US Airways, Inc., for American Airlines, Inc. as Successor and Real Party in Interest v. Sabre Holdings Corporation et al
Filing
882
OPINION AND ORDER re: #805 MOTION for Judgment as a Matter of Law on Count I or in the Alternative for a New Trial on Count I. filed by Sabre GLBL Inc., Sabre Holdings Corporation, Sabre Travel International Limited. For the foregoing reasons, Sabre's motion for judgment as a matter of law, or in the alternative for a new trial, on Count I pursuant to Rules 50 and 59 of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure is DENIED. (Signed by Judge Lorna G. Schofield on 3/21/2017) (kgo)
UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF NEW YORK
-------------------------------------------------------------X
:
US AIRWAYS, INC.,
:
Plaintiff,
:
:
-against:
:
SABRE HOLDINGS CORP., et al.,
:
Defendants. :
:
-------------------------------------------------------------X
3/21/2017
11 Civ. 2725 (LGS)
OPINION AND ORDER
LORNA G. SCHOFIELD, District Judge:
US Airways, Inc. (“US Airways”) brought antitrust claims against Sabre Holdings
Corporation, Sabre Travel International Ltd., and Sabre GLBL Inc. (collectively, “Sabre”), under
the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1 et seq., which were tried before a jury between October 24 and
December 20, 2016. The jury found in US Airways’ favor on one of the two claims tried. That
claim alleges that Sabre unreasonably restrained trade by imposing on US Airways
anticompetitive and unlawful contractual provisions that harmed competition and enabled Sabre
to charge US Airways higher booking fees than it would have been able to charge in a
competitive market. The jury awarded US Airways $5,098,142, or $15,294,426 after trebling.
Sabre has filed a motion for judgment as a matter of law under Federal Rule of Civil Procedure
50(b) on this claim or, in the alternative, for a new trial under Rules 50 and 59 of the Federal
Rules of Civil Procedure. For the reasons that follow, the motion is denied.
I.
BACKGROUND
A.
The Parties and the Claim
Defendant Sabre operates a global distribution system, and Sabre itself is referred to as a
“GDS.” Sabre is one of three GDSs in the United States. The GDSs provide computer services
that allow participating airlines and other travel providers to distribute schedule, fare and
booking information to travel agents. The GDSs also provide a means for travel agents to search
for, book and manage travel reservations.
Plaintiff US Airways1 is one of the airlines that participates in the Sabre distribution
system. US Airways and Sabre entered into successive contracts whereby Sabre distributed US
Airways’ flight and fare information to travel agents through the Sabre distribution system, and
US Airways paid Sabre a booking fee for its services whenever a US Airways ticket was sold
through Sabre. At issue is the parties’ contract that became effective on February 23, 2011 (the
“2011 Contract”).
B.
Summary of Relevant Pre-Trial Procedural History
US Airways commenced this action against Sabre on April 21, 2011, alleging four
antitrust violations under the Sherman Act. After a motion to dismiss, two of these claims
survived: (1) Count I, alleging vertical restraints of trade through contractual agreements with
airlines and travel agents containing anticompetitive provisions and (2) Count IV, alleging a
horizontal agreement among Sabre and its GDS competitors to limit competition among the
GDSs. Fact and expert discovery proceeded until 2014.
In January 2015, after the case was reassigned to me, Sabre’s motion for summary
judgment was granted in part. Among other limitations, US Airways’ damages were limited to
those suffered between February 23, 2011 -- when the 2011 Contract was signed -- and October
30, 2012 -- when a settlement agreement between the AMR Corporation and Sabre became
1
During the relevant period, US Airways was a stand-alone corporation. In December 2013, US
Airways Group and AMR Corporation, the parent company of American Airlines, Inc., merged
to form American Airlines Group, Inc., and US Airways became a wholly owned subsidiary of
American Airlines Group, Inc.
2
effective, barring American and any future merged parties (like US Airways) from suing for
harm suffered after that date.
In an effort to obtain a bench trial rather than a jury trial, US Airways filed an amended
complaint in July 2015, in effect waiving its estimated damages of $210 million after trebling
and seeking only declaratory relief and nominal damages not to exceed $20. Sabre made a
timely offer of judgment under Rule 68, agreeing to pay $20 in damages plus reasonable costs
and attorneys’ fees, and agreeing to entry of judgment without any admission of liability. US
Airways rejected the offer. Sabre then sought entry of judgment, arguing that its Rule 68 offer of
judgment provided US Airways with complete relief and that the outstanding demand for
declaratory judgment was moot. In September 2015, Sabre’s motion to dismiss the declaratory
judgment demand was granted, but Sabre’s motion to enter judgment was denied without
prejudice to renewal for technical reasons explained in the Court’s opinion.
