents . . . may participate in the health-contingent wellness program, the reward cannot
exceed the applicable percentage of the total cost of the coverage in which the employee and any
dependents are enrolled (such as family coverage or employee-plus-one coverage).”). EEOC has
thus achieved, at best, only partial consistency with HIPAA for only a minority of wellness
programs.
Indeed, most of the comment letters from business and industry groups contained in the
administrative record opposed the 30% incentive level because of these inconsistencies, noting
that the proposed rule had not provided any meaningful justification for its departure from the
2013 HIPAA regulations. See, e.g., AR 2630 (Ne. Bus. Grp. on Health); 2711, 2714, 2718 (Health
Enhancement Research Org.); 2755 (Bus. Health Coal.); 2894 (Nat’l Bus. Coal. on Health); 2924–
29 (Council of Ins. Agents & Brokers); 2965–66 (Bus. Roundtable); 3057–58 (Population Health
Alliance); 3074 (Aetna); 3476–78 (U.S. Chamber of Commerce); 3569–70 (members of
Congress); 3883 (Tyson Foods). Nowhere in the final rulemaking does EEOC explain why or how
the incentive level it adopted, which differs from the approach taken in HIPAA, is consistent with
its stated goal of harmonizing its regulations with HIPAA, or conversely, why it ultimately
concluded that a departure from the HIPAA regulations was necessary or appropriate.
EEOC’s first proffered reason for interpreting the “voluntary” provision of the ADA to
permit incentives of up to 30% is thus deeply flawed. Indeed, even assuming that the ADA rule
22
had achieved consistency with HIPAA, the agency’s failure to consider the fact that HIPAA
contains no “voluntary” requirement might be fatal to its chosen interpretation. That failure
certainly undermines EEOC’s first reason for its interpretation. But EEOC’s first reason is further
undermined by the fact that the ADA rule does not, in fact, achieve EEOC’s desired harmony with
HIPAA. EEOC’s argument that it adopted the 30% level to harmonize its regulations with HIPAA,
therefore, cannot support EEOC’s interpretation of the term “voluntary.”
ii. Current insurance rates
However, EEOC also stated in the final rule that it concluded that the 30% incentive level
was a reasonable interpretation of the term “voluntary” (i.e., non-coercive) based on “current
insurance rates.” ADA Rule, 81 Fed. Reg. at 31,133. The final rule does not elaborate on what
these rates are, how the agency evaluated them, or what bearing they have on the key question of
whether an incentive level is “coercive” or “voluntary.” Indeed, EEOC conceded at oral argument
that the administrative record contains no study or analysis of these “current insurance rates” or
how they relate to the voluntary disclosure of information in wellness programs. See Hrg. Tr. at
41:5–23.
The only reference to insurance rates the Court can find in the administrative record is
contained in the Kaiser Family Foundation’s Employer Health Benefits 2014 Annual Survey,
which analyzes changes in health plans, including increases in premiums, plan enrollment,
employee-employer cost sharing, etc., between 2013 and 2014. See AR 7563–804. This study
contains little that is relevant to the voluntariness question, and EEOC does not appear to rely on
this study in either its briefs or the rule. The study does contain some statistics that relate the cost
of premiums and income levels, which theoretically might be relevant here, but this information
is included in studies about premium costs based on “firm characteristics,” including the
23
percentage of “low-wage level or “high-wage level” workers a firm has. Low-wage level workers
are defined as those who earned less than $23,000 a year in 2014; high-wage level workers are
those who earned more than $57,000 a year. See, e.g., id. at 7605–06, 7611. The study concludes
that firms with more high-wage level workers have somewhat higher annual premiums than those
with more low-wage level workers.
