Le et al v. Zuffa, LLC

Filing 314

ORDER Denying #64 Motion to Dismiss and Granting #160 Stipulation of Electronically Stored Information. Signed by Judge Richard F. Boulware, II on 10/19/2016. (Copies have been distributed pursuant to the NEF - DL)

Download PDF
1 2 3 4 UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT 5 DISTRICT OF NEVADA 6 7 CUNG LE, NATHAN QUARRY, JON FITCH, et al, 8 9 10 11 *** Lead Case No.: 2:15-cv-01045-RFB-PAL Plaintiffs, ORDER Member Case Nos.: v. ZUFFA, LLC, d/b/a ULTIMATE FIGHTINGCHAMPIONSHIP and UFC, 12 Defendant. 13 14 KYLE KINGSBURY AND DARREN UYENOYAMA, on behalf of themselves and all others similarly situated, Case No.: 2:15-cv-1046-RFB-PAL 15 Plaintiffs, 16 17 18 v. ZUFFA, LLC, d/b/a Ultimate Fighting Championship and UFC, 19 Defendant. 20 21 22 LUIS JAVIER VAZQUEZ and DENNIS LLOYD HALLMAN, on behalf of themselves and all others similarly situated, Plaintiffs, 23 24 25 26 27 28 v. ZUFFA, LLC, d/b/a Ultimate Fighting Championship and UFC, Defendant. Case No.: 2:15-cv-01055-RFB-PAL 1 2 BRANDON VERA and PABLO GARZA, on behalf of themselves and all others similarly situated, Plaintiffs, 3 v. 4 5 Case No.: 2:15-cv-01056-RFB-PAL ZUFFA, LLC, d/b/a Ultimate Fighting Championship and UFC, 6 Defendants. 7 8 9 Plaintiffs, 10 v. 11 12 Case No.: 2:15-cv-01057-RFB-PAL GABE RUDIGER and MAC DANNZIG, on behalf of themselves and all others similarly situated, Zuffa, LLC, d/b/a Ultimate Fighting Championship and UFC, Defendants. 13 14 15 I. INTRODUCTION 16 Before the Court are identical Motions to Dismiss (ECF Nos. 64, 16, 30, 16) in the instant 17 case and member cases 2:15-cv-01046-RFB-PAL, 2:15-cv-01055-RFB-PAL, 2:15-cv-01056- 18 RFB-PAL, and 2:15-cv-01057-RFB-PAL, as well as a Stipulation re: Discovery of Electronically 19 Stored Information (ECF No. 160). For the sake of clarity, the Court will refer to the Motion to 20 Dismiss as ECF No. 64 in the lead case, Case No. 2:15-cv-01045-RFB-PAL. For the reasons 21 discussed, the Court DENIES the Motion to Dismiss (ECF No. 64) and GRANTS the Stipulation 22 re: Discovery of Electronically Stored Information (ECF No. 160). 23 24 II. BACKGROUND 25 A. Factual Background 26 The following allegations are common to all five cases against Defendant Zuffa and are 27 drawn from the Plaintiffs’ Complaint (ECF No. 1) in Case No. 2:15-cv-01045-RFB-PAL. 28 -2- 1 Plaintiffs are Elite Professional MMA Fighters (“Bout Class Plaintiffs”) and those fighters 2 called “Identity Plaintiffs” (collectively, “Plaintiffs”). Plaintiffs bring this action against Defendant 3 Zuffa, LLC, who operates under the trademark Ultimate Fighting Championship or “UFC.” The 4 UFC, which (through the conduct alleged herein) now controls approximately 90% of the revenues 5 derived from live Elite Professional MMA bouts, promotes and distributes professional live MMA 6 bouts through various venues, in the U.S. and internationally. Compl. ¶ 7. 7 Plaintiffs bring antitrust action under Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 2, for 8 treble damages and other relief arising out of Defendant’s overarching anticompetitive scheme to 9 maintain and enhance its (a) monopoly power (the “Relevant Output Market”) in the market for 10 promotion of live Elite Professional mixed martial arts (“MMA”) bouts, and (b) monopsony power 11 in the market for live Elite Professional MMA Fighter services (“Relevant Input Market”). Compl. 12 ¶ 1. The relevant geographic market for both the Relevant Input Market and Relevant Output 13 Market is limited to the United States and, in the alternative, North America. Id. 14 1. Input Market 15 By dominating the market for live Elite Professional MMA Fighter services through the 16 scheme alleged herein (including through long-term exclusive agreements with MMA Fighters 17 and other exclusionary and anticompetitive acts), the UFC controls the talents of Elite Professional 18 MMA Fighters, who are popular with national audiences. Id. at ¶ 5. 19 The UFC denied actual and potential rivals necessary inputs to run effective professional 20 MMA Promotion companies, raising their costs and making it impossible for them to compete 21 effectively. As a result of the UFC’s exclusionary scheme, multiple actual or potential rivals were 22 forced to sell to the UFC or exit the market entirely. Id. ¶ 11. 23 By following no objective ranking or title criteria, the UFC is able to exert control over its 24 roster of athletes who risk losing the opportunity to be afforded “title bouts” or to earn a living as 25 an MMA fighter. Id. ¶ 17. 26 2. Output Market 27 Defendant acquired and maintained monopoly power in the Relevant Output Market 28 through a series of exclusionary acts, including (a) direct acquisitions of actual or potential rivals -3- 1 (who were forced to sell to the UFC because they found it impossible to compete profitably due to 2 the UFC’s anticompetitive scheme), as well as (b) a multifaceted scheme to impair and foreclose 3 competition by leveraging the UFC’s market dominance—including its tight-fisted control over 4 the supply of Elite Professional MMA Fighters—to block actual or potential rivals from accessing 5 inputs. Id. ¶ 9. 