Faced with the loss of its declaratory judgment claim and the likely recovery of only $20
in damages, US Airways filed a motion to restore the damages it had waived. The motion was
granted in December 2015, with the proviso that US Airways reimburse Sabre for its costs,
including attorneys’ fees, incurred in connection with US Airways’ efforts to obtain a bench trial.
US Airways fulfilled the condition, paying Sabre over $6 million, and filed its Third Amended
Complaint in March 2016.
Trial was set to commence on October 24, 2016. The parties filed seven Daubert
motions seeking to disqualify or limit the testimony of eight experts, and eleven motions in
limine. The motions were adjudicated between July and September 22, 2016, with the exception
of one motion that was reserved for trial.
On September 26, 2016, the Second Circuit issued its opinion in United States v. Am.
3
Express Co., 838 F.3d 179 (2d Cir. 2016) (“Amex”), the Second Circuit’s first decision
addressing two-sided markets in an antitrust case. Whether the market was two-sided or onesided was also a key issue in this action. Sabre moved for reconsideration of the summary
judgment denial in light of Amex, arguing that US Airways’ claims should be dismissed. On
October 10, 2016, Sabre’s motion for reconsideration was denied. On October 11, 2016, Sabre
sought an adjournment of the trial and the opportunity to re-brief the Daubert motions in light of
Amex. US Airways opposed the adjournment, even though US Airways had prepared its case
before Amex. Sabre’s application was denied.
A jury trial commenced on October 24, 2016, on the two surviving claims. The first
claim was that certain provisions of the parties’ 2011 Contract harmed competition and caused
US Airways to pay Sabre a supracompetitive booking fee, in violation of Section 1 of the
Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1. The second claim was that Sabre conspired with its two GDS
competitors to limit competition among them for airlines’ distribution business, in violation of
Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 2.
After nine weeks of trial, the jury returned a verdict. On Count I, the contract restraints
claim, the jury found that the relevant market was one-sided, that Sabre had unreasonably
restrained trade and that US Airways had been injured as a result. The jury awarded US Airways
$5,098,142 in damages, before trebling. On Count IV, the conspiracy claim, the jury found for
Sabre. In response to hypothetical questions on the verdict form, the jury also found that, even
assuming that the market were two-sided, Sabre unreasonably restrained trade, US Airways was
injured as a result and US Airways suffered the same damages of $5,098,142.
4
II.
LEGAL STANDARDS
A.
Standards for Judgment as a Matter of Law and for a New Trial
Sabre moves for judgment as a matter of law on Count I under Rule 50(b), Fed. R. Civ. P.
Judgment as a matter of law is appropriate “only if the court, viewing the evidence in the light
most favorable to the non-movant, concludes that a reasonable juror would have been compelled
to accept the view of the moving party.” MacDermid Printing Sols. LLC v. Cortron Corp., 833
F.3d 172, 180 (2d Cir. 2016) (citation omitted). “The court cannot assess the weight of
conflicting evidence, pass on the credibility of witnesses, or substitute its judgment for that of the
jury.” Wiercinski v. Mangia 57, Inc., 787 F.3d 106, 113 (2d Cir. 2015) (internal quotation marks
omitted). A Rule 50 motion may be granted only if “there exists such a complete absence of
evidence supporting the verdict that the jury’s findings could only have been the result of sheer
surmise and conjecture, or the evidence in favor of the movant is so overwhelming that
reasonable and fair minded [persons] could not arrive at a verdict against [it].” Warren v. Pataki,
823 F.3d 125, 139 (2d Cir. 2016) (quoting S.E.C. v. Ginder, 752 F.3d 569, 574 (2d Cir. 2014)
(alteration in original), cert. denied sub nom. Brooks v. Pataki, 137 S. Ct. 380 (2016).
Sabre moves in the alternative for a new trial under Rules 50 and 59(a). A court may
grant a new trial only where “the court determines, in its independent judgment, that the jury has
reached a seriously erroneous result or [if] its verdict is a miscarriage of justice.” Crawford v.
Tribeca Lending Corp., 815 F.3d 121, 128 (2d Cir. 2016) (internal quotation marks omitted). A
district court may grant a new trial “even if some evidence supports the verdict,” id., but
“precedent counsels that trial judges must exercise their ability to weigh credibility with caution
and great restraint, as a judge should rarely disturb a jury’s evaluation of a witness’s credibility.”