Id. at 7598–99, 7605–06, 7611. But this doesn’t tell us
anything about what incentive level would render a wellness program involuntary or how the
agency determined what incentive level would be coercive. Thus, like the argument about
harmonizing its regulations with the HIPAA regulations, EEOC’s argument about current
insurance rates appears to be utterly lacking in substance based on a review of the administrative
record.
iii. Comment letters
Finally, EEOC asserts that it relied on comment letters in determining that the 30%
incentive level was a reasonable interpretation of “voluntary.” The only specific comment letter
it identifies, however, is that submitted by the American Heart Association, which endorses the
30% incentive level. See AR 2780. That letter states that “[i]t makes sense to make the incentive
level consistent across all types of programs, whether participatory or health-contingent,” but does
not explain why. Id. Moreover, the letter does not explain why the 30% level is an appropriate
measure of voluntariness—ironically, the letter even notes that it “is not intuitive that a program
is completely voluntary with an incentive attached that can significantly increase the cost of health
insurance.” Id.; see also id. at 2784 (remarking that the incentive level is “not entirely consistent
with voluntary”). Finally, even this letter urges EEOC to consider basing the 30% calculation on
the total cost of coverage, to achieve greater consistency with the ACA and HIPAA. Id. at 2780–
81. While EEOC is certainly entitled to rely on comments, as it points out, see Gov’t Mot. for
24
Summ. J. at 21 (citing Nat’l Ass’n of Regulatory Utility Comm’rs v. FCC, 737 F.2d 1095, 1125
(D.C. Cir. 1984)), this particular letter lends little weight to EEOC’s explanation because it
contains largely conclusory statements and no analysis as to why EEOC’s chosen incentive level
is a reasonable interpretation of “voluntary.” The letter is particularly unpersuasive given that the
majority of the comment letters expressed opposition to EEOC’s chosen incentive level (either
because the 30% level was too low or too high).
EEOC protests that it was “presented
with . . . every opinion under the sun” and was therefore entitled to rely on some but not others,
and the Court does not dispute this. But the agency must explain why it chose to rely on certain
comments rather than others, and it did not do so here.
iv. Failure to consider relevant factors
Significantly, the Court can find nothing in the administrative record—or the final rule—
to indicate that the agency considered any factors that are actually relevant to the voluntariness
question. Having chosen to define “voluntary” in financial terms—30% of the cost of self-only
coverage—the agency does not appear to have considered any factors relevant to the financial and
economic impact the rule is likely to have on individuals who will be affected by the rule. See,
e.g., Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Ass’n, 463 U.S. at 42–43. For example, commenters pointed out that,
based on the average annual cost of premiums in 2014, a 30% penalty for refusing to provide
protected information would double the cost of health insurance for most employees. AR 3778–
79 (Bazelon Ctr. for Mental Health Law), 3833 (Disability Rights Educ. & Def. Fund); see also
id. at 3493 (ACLU) (noting that most employees already contribute 20–30% of the cost of
coverage). At around $1800 a year, this is the equivalent of several months’ worth of food for the
average family, two months of child care in most states, and roughly two months’ rent. See id. at
3302 (Nat’l Women’s Law Ctr.); see also id. at 3492 (ACLU) (noting average annual premium);
25
3778 (Bazelon Ctr. for Mental Health Law) (same); 3833 (Disability Rights Educ. & Def. Fund)
(same). The agency did not consider the distributional impacts of the rule and what impact income
level would have on whether an incentive as a given percentage of premium costs would be
coercive for an employee. Indeed, many of the comments in the administrative record expressed
concern that the 30% incentive level was likely to be far more coercive for employees with lower
incomes, and was likely to disproportionately affect people with disabilities specifically, who on
average have lower incomes than those without disabilities. See, e.g., id. 2680 (comment from
Dr. Anna Slomovic suggesting that EEOC commission a study to examine the impact of the rule
on low-income employees); 3242 (Epilepsy Found.); 3302–03 (Nat’l Women’s Law Center); 3496
(ACLU); 3506–07 (Am. Psychological Ass’n); 3775 (Bazelon Ctr. for Mental Health Law); 3829–
30 (Disability Rights Educ. & Def. Fund); 7949 (RAND study noting that “high powered”
incentives of 20% or more might place a disproportionate burden on lower-paid workers).