6 B. Procedural History 7 On June 4, 2015, the five above-captioned cases were transferred into this District pursuant 8 to an order transferring them from the Northern District of California. Plaintiffs and Defendant 9 filed a Notice of Related Cases in all five cases. ECF Order No. 101 at 2. The Court summarizes the procedural history for the lead case, 2:15-cv-01045-RFB-PAL, 10 11 12 13 below: On December 16, 2014, Plaintiffs filed their Complaint in the Northern District of California. ECF No. 1. 14 On January 30, 2015, Defendant filed a Motion to Transfer case. ECF No. 31. 15 On February 10, 2015, Plaintiffs filed a Motion to Consolidate Cases. ECF No. 52. 16 On February 27, 2015, Defendant filed a Motion to Dismiss. ECF No. 64. 17 On June 2, 2015, the Northern District of California GRANTED the Motion to Transfer 18 19 20 21 Case to the District of Nevada. ECF No. 93. On September 25, 2015, the Court held a hearing on the parties’ outstanding motions in the various cases. ECF No. 186. The Court issued a minute order stating the following: • Case no. 2:15-cv-01045-RFB-PAL 22 o Motion to Dismiss (ECF No. 64) is DENIED; 23 o Stipulation of Electronically Stored Information (ECF No. 160) is GRANTED; 24 25 • Case no. 2:15-cv-01046-RFB-PAL, Motion to Dismiss (ECF No. 16) is DENIED; 26 • Case no. 2:15-cv-01055-RFB-PAL, Motion to Dismiss (ECF No. 39) is DENIED; 27 • Case no. 2:15-cv-01056-RFB-PAL, Motion to Dismiss (ECF No. 39) is DENIED; 28 • Case no. 2:15-cv-01057-RFB-PAL, Motion to Dismiss (ECF No. 16) is DENIED. -4- 1 III. LEGAL STANDARD A. Sherman Act, Section 2 2 1. Monopoly 3 4 Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire 5 with any other person or persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among the 6 several States, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of a felony, and, on conviction 7 thereof, shall be punished by fine not exceeding $100,000,000 if a corporation, or, if any other 8 person, $1,000,000, or by imprisonment not exceeding 10 years, or by both said punishments, in 9 the discretion of the court. 15 U.S.C. § 2. 10 “To succeed on its claim for actual monopolization under § 2, [plaintiff] must prove 11 [defendant]: (i) possessed monopoly power in the relevant markets; (ii) willfully acquired or 12 maintained its monopoly power through exclusionary conduct; and (iii) caused antitrust injury. 13 Am. Prof'l Testing Serv., Inc. v. Harcourt Brace Jovanovich Legal & Prof'l Publications, Inc., 108 14 F.3d 1147, 1151 (9th Cir. 1997) (citing Movie 1 & 2 v. United Artists, 909 F.2d 1245, 1254 (9th 15 Cir.1990), cert. denied, 501 U.S. 1230 (1991)). a. Monopoly power 16 17 “Monopoly power is defined as ‘the power to control prices or exclude competition.’ Mere 18 proof of exclusionary conduct is not sufficient to prove [defendant’s] dangerous probability of 19 success; other proof of market power is required.” Harcourt, 108 F.3d at 1154 (internal citations 20 omitted). 21 “Market power may be demonstrated through either of two types of proof. One type of 22 proof is direct evidence of the injurious exercise of market power. If the plaintiff puts forth 23 evidence of restricted output and supracompetitive prices, that is direct proof of the injury to 24 competition which a competitor with market power may inflict, and thus, of the actual exercise of 25 market power.” Rebel Oil Co. v. Atl. Richfield Co., 51 F.3d 1421, 1434 (9th Cir. 1995). “The 26 more common type of proof is circumstantial evidence pertaining to the structure of the market. 27 To demonstrate market power circumstantially, a plaintiff must: (1) define the relevant market, (2) 28 show that the defendant owns a dominant share of that market, and (3) show that there are -5- 1 significant barriers to entry and show that existing competitors lack the capacity to increase their 2 output in the short run.” Id. 3 “A ‘market’ is any grouping of sales whose sellers, if unified by a monopolist or a 4 hypothetical cartel, would have market power in dealing with any group of buyers.” Id. “Stated 5 differently, a ‘market’ is the group of sellers or producers who have the ‘actual or potential ability 6 to deprive each other of significant levels of business.’” Id. (internal citation omitted). “First and 7 foremost, the relevant market must be a product market. The consumers do not define the 8 boundaries of the market; the products or producers do.” Id. (citing Brown Shoe v. United States, 9 370 U.S. 294, 325 (1962)). “Second, the market must encompass the product at issue as well as all 10 economic substitutes for the product.” Id. “Third, although the general market must include all 11 economic substitutes, it is legally permissible to premise antitrust allegations on a submarket.” Id. 12 Regarding dominant share, the Ninth Circuit has held that a “market share of 44 percent is 13 sufficient as a matter of law to support a finding of market power, if entry barriers are high and 14 competitors are unable to expand their output in response to supracompetitive pricing.” Rebel Oil, 15 51 F.3d at 1438. 