Raedle v. Credit Agricole Indosuez, 670 F.3d 411, 418 (2d Cir. 2012); accord In re Joint E. & S.
5
Dist. Asbestos Litig., 52 F.3d 1124, 1135 (2d Cir. 1995) (it is for the jury to decide between
conflicting expert testimony).
B.
The Legal Framework Governing US Airways’ Antitrust Claims
To protect competition in the marketplace, Section 1 of the Sherman Act prohibits
“[e]very contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of
trade or commerce.” 15 U.S.C. § 1. “To prove a § 1 violation, a plaintiff must demonstrate: (1)
a combination or some form of concerted action between at least two legally distinct economic
entities that (2) unreasonably restrains trade.” Amex, 838 F.3d at 193 (quoting Geneva Pharms.
Tech. Corp. v. Barr Labs. Inc., 386 F.3d 485, 606 (2d Cir. 2004)).
As US Airways does not allege that Sabre’s conduct challenged in Count I was illegal per
se, the claim is appropriately analyzed under the rule of reason. Id. at 193–94. Under the rule of
reason’s three-step burden-shifting framework, a plaintiff must show first that a defendant’s
actions had an adverse effect on competition in the relevant market. A plaintiff can satisfy this
first step by showing that the challenged restraints “had an actual adverse effect on competition
as a whole in the relevant market.” Id. at 194 (quoting Capital Imaging Assocs., P.C. v. Mohawk
Valley Med. Assocs., Inc., 996 F.2d 537, 546 (2d Cir. 1993)). Alternatively, a plaintiff can
establish anticompetitive effects indirectly by showing that the defendant has “sufficient market
power to cause an adverse effect on competition.” Id. (quoting Tops Mkts., Inc. v. Quality Mkts.,
Inc., 142 F.3d 90, 96 (2d Cir. 1998)). “A plaintiff seeking to use market power as a proxy for
adverse effect must show market power, plus some other ground for believing that the
challenged behavior could harm competition in the market . . . .” Id. at 195 (quoting Tops Mkts.,
142 F.3d at 97). Under either inquiry, the boundaries of the relevant product market and
geographic market are critical aspects of proving harm. Here, the parties agreed that the relevant
6
geographic market is the United States.
At the second step, the burden shifts to the defendant “to offer evidence of any
procompetitive effects of the restraint at issue.” Id. At the third step, “the burden shifts back to
the plaintiff[] to prove that any legitimate competitive benefits offered by defendant[] could have
been achieved through less restrictive means.” Id. (quoting Geneva Pharms., 386 F.3d at 507)
(alteration in original). Ultimately, “[t]he overarching standard is whether defendants’ actions
diminish overall competition, and hence consumer welfare.” Id. at 195 (quoting K.M.B.
Warehouse Distribs., Inc. v. Walker Mfg. Co., 61 F.3d 123, 128 (2d Cir. 1995)).
In addition to showing that a defendant’s behavior unreasonably restrained trade, a
plaintiff also must prove that a defendant’s violation of the antitrust laws caused the plaintiff to
suffer injury to its business or property. 15 U.S.C. § 15; Gelboim v. Bank of Am. Corp., 823 F.3d
759, 772–74 (2d Cir. 2016), cert. denied, 137 S. Ct. 814 (2017). If a defendant is found to have
violated the antitrust laws, the jury must then determine the amount of plaintiff’s damages, if
any.
III.
DISCUSSION
A.
Background
There was sufficient evidence introduced at trial from which the jury could reasonably
have found as follows:
1.
The History of the GDS Business
The GDSs use computerized reservation systems that evolved out of those developed by
the airlines for their own use beginning in the 1960s. (Tr. 964:23-965:1; 968:13-21.) These
systems were first made available to travel agents in the mid-1970s. (Id.) The airlines’ systems
offered not only their own fights and fares, but also those of other carriers in order to attract
7
users to their platform. (Tr. 977:21-978:2.) As the systems became more established, the
airlines began to charge other airlines booking fees for bookings made through their platform.
(Tr. 978:16-979:11.) In 1984, the Department of Justice and the Civil Aeronautics Board
concluded that the airlines had engaged in discriminatory pricing and began to regulate the
reservation systems. (Tr. 981:3; 979:7-11; PX-521.)
In 1992, the U.S. Department of Transportation (“DOT”) enacted a “mandatory
participation” rule, which required the airlines to offer the same flights and fares on other airline
reservation systems that they made available on their own systems. (Tr. 987:2-989:18.) This
rule was the genesis of some of the contractual provisions at issue in this case. The regulations
standardized the information available, thereby encouraging travel agents to search and book
through a single airline’s reservation system, a practice known as “single homing” that persists
today. (Tr. 989:21-990:9; 995:3-8; 995:23-996:5; 2117:4-2119:17.)