While EEOC is not required to respond to every comment it receives, it does have to
respond “in a reasoned manner to those that raise significant problems.” Covad Commc’ns Co. v.
FCC, 450 F.3d 528, 550 (D.C. Cir. 2006).
The possibility that the ADA rule could
disproportionately harm the group the ADA is designed to protect would appear to pose a
“significant problem.” This again demonstrates EEOC’s failure to engage meaningfully with the
text and purpose of the ADA. EEOC acknowledged in the final rule that some commenters
expressed concern that the incentive level was too high, see 81 Fed. Reg. at 31,129, 31,132–33,
but it did not otherwise respond to these specific concerns—for example, by explaining why it did
not consider certain economic factors or why it chose to discount so many commenters’ consistent
concerns in promulgating the final rule.
EEOC argues, however, that under the ACA, large employers, defined as those with fifty
26
or more full-time employees, are already incentivized to offer full-time employees “affordable”
coverage, or face an additional tax. See Gov’t Mot. for Summ. J. at 19–20; see also 26 U.S.C.
§ 36B(c)(2)(C); 26 C.F.R. § 1.36B-2(c)(3)(v)(A)(4). Thus, EEOC concluded in the ADA rule that
this ACA provision and its implementing regulations “promotes the ADA’s interest in ensuring
that incentive limits are not so high as to make participation in a wellness program involuntary.”
See 81 Fed. Reg. at 31,132. But this conclusion ignores the fact that the ADA covers employers
with 15 or more employees, 42 U.S.C. § 12111(5)(A), while the ACA “affordability” tax applies
to employers with 50 or more employees. The final rule does not discuss the fact that many ADAcovered employees will not be protected by this ACA provision. In addition, the ACA tax only
“incentivizes” employers—they may choose to pay the tax and offer “unaffordable” coverage to
employees. The ADA’s voluntariness provision, on the other hand, requires that employees be
protected from coerced disclosure of ADA-protected information—and it is EEOC who is charged
with protecting them.
Most importantly, though, EEOC’s ACA-based argument cannot support EEOC’s
interpretation of the term “voluntary” on its own, or make up for EEOC’s failure to give a reasoned
explanation for its decision to define “voluntary” as a 30% incentive cap in the first place. Indeed,
EEOC’s reliance on this argument here suggests that EEOC recognizes that the 30% incentive
level may not be a meaningful measure of “voluntariness”: EEOC is essentially arguing that it
doesn’t matter if the 30% incentive level is too high—i.e., inconsistent with the voluntary
requirement—because another statutory provision might prevent employers from imposing
insurance costs on employees that could coerce them into disclosing protected information.
Needless to say, this is a woefully insufficient justification for EEOC’s chosen statutory
interpretation.
27
*
*
*
To be clear, there is plenty of evidence to support EEOC’s conclusion that regulation was
needed in this area to clarify employer obligations with respect to wellness programs, see, e.g., AR
2895, 2923, 3462; see also AARP I, 226 F. Supp. 3d at 13–15 (discussing regulatory history of the
ADA and GINA rules), and there is also evidence that the use of incentives increases participation
in wellness programs, see AR 3000, 3053, 7836, 7908–34, 7949, 8175; see also id. at 7105
(comment on GINA rule). But EEOC has not justified its decision to interpret “voluntary” in the
ADA to permit incentives of up to 30%, because it has not adequately explained how it determined
that the 30% incentive level is an adequate measure of voluntariness. Courts may not “simply
accept whatever conclusion an agency proffers merely because it is the agency’s judgment.”
Tripoli Rocketry Ass’n, Inc. v. ATF, 437 F.3d 75, 77 (D.C. Cir. 2006). While the Court
acknowledges that some arbitrary line drawing may be necessary in determining where to set the
incentive level, the agency must still point to some evidence in the record that reasonably supports
where it chose to draw the line, and it must also respond to “substantial criticisms” of that choice.