16 “Entry barriers are ‘additional long-run costs that were not incurred by incumbent firms 17 but must be incurred by new entrants,’ or ‘factors in the market that deter entry while permitting 18 incumbent firms to earn monopoly returns.’” Id. at 1439 (internal citations omitted). “The main 19 sources of entry barriers are: (1) legal license requirements; (2) control of an essential or superior 20 resource; (3) entrenched buyer preferences for established brands; (4) capital market evaluations 21 imposing higher capital costs on new entrants; and, in some situations, (5) economies of scale.” 22 Id. “To justify a finding that a defendant has the power to control prices, entry barriers must be 23 significant—they must be capable of constraining the normal operation of the market to the extent 24 that the problem is unlikely to be self-correcting.” Id. On the other hand, “[b]arriers to entry are 25 insignificant when natural market forces will likely cure the problem.” 26 27 b. Willfully acquired/maintained conduct 28 -6- through exclusionary 1 The second factor in determining a monopoly focuses on whether defendant “willfully 2 acquired or maintained monopoly power by engaging in predatory or anticompetitive conduct 3 designed to destroy competition.” Movie 1 & 2 v. United Artists Commc'ns, Inc., 909 F.2d 1245, 4 1255 (9th Cir. 1990). 5 Determining what constitutes exclusionary conduct can be complex. “Under the best of 6 circumstances, applying the requirements of § 2 ‘can be difficult’ because ‘the means of illicit 7 exclusion, like the means of legitimate competition, are myriad.’” Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law 8 Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 414 (2004) (internal citation omitted). For 9 example, “[t]hey may involve a ‘course of dealing’ that, even if profitable, indicates a ‘willingness 10 to forsake short-term profits to achieve an anticompetitive end.’” Pac. Bell Tel. Co. v. Linkline 11 Commc'ns, Inc., 555 U.S. 438, 458 (2009) (quoting Trinko, 540 U.S. at 409). 12 In the Ninth Circuit, there must be a “‘preliminary showing of significant and more-than- 13 temporary harmful effects on competition (and not merely upon a competitor or customer)’ before 14 these practices can rise to the level of exclusionary conduct.” Am. Prof'l Testing Serv., Inc. v. 15 Harcourt Brace Jovanovich Legal & Prof'l Publications, Inc., 108 F.3d 1147, 1151 (9th Cir. 1997). 16 Such conduct may be inferred. For example, “[t]he showing of a possible split agreement is one 17 piece of circumstantial evidence from which a jury may infer a willful acquisition or maintenance 18 of monopoly power. Market share is another. The fact that [defendant] acquired its prior competitor 19 [], thus eliminating its only serious competition in the market, is further evidence of anti- 20 competitive conduct on the part of [defendant].” Id. In that case, the Ninth Circuit dismissed 21 defendant’s motion for summary judgment. 22 However, certain acts, such as discount pricing alone, may not rise to the level of 23 exclusionary conduct: “the exclusionary conduct element of a claim arising under § 2 of the 24 Sherman Act cannot be satisfied by reference to bundled discounts unless the discounts result in 25 prices that are below an appropriate measure of the defendant's costs.” Cascade Health Solutions 26 v. PeaceHealth, 515 F.3d 883, 903 (9th Cir. 2008). 27 c. Caused antitrust injury 28 -7- 1 “To show antitrust injury, a plaintiff must prove that his loss flows from an anticompetitive 2 aspect or effect of the defendant's behavior, since it is inimical to the antitrust laws to award 3 damages for losses stemming from acts that do not hurt competition. If the injury flows from 4 aspects of the defendant's conduct that are beneficial or neutral to competition, there is no antitrust 5 injury, even if the defendant's conduct is illegal per se.” Rebel Oil, 51 F.3d at 1433. 6 “In deciding whether the plaintiff was injured by an anticompetitive aspect or effect of the 7 defendant's behavior, care must be taken in defining ‘competition.’ Competition consists of rivalry 8 among competitors… But reduction of competition does not invoke the Sherman Act until it harms 9 consumer welfare.” Id. 10 2. Monopsony 11 The Supreme Court characterizes a monopsony as follows: “Monopsony power is market 12 power on the buy side of the market. As such, a monopsony is to the buy side of the market what 13 a monopoly is to the sell side and is sometimes colloquially called a ‘buyer's monopoly.’” 14 Weyerhaeuser Co. v. Ross-Simmons Hardwood Lumber Co., 549 U.S. 312, 320 (2007). 