Around the same time as the 1992 rules were issued, airlines began divesting themselves
of the reservation systems business, creating GDSs that were independent of the airlines. (Tr.
990:15-991:4.) GDSs were also consolidating and the internet was beginning to change the way
that airline tickets were bought and sold. (Tr. 991:5-22.) In 2004, after 20 years of regulation,
the DOT deregulated the GDS industry. (Tr. 1006:3-8; PX-007.) The DOT found that each of
the GDSs had market power over most airlines because travel agents generally “single-homed”
and the airlines were dependent upon the GDSs to reach traditional travel agents. (PX-007.0013.0015.) However, the DOT expected that new technologies would create sufficient competition
in the airline ticket distribution market to erode the GDSs market power over time. (Tr. 997:61002:23; 1006:3-8, PX-007.003.)
8
2.
The GDS Business
Sabre is one of only three GDSs in the United States, with Amadeus and Travelport. (Tr.
448:6-12.) Sabre is the largest and controls over 50% of the market. (Tr. 1365:14-1366:1.)
Since deregulation, the number of GDS competitors has dropped from four to three. (Tr. 1004:18.) No new GDS has entered the market since the 1980s. (Tr. 962:24-963:1, 1006:9-10.) US
Airways estimated that 40% percent of its revenues were booked through Sabre, and another
25% through the other GDSs. (Tr. 202:15-203:6; PX 1178.0001.)
“Brick and mortar” travel agencies book almost exclusively through the GDSs. (Tr.
2034:1-16; 2039:25-2041:4; 2049:3-14.) These travel agencies’ clients are primarily corporate
travelers, who are higher value customers for airlines. (Tr. 202:4-14.) Travel agencies
frequently “single-home” with one GDS. In 2011, 94% of travel agency locations (i.e. travel
agency offices, sometimes within a large multi-office travel agency) used a single GDS. (PX1181.) Because of single-homing, US Airways must participate in each of the GDSs to reach the
corporate travelers whose travel agents book through that GDS. (Tr. 1254:1-20; 2031:2-21;
2059:5-2060:7.)
GDSs earn revenues through booking fees paid by the airlines and other travel providers.
(See Tr. 443:3-7; 452:21-23; 529:2-530:7; 978:16-19.) The GDSs do not charge travel agents for
GDS services. Instead, travel agencies receive incentive payments from GDSs, as well as
commission payments from airlines. (Tr. 1864:18-25; 2054:17-2057:6.) From 2006 through
2012, Sabre paid more than $1.2 billion in incentive fees to travel agents. (Tr. 1272:17-1273:7;
2057:17-2058:25; PX-766.) US Airways’ expert, Professor Joseph Stiglitz, opined that these
“incentive payments” serve to keep the travel agents loyal to its chosen GDS, but do not benefit
the airlines. (Tr. 1379:17-23; 1905:17-19; 5518:25-5519:6.)
9
3.
The Challenged Contractual Provisions
Starting in 2006, the US Airways’ contract with Sabre included the same or similar
provisions at issue here. Claims based on those provisions in the 2006 contract were dismissed
as time barred. The challenged restraints, collectively referred to as the “full content” provisions
(Tr. 5261:15-5262:25), as they appear in the parties’ 2011 Contract (PX-006) are:
A “No Discounts” provision, also referred to as a “parity” provision, prohibiting
US Airways from providing lower fares through other, non-Sabre, channels. The
contract specifically required that “in no case will the Fares provided through the
Sabre GDS for Bookings in the Sabre GDS . . . be more expensive or less
comprehensive than the Fares offered by [US Airways] via any Reservation
Outlet.” (PX-006.0013.)
A “No Surcharge” provision, preventing US Airways from charging or collecting
from travel agents a fee or higher prices for booking through Sabre. The contract
stated that US Airways “shall not charge to or collect from any Sabre Subscriber a
service fee or any similar charge.” (PX-006.0027.)
A “No Better Benefits” provision, requiring US Airways to provide Sabre GDS
service subscribers access to “the same types, amounts and levels of products,
services, functionality, enhancements, promotional opportunities, . . . incentives,
commissions, . . . benefits and rights” that US Airways offered to users of any
other booking channel. (PX-006.0003.)