See United Distribution Cos. v. FERC, 88 F.3d 1105, 1141 n.45 (D.C. Cir. 1996); see also Emily’s
List v. FEC, 581 F.3d 1, 22 n.20 (D.C. Cir. 2009). In short, the process by which an agency reaches
a given result “must be logical and rational.” Tripoli, 437 F.3d at 77.
That has not been the case here. The agency’s proffered reasons do not support its
determination that permitting incentives of up to 30% is a reasonable interpretation of the ADA’s
voluntariness requirement. Based on the administrative record, it appears that EEOC co-opted the
30% incentive level from the HIPAA regulations without giving sufficient thought to whether or
how it should apply in the context of the ADA, and particularly in the context of the ADA’s
requirement that wellness programs be “voluntary.” Indeed, EEOC does not appear to have
28
considered any factor that actually speaks to whether a given incentive level is voluntary or
coercive.
Because of this, the Court concludes that EEOC’s interpretation of the ADA’s
voluntariness requirement is neither reasonable nor supported by the administrative record.
b. The GINA rule
With respect to the GINA rule, AARP argues that the interpretation of the term “voluntary”
is unreasonable because it is inconsistent with GINA’s definition of “genetic information,” in that
the rule interprets the “voluntary” requirement to treat spousal information differently from other
types of genetic information. However, AARP also argues that the rule suffers from the same
shortcomings as the ADA rule, in that EEOC failed to consider factors relevant to voluntariness
and significant comments and did not otherwise support its decision to impose the 30% incentive
level for GINA. See Pl.’s Mot. for Summ. J. at 39–45.
GINA defines “genetic information” to include the genetic tests of family members of an
individual, and the manifestation of a disease or disorder in family members; “family members”
includes dependents by marriage. See 42 U.S.C. §§ 2000ff(3), (4); 29 U.S.C. § 1181(f)(2). The
new GINA rule permits employers to impose a 30% incentive/penalty on employees to encourage
the disclosure of a spouse’s manifestation of disease or disorder. GINA Rule, 81 Fed. Reg. at
31,144. But the rule does not permit employers to use incentives to collect information about the
spouse’s genetic information, or about the manifestation of diseases or disorders in an employee’s
children, or the genetic information of the children. Id. AARP argues that this provision is
inconsistent with the definition of genetic information in GINA, because EEOC is giving more
protection to one type of genetic information than to another. According to AARP, this also
renders the GINA rule internally inconsistent, in that the meaning of “voluntary” disclosure with
respect to spousal information is different than the meaning of “voluntary” disclosure with respect
29
to all other genetic information, because one meaning permits the use of incentives and the other
does not.
The Court is not convinced that EEOC’s decision to distinguish between different types of
genetic information with respect to incentives necessarily renders the rule unreasonable or
inconsistent with GINA. If the “voluntary” requirement in GINA gives the agency discretion to
allow incentives for the disclosure of genetic information generally, as AARP agrees, it likely also
gives the agency discretion to allow employers to incentivize the disclosure of some protected
information, but not all. Somewhat more troubling, however, is the explanation EEOC gave for
its decision to distinguish between spousal information and other genetic information, and it is this
in particular with which AARP takes issue. EEOC concluded that there was less risk of employer
discrimination based on the disclosure of a spouse’s medical history, because the spouse’s history
does not reveal actual genetic information about the employee, and therefore cannot be used to
make predictions about an employee’s health. While this premise is certainly logical, it appears
to miss the purpose of including spousal information in the definition of genetic information in the
first place. Employers are likely to discriminate on the basis of health status or genetic information
due to the potential for increased insurance costs to the employer, and this concern about increased
costs would apply to anyone covered by the health plan, including dependents, not just to the
employee. That, presumably, is why Congress included spousal information in the definition of
genetic information of the employee. Again, the purpose or objectives of the statute are important
in considering the reasonableness of the agency’s statutory interpretation, and EEOC does not
appear to have considered—or even acknowledged—this concern at all. EEOC’s proffered
explanation therefore appears to be somewhat inconsistent with GINA’s objectives.