15 Citing Weyerhaeuser, the Ninth Circuit found that “[t]he Supreme Court has made 16 clear…that because antitrust law operates to correct all distortions of competition, it condemns 17 market actors who distort competition, whether on the buyer side or seller side … Accordingly, 18 the Court has long understood the Sherman Act to condemn buyer side cartels.” California ex rel. 19 Harris v. Safeway, Inc., 651 F.3d 1118, 1161 (9th Cir. 2011) 20 While monopsonies and monopolies share many similarities, there are circumstances in 21 which only monopsonistic, but not monopolistic behavior, is alleged. See United States v. Syufy 22 Enterprises, 903 F.2d 659, 663 (9th Cir. 1990) “[O]f significance is the government's concession 23 that [the defendant] was only a monopsonist, not a monopolist. Thus, the government argues that 24 [the defendant] had market power, but that it exercised this power only against its suppliers (film 25 distributors), not against its consumers (moviegoers).” 26 In Syufy, the Court noted that “[w]hile it is theoretically possible to have a middleman who 27 is a monopolist upstream but not downstream, this is a somewhat counterintuitive scenario. Why, 28 if he truly had significant market power, would Raymond Syufy have chosen to take advantage of -8- 1 the big movie distributors while giving a fair shake to ordinary people? And why do the 2 distributors, the alleged victims of the monopolization scheme, think that Raymond Syufy is the 3 best thing that ever happened to the Las Vegas movie market? The answers to these questions are 4 significant because, like all antitrust cases, this one must make economic sense.” Id. 5 In this case, as in Weyerhaeuser, the Plaintiffs allege that the Defendant engaged in both 6 monopolistic and monopsonistic behavior. The Supreme Court applies the monopoly test 7 regarding predatory pricing, to their analysis of whether the Defendant engaged in a monopsony: 8 “The general theoretical similarities of monopoly and monopsony combined with the theoretical 9 and practical similarities of predatory pricing and predatory bidding convince us that our two- 10 pronged Brooke Group test should apply to predatory-bidding claims.” Weyerhaeuser, 549 U.S. at 11 325. Therefore, the Court applies the standard for monopoly under Section 2 of the Sherman Act. 12 B. Motion to Dismiss under Rule 12(b)(6) 13 An initial pleading must contain “a short and plain statement of the claim showing that the 14 pleader is entitled to relief.” Fed. R. Civ. P. 8(a). The court may dismiss a complaint for failing to 15 state a claim upon which relief can be granted. Fed. R. Civ. P. 12(b)(6). 16 In ruling on a motion to dismiss, “[a]ll well-pleaded allegations of material fact in the 17 complaint are accepted as true and are construed in the light most favorable to the non-moving 18 party.” Faulkner v. ADT Sec. Servs., Inc., 706 F.3d 1017, 1019 (9th Cir. 2013) (citations omitted). 19 To survive a motion to dismiss, a complaint need not contain “detailed factual allegations,” 20 but merely asserting “‘labels and conclusions’ or ‘a formulaic recitation of the elements of a cause 21 of action’” is not sufficient. Ashcroft v. Iqbal, 556 U.S. 662, 678 (2009) (quoting Bell Atlantic 22 Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544, 555 (2007)). “As a general rule, a district court may not consider 23 any material beyond the pleadings in ruling on a Rule 12(b)(6) motion.” Lee v. City of Los 24 Angeles, 250 F.3d 668, 688 (9th Cir. 2001) (citation and internal quotation marks omitted). 25 C. Motion to Dismiss a Sherman Act Claim 26 “In order to state a valid claim under the Sherman Act, a plaintiff must allege that the 27 defendant has market power within a ‘relevant market.’ That is, the plaintiff must allege both that 28 -9- 1 a ‘relevant market’ exists and that the defendant has power within that market.” Newcal Indus., 2 Inc. v. Ikon Office Solution, 513 F.3d 1038, 1044 (9th Cir. 2008). 3 “There is no requirement that these elements of the antitrust claim be pled with specificity.” 4 Newcal, 513 F.3d at 1045. “An antitrust complaint therefore survives a Rule 12(b)(6) motion 5 unless it is apparent from the face of the complaint that the alleged market suffers a fatal legal 6 defect. And since the validity of the ‘relevant market’ is typically a factual element rather than a 7 legal element, alleged markets may survive scrutiny under Rule 12(b)(6) subject to factual testing 8 by summary judgment or trial.” Id. See Cost Mgmt. Servs., Inc. v. Washington Natural Gas Co., 9 99 F.3d 937, 950 (9th Cir. 1996) (“In order to survive a motion to dismiss under Rule 12(b)(6), an 10 antitrust complaint ‘need only allege sufficient facts from which the court can discern the elements 11 of an injury resulting from an act forbidden by the antitrust laws.’ CMS's complaint should not be 12 dismissed unless it appears beyond doubt that CMS can prove no set of facts in support of its claim 13 which would entitle it to relief”) (quoting Newman v. Universal Pictures, 813 F.2d 1519, 1522 14 (9th Cir.1987), cert. denied, 486 U.S. 1059 (1988).; SmileCare Dental Group v. Delta Dental Plan 15 of California, Inc., 88 F.3d 780, 783 (9th Cir.1996)). 16 “There are, however, some legal principles that govern the definition of an antitrust 17 ‘relevant market,’ and a complaint may be dismissed under Rule 12(b)(6) if the complaint's 18 ‘relevant market’ definition is facially unsustainable.” Newcal, 513 F.3d at 1045. 