A “No Direct Connects” provision, preventing US Airways from inducing travel
agents, or their customers, from directly connecting their reservation system with
the airlines’. The contract provided, “[US Airways] shall not require or induce
10
any Sabre Subscriber to book on any Participating Carrier Internet Site.” The
contract further stated, “[US Airways] will not . . . in any other manner
whatsoever require or provide commissions, compensation or other benefits or
rights . . . or otherwise encourage, promote or induce . . . Sabre Subscribers (or
their customers) to circumvent the Sabre GDS.” (PX-006.0004.)
After US Airways merged with America West Airlines in 2005, the airline tried
unsuccessfully to avoid the challenged restraints. (Tr. 186:21-189:4.) Ultimately, US Airways
had no choice but to accept them in the US Airways-Sabre 2006 contract for fear of being
removed from the Sabre GDS or being retaliated against, for example, through “display biasing,”
which means reordering search results as they appear in the system to disadvantage a particular
airline. (Tr. 190:19-193:3.) When the contract came up for renewal in 2011, US Airways again
was forced to accept the full content restrictions. (Tr. 523:8-13; 818:15-819:10; 840:5-9.)
The 2011 Contract requires US Airways to pay Sabre a booking fee of at least $3.41 per
flight segment booked through Sabre. (Tr. 1241:11-12; 1351:6-7; PX-006.0010.)
B.
The Relevant Market
“[M]arket definition is a deeply fact-intensive inquiry,” Todd v. Exxon Corp., 275 F.3d
191, 199 (2d Cir. 2001) (Sotomayor, J.), which requires consideration of the “commercial
realities” of competition. Amex, 838 F.3d at 197. Products or services are in the same relevant
product market if they are “reasonably interchangeable by consumers for the same purposes.”
Id. at 196 (quoting Geneva Pharms., 386 F.3d at 496). The purpose of market definition is “to
identify the market participants and competitive pressures that restrain an individual firm’s
ability to raise prices or restrict output.” Geneva Pharms., 386 F.3d at 496. The jury found that
Sabre had harmed competition “in the relevant market” and that the relevant market was a one-
11
sided market.
1.
Product Market for GDS Services
US Airways presented sufficient evidence for a reasonable jury to conclude that the
relevant product market is the market for GDS services linking airlines with traditional travel
agents that serve the vast majority of business travelers, but that the relevant market does not
include other means of distributing airline tickets, such as airline websites and online travel
agencies (e.g. Expedia, Travelocity), among others, because consumers do not view them as
reasonable substitutes for GDS services. (E.g., Tr. 1361:8-1365:12.)
Sabre does not challenge the sufficiency of the evidence. Sabre argues instead that US
Airways’ market definition is improper as a matter of law because US Airways explicitly
assumed the existence of the challenged contractual restraints in the relevant market analysis.
(E.g., Tr. 1365:1-8.) Sabre relies primarily on the Queen City Pizza, Inc. v. Domino’s Pizza,
Inc., 124 F.3d 430 (3d Cir. 1997), line of cases to argue that the relevant market must be defined
without reference to the challenged contractual restraints. See also Smugglers Notch
Homeowners’ Ass’n. Inc. v. Smugglers’ Notch Mgmt. Co., 414 F. App’x 372, 376–77 (2d Cir.
2011) (summary order). These cases are factually distinguishable and do not render Plaintiff’s
proposed relevant market deficient as a matter of law.
In Queen City, the Third Circuit affirmed the dismissal of antitrust claims because the
plaintiffs had failed to allege a valid relevant market. The plaintiffs were a group of Domino’s
Pizza franchisees who challenged contractual terms in the franchise agreement requiring them to
buy only Domino’s-approved ingredients and supplies. Queen City Pizza, 124 F.3d at 442–43.
The plaintiffs asserted monopoly and illegal tying claims, among others, alleging that the
relevant market was the market for ingredients and supplies used in Domino’s restaurants. Id. at
12
435. The Third Circuit rejected this narrow market definition, reasoning that pizza ingredients
and supplies from Domino’s and other suppliers are reasonably interchangeable, and that “[a]
court making a relevant market determination looks not to the contractual restraints assumed by a
particular plaintiff when determining whether a product is interchangeable, but to the uses to
which the product is put by consumers in general.” Id. at 438.