Aside from this issue, however, the GINA rule also suffers from the same problems as the
30
ADA rule, in that EEOC did not adequately explain the basis for its decision to interpret GINA’s
“voluntary” provision as permitting the 30% incentive level. In the proposed GINA rule, EEOC
originally based the 30% incentive level on the total cost of coverage for the plan in which the
employee and any dependents were enrolled, rather than the total cost of self-only coverage as in
the ADA rule. See Proposed GINA Rule, 80 Fed. Reg. 66853, 66857 (Oct. 30, 2015). This
decision received extensive criticism in the comment letters, however, and EEOC ultimately
decided to adopt the same incentive level it used in the ADA rule, i.e., 30% of the cost of self-only
coverage. See, e.g., AR 7198–99 (Soc’y for Human Res. Mgmt.); 7205 (Unite Here Health);
7212–14 (Coll. & Univ. Prof’l Ass’n for Human Res.); see also GINA Rule, 81 Fed. Reg. at
31,154. In fact, in the final rule, EEOC cites its decision in the ADA rule as the basis for its
decision to adopt the 30% incentive level in the GINA rule, explaining that it had “determined, in
developing the final ADA rule . . . that incentives in excess of 30 percent . . . would be coercive,”
and therefore there was “no reason” to adopt “a different threshold where the employee’s spouse
is the individual whose health information is being sought.” GINA Rule, 81 Fed. Reg. at 31,154.
As with the ADA rule, however, the administrative record contains no explanation how
EEOC concluded that the 30% level was the appropriate measure for voluntariness or is consistent
with GINA’s statutory requirement that the disclosure of information be voluntary. The American
Heart Association submitted a separate comment on the GINA rule endorsing the 30% level, but
again offered little basis for doing so that would bolster EEOC’s explanation. See AR 6932. The
argument that the 30% level was the number “chosen by Congress” fails here for the same reason
it failed in the context of the ADA rule: the 30% number was chosen by Congress in a different
context under a different statute that did not contain a voluntariness requirement. Simply stating
that the 30% level in the GINA rule “draw[s] inspiration from” the HIPAA regulations and the
31
ACA is not a sufficient explanation for this interpretation of the statutory term “voluntary.” See
Hrg. Tr. at 49:8–11. Moreover, the GINA rule likewise does not accomplish EEOC’s stated goal
of harmonizing its regulations with HIPAA, nor did EEOC explain why a departure from the
HIPAA regulations was appropriate, beyond the wholly conclusory statement that permitting a
higher incentive would render the disclosure of GINA-protected information involuntary. See,
e.g., AR 7205 (Unite Here Health); 7216 (Coll. & Univ. Prof’l Ass’n for Human Res.) (“The
Commission has not included within either of its proposals [the GINA rule and the ADA rule] any
meaningful justification for this unwise departure.”).
Once again, the administrative record contains little evidence that EEOC actually analyzed
any factors that might be relevant to the economic “coerciveness” of an incentive level in GINA,
for example, factors related to income. This would seem to be particularly important with the
adoption of the GINA rule, because with the addition of the GINA rule an employee and his or her
family may face “stacked” penalties or incentives for the disclosure of information. In other words,
an employer may adopt a 30% incentive for the disclosure of an employee’s ADA-protected
information, as well as a 30% incentive for the disclosure of the employee’s spouse’s GINAprotected information. See GINA Rule, 81 Fed. Reg. at 31,146. The potential cumulative effect
of these incentives is surely relevant to the question of whether disclosure is voluntary or not. But
beyond the mention in the final rule that stacking is possible, there is no indication that EEOC
considered this at all.