19 20 21 22 23 IV. DISCUSSION Defendant makes three main arguments as to why the case should be dismissed under Rule 12(b)(6). The Court addresses each argument below. A. Strong Competition v. Antitrust Violation 24 While Defendant attempts to characterize its own behavior as “strong competition,” the 25 Court does not construe Plaintiffs’ Complaint to allege that Zuffa’s behavior is merely “strong 26 competition.” Rather, Plaintiffs argue that Zuffa’s conduct “has foreclosed competition and 27 thereby enhanced and maintained the UFC’s monopoly power in the Relevant Output Market and 28 - 10 - 1 monopsony power in the Relevant Input Market.” Compl. at ¶ 5. These claims state an antitrust 2 violation. The Court rejects Defendant’s first argument. B. Properly Defined Relevant Markets 3 4 Because the Court construes the need for a plaintiff alleging a Sherman Act Section 2 claim 5 to define a “relevant market” in order to survive a motion to dismiss, the Court focuses its attention 6 on this specific argument. See Newcal, 513 F.3d at 1044-45. 7 In their Complaint, Plaintiffs refer to two relevant markets: “live Elite Professional MMA 8 bouts (the ‘Relevant Output Market’), and … live Elite Professional MMA Fighter services (the 9 ‘Relevant Input Market’).” Compl. at ¶ 4. Plaintiffs define “Elite Professional MMA Fighter” as 10 the following: “any Professional MMA Fighter who has demonstrated success through 11 competition in local and/or regional MMA promotions, or who has developed significant public 12 notoriety amongst MMA Industry media and the consuming audience through demonstrated 13 success in athletic competition. All UFC Fighters are Elite Professional MMA Fighters.” Compl. 14 ¶ 30(d). 15 Defendants argue that “[b]oth of Plaintiffs’ market definitions are based on what the 16 Complaints describe as ‘Elite Professional MMA fighters,’ a term not used in the industry and 17 apparently created solely for the purpose of this litigation. Plaintiffs do not define the contours of 18 these markets, particularly in what distinguishes an ‘Elite’ fighter from other Professional MMA 19 fighters, in any understandable, much less a legally cognizable, way.” Mot. Dismiss at 17. In 20 support of this argument, Zuffa argues that “courts have repeatedly rejected attempts to define 21 narrow antitrust markets by subjective, vague terms purporting to reflect alleged qualitative 22 differences because such distinctions are “economically meaningless where the differences are 23 actually a spectrum of price and quality differences.” Mot. Dismiss at 18 (citing In re Super 24 Premium Ice Cream Distrib. Antitrust Litig., 691 F. Supp. 1262, 1268 (N.D. Cal. 1988)). 25 The Court finds that Defendant cites to no controlling case law, and that on the contrary, 26 the Ninth Circuit has held that, with regards to the requisite specificity needed to define the 27 “relevant market” in a Section 2 Sherman Act claim, “[a]n antitrust complaint [] survives a Rule 28 12(b)(6) motion unless it is apparent from the face of the complaint that the alleged market suffers - 11 - 1 a fatal legal defect. And since the validity of the ‘relevant market’ is typically a factual element 2 rather than a legal element, alleged markets may survive scrutiny under Rule 12(b)(6) subject to 3 factual testing by summary judgment or trial.” Newcal, 513 F.3d at 1045. Here, Defendant does 4 not argue that the Complaint suffers from a facial deficiency. Rather, Defendant attempts to argue 5 that the term “elite” is subjective and vague. 6 Plaintiffs argue that the “Elite” designation is well understood in the industry. Opp’n at 5. 7 Plaintiffs argue that the UFC has cornered the “elite” market. As a result, Plaintiffs allege that “the 8 UFC controls the talents of Elite Professional MMA Fighters, who are popular with national 9 audiences.” Compl. at ¶ 5. This is supported by allegations that “[w]ithout big-ticket MMA Cards 10 with Elite Professional MMA Fighters, MMA Promoters are unable to generate sufficient public 11 demand to lock down sponsors and venues large enough to generate enough revenues to be able 12 to offer sufficient bout purses that would enable them to attract Elite Professional MMA Fighters.” 13 Compl. at ¶ 108. 14 Plaintiffs also argues that “the MMA industry itself distinguishes Elite from non-Elite 15 Fighters: the UFC has identified its fighters as “elite[-]level;” investment analysts like Moody’s 16 describes UFC’s market dominance based on its ‘elite’ fighters; and fighters, fan blogs and 17 websites use the same terms.” Opp’n at 6, n.6. 18 Last, the Plaintiffs argue, and the Court agrees, that the Supreme Court has recognized 19 distinctions in different levels of athletic competitions to constitute a relevant market for the 20 purpose of the Sherman Act: “championship boxing is the ‘cream’ of the boxing business, and … 21 is a sufficiently separate part of the trade or commerce to constitute the relevant market for 22 Sherman Act purposes.” Int'l Boxing Club of N. Y., Inc. v. United States, 358 U.S. 242, 252 23 (1959). This finding was supported by the large gap between the championship and non- 24 championship markets such as: average revenue; the costs of television rights; revenues for movie 25 rights compared to the non-existence of non-championship picture rights; and the amount that 26 spectators pay for tickets to championship fights than for nontitle fights. Id. at 250-51. 