Critical to the Third Circuit’s analysis was that the plaintiff franchisees voluntarily
accepted the contractual restraints and were not forced to accept them as a consequence of the
defendant’s market power. Id. at 441. The Third Circuit observed, “Plaintiffs need not have
become Domino’s franchisees” and could have selected a different franchisor with different or
fewer contractual restrictions. Id. In other words, competition in the market for franchise
agreements constrained Domino’s ability to abuse its contractual power. Queen City thus
prohibits a market definition narrowed by contractual restraints that a counterparty willingly
assumes in a competitive market. See id. at 440; Newcal Indus., Inc. v. Ikon Office Sol., 513 F.3d
1038, 1048 (9th Cir. 2008) (“[T]he law prohibits an antitrust claimant from resting on market
power that arises solely from contractual rights that consumers knowingly and voluntarily gave
to the defendant (as in Queen City Pizza . . . ).”).
This case is factually distinguishable from Queen City. Here, Plaintiff presented ample
evidence that it had no choice but to accept Sabre’s contractual terms because of Sabre’s
economic market power. (Tr. 218:19-219:16; 474:9-18; 523:6-9; 1251:11-25.) Unlike Queen
City, where the court found that market power arose solely from the contracts, here, Plaintiff
presented evidence that market power arose from Sabre’s economic power and US Airways was
forced to accept the challenged contractual terms:
Sabre had over 50% of the bookings made in the GDS market, impacting a
13
significant portion of corporate travel bookings (see PX-751);
Corporate travel bookings represented the most lucrative segment of US Airways’
business and most travel agency locations ‘single-homed’ with a single GDS. (Tr.
202:4-14; 1277:1-13.)
In total, about 40% of US Airways’ revenue was booked through Sabre. (Tr.
202:1-2; 474:17-18; PX-1178.)
Consequently, US Airways determined that removal of their flights from the
Sabre system would have jeopardized 15 to 20% of their revenue and the future of
the company. (Tr. 202:15-203:6; 219:7-16; 1279:6-17; 1280:18-23.)
US Airways had no choice but to accept Sabre’s terms. (Tr. 212:17-24; 218:19219:16; 474:9-18; 523:6-9; 591:2-4.)
This evidence removes the present case from the ambit of the Queen City rule on which
Sabre relies. See Meredith Corp. v. SESAC, LLC, No. 09 Civ. 9177, 2011 WL 856266, at *7–8
(S.D.N.Y. Mar. 9, 2011) (distinguishing Queen City as a “contract power” case where
defendant’s market power arose solely from contractual rights and on grounds that there was
competition in market for restaurant franchise opportunities); Newcal Indus., Inc., 513 F.3d at
1049 (rejecting defendant’s argument that the facts were similar to Queen City because the
market power at issue did not rest solely on contractual power).
Sabre also argues that US Airways’ product market definition is inconsistent with its
theory of injury and causation, which depended on non-GDS competitors being available to
travel agents and travelers. At trial, US Airways argued that its damages should be measured
with reference to a competitive market, in which competition from channels outside of the
market for GDS services (e.g. purchases directly from airlines or from GDS alternatives) would
14
drive down the price (booking fee) for GDS distribution services. Sabre’s argument is incorrect.
In defining the relevant market, “[t]he basic principle is that the relevant market definition must
encompass the realities of competition.” Amex, 838 F.3d at 197 (emphasis added) (quoting
Balaklaw v. Lovell, 14 F.3d 793, 799 (2d Cir. 1994)). In contrast, the inquiry at the injury and
damages stage is whether US Airways suffered injury as a result of Sabre’s unlawful restraint of
trade, which requires examining what would have happened in the hypothetical “but for
competitive world” had the unlawful restraint not existed. See 2A Phillip E. Areeda et al.,
Antitrust Law ¶ 392b, at 379 (4th ed. 2014) (When measuring damages, “[t]he guiding principle
is that the antitrust victim should recover the difference between its actual economic condition
and its ‘but for’ condition.”). Because each stage of analysis requires a distinct inquiry,
assuming the contractual restraints apply at one stage and not at the other is neither illogical nor
inconsistent.
2.
One-Sided Market
At trial, the evidence was sufficient for a reasonable jury to conclude -- as it did -- that
the relevant market for purposes of Count I was one-sided, even though Sabre and the other
GDSs are two-sided platforms. In other words, the evidence was sufficient for the jury to
conclude that the relevant product market was not two-sided and interdependent, such that
benefits to the travel agent side of the market had to be considered in assessing harm to
competition. This issue was the basis for US Airways’ argument that Sabre’s supracompetitive
prices, which are the measure of US Airways’ harm, should be measured without subtracting
Sabre’s incentive payments to travel agents.2 (See Tr. 1883:2-17; 1884:9-13; 5519:19-25;
2
US Airways presented evidence that, without considering travel agent incentives, Sabre
charged supracompetitive prices, and therefore US Airways had damages, ranging from $44.5
15
5532:19-5533:23.)