In short, EEOC’s explanation for its chosen interpretation of “voluntary” in the GINA rule
fares no better than its explanation in the ADA rule—principally because EEOC relies primarily
on its decision in the ADA rule as the basis for its decision here. Therefore, the Court again finds
that the agency has failed to give a reasoned explanation for its decision to interpret the term
32
voluntary to allow incentives of up to 30% of the cost of self-only coverage.
*
*
*
EEOC has failed to adequately explain its decision to construe the term “voluntary” in the
ADA and GINA to permit the 30% incentive level adopted in both the ADA rule and the GINA
rule. Neither the final rules nor the administrative record contain any concrete data, studies, or
analysis that would support any particular incentive level as the threshold past which an incentive
becomes involuntary in violation of the ADA and GINA. To be clear, this would likely be a
different case if the administrative record had contained support for and an explanation of the
agency’s decision, given the deference courts must give in this context. But “deference” does not
mean that courts act as a rubber stamp for agency policies. See Presley v. Etowah Cty. Comm’n,
502 U.S. 491, 508 (1992) (“Deference does not mean acquiescence.”). When choosing from a
range of possible interpretations of a statutory term, the agency must give a reasoned explanation
for its decision. Absent such reasoning or factual support here, the Court “must conclude” that the
agency has made its decision arbitrarily. See Ass’n of Private Colls. & Univs. v. Duncan, 870 F.
Supp. 2d 133, 154 (D.D.C. 2012) (citing U.S. Air. Tour Ass’n v. FAA, 298 F.3d 997, 1019 (D.C.
Cir. 2002)). Accordingly, EEOC’s motion for summary judgment will be denied, and AARP’s
motion will be granted.
C. REMEDY
Having found that both the ADA rule and the GINA rule are arbitrary and capricious, the
Court must now decide on the appropriate remedy. An agency’s failure to provide a reasoned
explanation for its decision requires a court to remand to the agency for further consideration, but
does not necessarily require vacatur. See, e.g., Advocates for Highway & Auto Safety v. Fed.
Motor Carrier Safety Admin., 429 F.3d 1136, 1151 (D.C. Cir. 2005) (citations omitted) (“While
33
unsupported agency action normally requires vacatur, . . . this court is not without discretion [to
remand without vacating].”); Allied-Signal, Inc. v. Nuclear Regulatory Comm’n, 988 F.2d 146,
150 (D.C. Cir. 1993) (“An inadequately supported rule…need not necessarily be vacated.”); Int’l
Union, United Mine Workers of Am. v. Fed. Mine Safety & Health Admin., 920 F.2d 960, 966
(D.C. Cir. 1990) (“We have commonly remanded without vacating an agency’s rule or order where
the failure lay in lack of reasoned decisionmaking . . . ”). “The ‘decision whether to vacate
depends on the seriousness of the [rule’s] deficiencies (and thus the extent of doubt whether the
agency chose correctly) and the disruptive consequences of an interim change that may itself be
changed.’” Defs. of Wildlife v. Jackson, 791 F. Supp. 2d 96, 117 (D.D.C. 2011) (alterations in
original) (quoting Comcast Corp. v. FCC, 579 F.3d 1, 8 (D.C. Cir. 2009)). Neither party addresses
this issue in their briefs, but at oral argument, unsurprisingly, AARP requested that the Court
vacate the rules and EEOC preferred remand to the agency without vacatur. See Hrg. Tr. at 46:17–
25, 65:6–21.
The lack of a reasoned explanation is a serious failing in an agency’s decision, because it
leaves the Court in doubt as to “whether the agency chose correctly” in making its decision. See
Am. Petrol. Inst. v. Johnson, 541 F. Supp. 2d 165, 185 (D.D.C 2008) (quoting United Mine
Workers of Am., 920 F.2d at 967)). While EEOC has discretion to choose the correct incentive
level, the fact that it does not appear to have considered any relevant factors in determining what
incentive level best approximates “voluntariness” suggests that the agency’s decision may very
well be different on remand. Id. at 185–86. Thus, this factor weighs in favor of vacatur.