27 28 Defendant replies by arguing that, in these cases, the market was defined around “objective, clearly definable categories such as particular leagues, divisions, or events.” Reply at 10. - 12 - 1 The Court understands that distinctions of elite and non-elite status, the “relevant market,” 2 will vary from sport to sport. See United States v. E. I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 3 404 (1956) (“The ‘market’ which one must study to determine when a producer has monopoly 4 power will vary with the part of commerce under consideration.”). To find whether the Plaintiffs 5 defined a relevant market within a sport, therefore, the Court must take into consideration how 6 athletes in their respective fields are ranked with regards to one another. 7 Plaintiffs alleges that through UFC's monopolistic/monopsonistic power over the relevant 8 input and output markets, the UFC has created the exact championship league held to be the 9 relevant market in other sporting contexts: “The UFC is an individual sport that issues 10 championship titles to athletes competing in, and winning, title bouts. The UFC follows no 11 independent ranking criteria, nor does it establish any objective criteria for obtaining a title bout. 12 By following no objective criteria, the UFC is able to exert considerable control over its roster of 13 athletes who risk losing the opportunity to be afforded ‘title bouts’ or to earn a living as an MMA 14 fighter.” Compl. ¶17. The Court therefore finds that the Plaintiffs’ relevant market is sufficient 15 for Section 2 purposes. Plaintiffs allege that the elite market is captured by UFC and that elite 16 status is reflected in part by the amount of media attention elite MMA fighters receive. 17 Second and related, Defendant argues that “Plaintiffs’ allegation that ‘all or virtually all . . 18 . Elite Professional MMA fighters’ are under contract to the UFC is just a tautology to create a 19 single-brand market comprised solely of UFC fighters under a different name.” Mot. Dismiss at 20 18-19. In support of this argument, Defendant argues that “Courts’ acceptance of such circular, 21 single-brand markets ‘are, at a minimum, extremely rare.’” Id. (quoting Apple, Inc. v. Psystar 22 Corp., 586 F. Supp. 2d 1190, 1198 (N.D. Cal. 2008). 23 The Court finds this argument unpersuasive. Plaintiffs’ theory is that the UFC has acquired 24 monosopnistic power over the Elite Fighters services market, which necessarily means that the 25 market is a single-brand market. Further, Defendant fails to cite to controlling case law in support 26 of its position. Therefore, the Court rejects Defendant’s argument that the term “elite” is so vague 27 or circular as to render Plaintiff’s relevant market “legal defective.” “And since the validity of the 28 ‘relevant market’ is typically a factual element rather than a legal element, alleged markets may - 13 - 1 survive scrutiny under Rule 12(b)(6) subject to factual testing by summary judgment or trial.” 2 Newcal, 513 F.3d at 1044. 3 C. Specificity of Anticompetitive Conduct 4 Third, Zuffa argues that: 1) exclusive dealing arrangements are common, procompetitive, 5 and an integral feature of the sports and entertainment businesses; 2) Plaintiffs failed to allege 6 specific facts plausibly showing that Zuffa’s exclusive dealing arrangements foreclose competition 7 in either relevant market. Zuffa further argues that Plaintiffs fail to show: substantial foreclosure 8 of athletics; foreclosure in competition for exclusive contracts; duration of exclusivity; percentage 9 of market foreclosure; foreclosure of event venues; substantial foreclosure of sponsors; substantial 10 foreclosure of television distribution outlets; and 3) the UFC has no duty to deal with competitors. 11 Because the Court does not construe Plaintiffs’ Complaint to argue that UFC must “deal with” 12 competitors but, rather, Plaintiffs argue that UFC’s behavior is anticompetitive, the Court 13 addresses only the first two arguments. 14 As stated previously, “to state a valid claim under the Sherman Act, a plaintiff must allege 15 that the defendant has market power within a ‘relevant market.’” Newcal, 513 F.3d at 1044. “There 16 is no requirement that these elements of the antitrust claim be pled with specificity.” Id. at 1045. 17 Therefore the Plaintiff need not plead specific facts plausibly showing that the exclusivity 18 provisions in Zuffa’s contracts are anticompetitive. Rather, in the Ninth Circuit, there must be a 19 “‘preliminary showing of significant and more-than-temporary harmful effects on competition 20 (and not merely upon a competitor or customer)’ before these practices can rise to the level of 21 exclusionary conduct.” Am. Prof'l Testing Serv., 108 F.3d at 1151. Such conduct may be inferred, 22 for example, by market share. Id. “[E]xclusive dealing arrangement violates Section 1 only if its 23 effect is to ‘foreclose competition in a substantial share of the line of commerce affected.’ Allied 24 Orthopedic Appliances Inc. v. Tyco Health Care Grp. LP, 592 F.3d 991, 996 (9th Cir. 2010). 25 Plaintiffs identity various clauses in UFC’s exclusivity contracts that are anticompetitive. 26 See Compl. ¶ 113. These contracts contain an “Exclusivity Clause,” which restricts fighters from 27 appearing in other rival MMA events and includes various termination and extension clauses that 28 can be triggered at the UFC’s sole discretion, thereby effectively extending the exclusivity - 14 - 1 provisions indefinitely. Compl. ¶ 113(a). The “Champion’s Clause” prevents fighters from 2 soliciting competing bids from other MMA Promotions even after the end of his or her original 3 UFC contract term. Id. ¶113(b). The “Right to First Offer” and “Right to Match” Clauses, grant 4 the UFC the option to match the financial terms and conditions of any offer made to a UFC Fighter 5 for an MMA bout even after the Fighter’s contract has expired. Id. ¶113(c). The “Ancillary Rights 6 Clause” grants the UFC exclusive and perpetual worldwide personality and Identity rights not only 7 of the UFC Fighter, but of “all persons associated with” the athlete, in any medium, including 8 merchandising, video games and broadcasts, and for all other commercial purposes, thus 9 preventing MMA Fighters from financially benefiting from the reputations that they built during 10 their MMA careers even after death, and locking UFC Fighters out of revenues generated by the 11 exploitation of their Identities, including after the term of the contract. Id. ¶113(d). The “Promotion 12 Clause” requires UFC Fighters to attend, cooperate and assist in the promotion of bouts in which 13 they fight and, as required by the UFC, any other bouts, events, broadcasts, press conferences and 14 sale of merchandise, for no additional compensation. Id. ¶113(e). Last, contracts contain a 15 “Retirement Clause,” which gives the UFC the power “to retain the rights to a retired fighter in 16 perpetuity.” Id. ¶113(f). 17 Defendant argues that its exclusive dealing agreements are insufficient to establish 18 anticompetitive behavior, particularly in the competitive sports context and that Plaintiffs must 19 allege facts showing that the “effect is to ‘foreclose competition in a substantial share of the line 20 of commerce affected.’” Allied Orthopedic Appliances Inc. v. Tyco Health Care Grp., LP, 592 21 F.3d 991, 996 (9th Cir. 2010). 22 However, Plaintiffs allege multiple acts that, as a whole, constitute an anticompetitive 23 scheme. Exclusive dealing arrangements are but a part of this scheme. For example, Plaintiffs 24 allege that UFC’s exclusionary scheme included the use of threats, intimidation, and retaliation 25 against MMA fighters who work with or for would-be rivals or speak out against the UFC. Compl 26 ¶¶ 116-19. Therefore, Defendant has, “by successfully eliminating and impairing actual or 27 potential rivals in the Relevant Output Market … garnered and maintained unrivaled bargaining 28 power vis-à-vis Elite Professional MMA Fighters.” Compl. ¶ 111. Last, “[t]he UFC has also used - 15 - 1 its ill-gotten power in the Relevant Markets to restrict its actual or potential rivals’ access to top 2 quality venues, sponsors, endorsements, PPV and television broadcast outlets.” Compl. ¶ 73. 3 Plaintiffs allege that “[t]he anticompetitive effects associated with [defendant’s] [] monopsony 4 power manifest themselves as: artificially suppressed compensation for Elite Professional MMA 5 Fighters in the Bout Class, and the improper expropriation of Elite Professional MMA Fighters’ 6 Identities, resulting in artificial underpayments (including non-payment) to UFC Fighters in the 7 Identity Class.” Compl. ¶ 107. As a result, Plaintiffs further argue that the Defendant “now controls 8 approximately 90% of the revenues derived from live Elite Professional MMA bouts.” Compl. ¶ 9 7. 10 As the Ninth Circuit has held, “in the antitrust context, the ‘character and effect of a 11 conspiracy are not to be judged by dismembering it and viewing its separate parts, but only by 12 looking at it as a whole.’” Costco Wholesale Corp. v. Maleng, 522 F.3d 874, 886 (9th Cir. 2008) 13 (quoting Continental Ore Co. v. Union Carbide & Carbon Corp., 370 U.S. 690, 699 (1962)). 14 Defendant replies by characterizing these various allegations as a “monopoly broth,” which 15 it argues is insufficient to establish anticompetitive conduct. However, Defendant overlooks the 16 scheme that Plaintiff alleges, and concerns itself instead with the validity of the exclusive dealing 17 agreements. Defendant argues that, because exclusive dealing arrangements are legal, the entire 18 scheme should be deemed such. Reply at 4. 