The concept of two-sidedness in economics is relatively new and complex. See Amex,
838 F.3d at 185 n.3 (“Two-sided markets were first clearly identified in the early 2000s by
economists Jean-Charles Rochet and Jean Tirole . . . .”). Simply put, “[a] two-sided platform
provides goods or services to two distinct groups of customers who need each other in some way
and who rely on the platform to intermediate transactions between them.” ABA Section of
Antitrust Law, Market Definition in Antitrust: Theory and Case Studies, 439–40 (2012) (“ABA,
Market Definition”). “Two-sided platforms minimize transactions costs between entities that can
benefit from getting together, permitting value-creating exchanges to take place that would not
occur otherwise.” Id. at 440 (internal quotation marks omitted). Websites like eBay, which
connect buyers and sellers of goods in online auctions, or credit cards that provide a way to link
merchants and customers, are two-sided platforms. GDSs likewise are two-sided platforms.
They provide an avenue for airlines selling tickets and travel agents purchasing tickets to do
business with each other.
Economists define a two-sided market as one in which a “platform can affect the volume
of transactions by charging more to one side of the market and reducing the price paid by the
other side by an equal amount; in other words, the price structure matters, and platforms must
design it so as to bring both sides on board.” Amex, 838 F.3d at 185 n.3 (quoting Jean-Charles
Rochet & Jean Tirole, Two-Sided Markets: A Progress Report, 37 Rand J. Econ. 645, 664–65
million to $73.2 million, depending on whether a $1.35 or $0 booking fee benchmark is used.
(PX-1184.) US Airways’ experts also explained that, even accounting for travel agency
incentives in a two-sided market, Sabre had lower but still supracompetitive prices. (Tr.
2361:20-2362:25; 2453:24-2454:5; 2514:8-20.) Although the jury found that the relevant market
was one-sided, it also hypothetically found damages of approximately $5 million if the market
were two-sided.
16
(2006) (“Rochet & Tirole, Two-Sided Markets”)). Profit-maximizing prices of two-sided
platforms may require charging one side of the platform less than the marginal cost of serving
that set of customers. David S. Evans & Michael Noel, Defining Antitrust Markets when Firms
Operate Two-Sided Platforms, 2005 Colum. Bus. L. R. 667, 668 (2005).
The economic concept of two-sided platforms or markets is not the same as the legal
concept of the relevant market in antitrust law, a distinction that economists and lawyers alike
recognize. See, e.g., David S. Evans & Richard Schmalensee, The Industrial Organization of
Markets with Two-Sided Platforms, 3 Competition Policy Int’l 151, 153 n.5 (2007) (commenting
on the Rochet and Tirole definition, “[n]ote that the word market is being used in the loose
manner that is the custom among economists and not in the antitrust sense. The Rochet-Tirole
definition would be more precise if it said ‘A two-sided platform business exists if . . . .’”); ABA,
Market Definition at 447. The basic difference is that “[t]wo-sided platforms serve two distinct
sets of customers who receive different but related products or services. Market definition [for
antitrust purposes] must consider whether both sides of the platform should be combined in one
market or whether separate markets should be defined for each side.” Id. (citation omitted). The
relevant market for purposes of antitrust analysis may not be two-sided even though the
defendant operates a two-sided platform. See, e.g., Amex, 838 F.3d at 197–98 (differentiating
between the relevant market defined in United States v. Visa U.S.A., Inc., 344 F.3d 229 (2d Cir.
2003), and in Amex, both of which involve credit card platforms).
The vocabulary of two-sidedness is new, but courts have long addressed claims and
developed case law involving businesses now recognized as two-sided platforms by closely
examining the competitive realities of the market. See, e.g., Times-Picayune Pub. Co. v. United
States, 345 U.S. 594, 610 (1953) (recognizing -- without using the language of two-sidedness --
17
that “every newspaper is a dual trader in separate though interdependent markets; it sells the
paper’s news and advertising content to its readers; in effect that readership is in turn sold to the
buyers of advertising space”). The relevant market is not two-sided merely because it involves a
platform with customers on both sides. If that were the case, the relevant market for every
business with a middleman would be two-sided as a matter of law. The ultimate goal of defining
the relevant market remains “to identify the market participants and competitive pressures that
restrain an individual firm’s ability to raise prices or restrict output.” Geneva Pharm., 386 F.3d
at 496.