Nevertheless, the second factor, the consequences of vacatur, weighs heavily in favor of
simply remanding without vacatur. The ADA and GINA rules were promulgated in May 2016,
took effect in July 2016, and became “applicable” on January 1, 2017, in order to give businesses
34
time to bring their wellness programs into compliance with these rules. ADA Rule 81 Fed. Reg.
at 31,126, 31,129; GINA Rule, 81 Fed. Reg. at 31,143, 31,147. Employer health plans for the year
2017 were undoubtedly designed in reliance on these rules, which have now been “applicable” for
eight months. See, e.g., U.S. Chamber of Commerce v. SEC, 443 F.3d 890, 909 (D.C. Cir. 2006)
(finding that vacatur was inappropriate because many businesses had already come into
compliance with the invalid rule, meaning that vacatur could cause significant disruption in the
industry); see also MCI Telecomms. Corp. v. FCC, 143 F.3d 606, 609 (D.C. Cir. 1998) (noting
that vacatur would disrupt business plans already made). It is far from clear that it would be
possible to restore the status quo ante if the rules were vacated; rather, it may well end up punishing
those firms—and employees—who acted in reliance on the rules. See, e.g., Defs. of Wildlife, 791
F. Supp. 2d at 118–19 (citing Sugar Cane Growers Coop. v. Veneman, 289 F.3d 89, 97–98 (D.C.
Cir. 2002)). Employees who received incentives from their employers would presumably be
obligated to pay these back, which may not be feasible for many; employers who imposed a penalty
rather than an incentive would likewise be obligated to repay to employees the cost of the penalty,
which again, may or may not be feasible. Vacatur will not remedy the fact that many employees
who have chosen to disclose their protected medical information have already done so; this
information cannot be made confidential again. Employers who adopted incentives would be
faced with the possibility that their current health plans are illegal; at best, employers would once
again be left in limbo as to what is permitted and what is not with regard to incentives. In short,
this is not a case in which vacatur would simply cause a private party to suffer pecuniary loss. See,
e.g., Reed v. Salazar, 744 F. Supp. 2d 98, 119–20 (D.D.C. 2010). Instead, vacatur appears likely
to cause potentially widespread disruption and confusion.
Hence, while the Court has serious concerns about the agency’s reasoning regarding the
35
GINA and ADA rules, these concerns are currently outweighed by the “disruptive consequences”
that are likely to result from vacatur. Assuming that the agency can address the rules’ failings in
a timely manner, vacatur “is not the required remedy,” and would indeed be inappropriate at this
time. AFL-CIO v. Chao, 496 F. Supp. 2d 76, 91 (D.D.C. 2007). Thus, for the present, the Court
will remand the rules to EEOC for reconsideration without vacatur.
CONCLUSION
For the foregoing reasons, EEOC’s motion to dismiss, or in the alternative, motion for
summary judgment, will be denied, and AARP’s motion for summary judgment will be granted.
The Court concludes that AARP has sufficiently demonstrated that it has associational standing to
bring this suit on behalf of its members. EEOC, moreover, has failed to provide a reasoned
explanation for its decision to adopt the 30% incentive levels in both the ADA and GINA rules.
However, because the Court finds that vacatur of the rules is likely to have significant disruptive
consequences, the Court will not vacate the rules and will simply remand them to the agency for
reconsideration. A separate order has been issued on this date.
/s/
JOHN D. BATES
United States District Judge
Dated: August 22, 2017
36
Disclaimer: Justia Dockets & Filings provides public litigation records from the federal appellate and district courts. These filings and docket sheets should not be considered findings of fact or liability, nor do they necessarily reflect the view of Justia.
Why Is My Information Online?