19 The Court disagrees with the contention that a single element of a scheme, if legal, makes 20 legal the conduct as a whole. One of the cases Defendant cites in its own brief belies this claim: 21 “it would not be proper to focus on specific individual acts of an accused monopolist while refusing 22 to consider their overall combined effect. … We are not dealing with a mathematical equation. We 23 are dealing with what has been called the ‘synergistic effect’ of the mixture of the elements.” City 24 of Anaheim v. S. California Edison Co., 955 F.2d 1373, 1376 (9th Cir. 1992). Only where “we are 25 shown is a number of perfectly legal acts, [does] it become[] much more difficult to find overall 26 wrongdoing.” Id. 27 /// 28 /// - 16 - 1 The Court therefore finds that, as a whole, Plaintiffs plead facts showing that the scheme 2 is anticompetitive such that the “effect is to ‘foreclose competition in a substantial share of the line 3 of commerce affected.’” Allied Orthopedic, 592 F.3d at 996. 4 D. Ancillary Rights and Reduced Competition 5 Specifically, Zuffa argues that: 1) name and likeness licenses are common and 6 procompetitive; 2) contractual restrictions on the use of the UFC name and marks are the legitimate 7 exercise of Zuffa’s intellectual property rights and are not anticompetitive; and 3) Plaintiffs’ 8 identity rights claims do not state an antitrust violation. 9 Applying the analysis above regarding exclusive dealing contracts, which include the 10 ancillary rights clause, the Court finds that as a whole, Plaintiffs have pled facts showing that the 11 scheme is anticompetitive such that the “effect is to ‘foreclose competition in a substantial share 12 of the line of commerce affected.’” Allied Orthopedic, 592 F.3d at 996. In light of the sufficiency 13 of the allegations of the Complaint, and given the pleading standard set out in Fed. R. Civ. P. 14 12(b)(6) and with regards to the Sherman Act in particular, the Court finds the Plaintiffs have 15 sufficiently stated the second factor of a Section 2 claim: that the Defendant maintained its 16 monopolistic/monopsonistic power by allegedly anticompetitive behavior. 17 E. Anticompetitive Effect of Zuffa’s Acquisitions 18 Defendant argues that: 1) all but one of the acquisitions that Plaintiffs discuss occurred 19 outside the applicable four-year statute of limitations; 2) Plaintiffs have not pled facts showing 20 plausible high barriers to entry in the promotion of MMA bouts; 3) Plaintiffs have not pled any 21 specific, plausible allegations from which the court could conclude that the Strikeforce acquisition 22 had any anticompetitive effect; and 4) Plaintiffs fail to plead specific facts showing that the 23 acquisitions have reduced output. 24 At the pleading stage, the Court need only find that the Plaintiffs have “allege[d] sufficient 25 facts from which the court can discern the elements of an injury resulting from an act forbidden 26 by the antitrust laws.’” Cost Mgmt. Servs., Inc. v. Washington Natural Gas Co., 99 F.3d 937, 950 27 (9th Cir. 1996). “To show antitrust injury, a plaintiff must prove that his loss flows from an 28 anticompetitive aspect or effect of the defendant's behavior” Rebel Oil, 51 F.3d at 1433 - 17 - 1 Plaintiffs allege multiple antitrust injuries: “As a result of the UFC’s scheme: (i) 2 compensation associated with fighting in MMA bouts to members of the Bout Class has been and 3 continues to be artificially suppressed, and (ii) the Identities of UFC Fighters continues to be 4 expropriated and compensation by the UFC and its licensees for the expropriation of, exploitation 5 of and right to exploit Identities of the members of the Identity Class has been and continues to be 6 artificially suppressed. In addition, the anticompetitive effects of the UFC’s exclusionary scheme 7 in the Relevant Markets include, inter alia: A) reduced competitiveness of live Elite Professional 8 MMA events; B) artificially suppressed output in the Relevant Output Market, including reduced 9 number of live Elite Professional MMA bouts than would exist in the absence of the challenged 10 anticompetitive scheme; and, C) artificially suppressed demand in the Relevant Input Market.” 11 Compl. ¶ 151. In light of these alleged injuries, the Court finds that the Plaintiff has sufficiently plead 12 13 antitrust injuries sufficient to survive a motion to dismiss. 14 15 V. CONCLUSION 16 IT IS ORDERED that in the following: 17 Case no. 2:15-cv-01045-RFB-PAL Motion to Dismiss (ECF No. 64) is DENIED; 18 Stipulation of Electronically Stored Information (ECF No. 160) is GRANTED; 19 Case no. 2:15-cv-01046-RFB-PAL, Motion to Dismiss (ECF No. 16) is DENIED; 20 Case no. 2:15-cv-01055-RFB-PAL, Motion to Dismiss (ECF No. 39) is DENIED; 21 Case no. 2:15-cv-01056-RFB-PAL, Motion to Dismiss (ECF No. 39) is DENIED; 22 Case no. 2:15-cv-01057-RFB-PAL, Motion to Dismiss (ECF No. 16) is DENIED. 23 DATED: October 19, 2016. 24 __________________________________ RICHARD F. BOULWARE, II UNITED STATES DISTRICT JUDGE 25 26 27 28 - 18 -

Disclaimer: Justia Dockets & Filings provides public litigation records from the federal appellate and district courts. These filings and docket sheets should not be considered findings of fact or liability, nor do they necessarily reflect the view of Justia.


Why Is My Information Online?