Amex clarified that the relevant market is considered two-sided where “interdependency
that causes price changes on one side can result in demand changes on the other side.” 838 F.3d
at 186. Where this interdependency exists, it would be error to separate the two sides of the
market in defining the relevant market because it would “allow[] legitimate competitive activities
[on one side of the market] to be penalized no matter how output-expanding such activities may
be.” Id. at 198. In Amex, the Second Circuit rejected the district court’s separation of the two
sides of the market because “[s]eparating the two markets . . . -- analyzing the effect of Amex’s
vertical restraints on the market for network services while ignoring their effect on the market for
general purpose cards -- ignores the two markets’ interdependence.” Id.3
3
The jury in the present case was instructed:
A second dispute, which you must also decide, is whether the market is onesided or two-sided. US Airways contends that the market is one-sided and that
you should consider only the impact on the airline side when you evaluate the
issue of harm to competition. Sabre contends that the market is two-sided and
that you should consider the net competitive impact of the restraints both on the
airline side and on the travel agent side when you are assessing harm to
competition.
Two-sidedness is a special concept in antitrust economics. In a two-sided
18
Here, Plaintiff presented sufficient evidence to support the jury’s conclusion that the
relevant market is one-sided. As discussed above, US Airways defined the relevant product
market as the market for GDS services linking airlines with traditional travel agents that serve
the vast majority of business travelers. At trial, US Airways expert, Stiglitz, testified in sum that
the relevant market is one-sided because the GDS services market lacks interdependence where
benefits to one side depend on the number of people or usage on the other side. (Tr. 1369:101371:20.)
Stiglitz’s conclusion was based on the unique nature of the GDS services market, as
explained by Plaintiff’s fact and expert witnesses. These facts include the following:
There are only three GDSs. (Tr. 448:6-12.) The airlines that rely on corporate
travelers, including Plaintiff, subscribe to all of the GDSs. (See Tr. 2059:12060:7.) The large traditional travel agencies -- so-called “brick and mortar”
travel agencies versus online travel agents like Expedia -- book most corporate
travel in the United States and use the GDSs to make their bookings. (Tr.
2030:10-16.) Traditional travel agents at a particular location, including those at
large travel agencies with multiple locations, mostly engage in “single homing,”
meaning that they rely on one GDS to book their travel. (Tr. 2030:13-17;
2045:10-2049:14.) Accordingly, all, or almost all, traditional travel agents are
already linked to the airlines through a GDS, and vice versa. (Tr. 1375:23-
market, a firm sells two different products or services to two different groups of
consumers, and demand from one group of consumers depends on the demand
from the other group. However, a market is not two-sided merely because there
are customers on both sides, such as buyers and sellers brought together by an
intermediary. The market in this case is considered two-sided if the two sides are
interdependent such that a change in price on one side of the market affects
demand on the other side. (Tr. 5626:4-22.)
19
1376:1; 1878:23-24.)
Sabre charges the airlines booking fees, which fund incentive payments that Sabre
pays to travel agencies. (Tr. 452:21-23; 454:5-7; 2054:17-21.) Travel agents do
not pay for GDS services. (See Tr. 1272:22-1273:4; 1296:25-1297:8; 2054:172057:6.) This payment structure shifts to the airline side of the platform the cost
of both travel agents and airlines using GDS services. (See Tr. 1296:25-1297:8.)
Because all or almost all travel agents are already users of a GDS platform, these
incentives serve only to keep travel agents loyal to a particular GDS. (Tr.
1379:17-23; 1905:17-19; 5518:25-5519:6.) GDS payments to travel agents do not
increase demand for GDS services and do not expand the market. (Tr. 1377:1014.) GDS incentive payments to travel agents also fail to benefit the airlines
because these payments do not incentivize travelers to book a particular airline.
(Tr. 1905:17-19.) Once the potential consumers on both sides of the platform
have joined, it no longer promotes competition, or benefits both sides of the
platform, for one side of the platform (the airlines) to pay another set of customers
(the travel agents) to join the platform. Doing so no longer grows the market.
(Tr. 1372:3-1375:21.)
In economics terminology, the GDS services market is a mature market.4 (Tr.
4
See Oz Shy, A Short Survey of Network Economics, 38 Review of Indus. Org. 119, 136 (2011)
(“The example of payment cards highlights the limitation of the two-sided market theory,
because under full capacity no new spillovers between buyers and merchants can be created.
More precisely, no additional network effects can be generated once most buyers already use
payment cards and most merchants accept merchant cards. Therefore, policy conclusions of twosided market models should be confined to immature markets.”) (emphasis added); Alan Frankel
and Allan L. Shampine, The Economic Effects of Interchange Fees, 73 Antitrust L. J. 627, 655
(2006) (“By its nature, a network externality is likely to become less important . . . as a network
matures.”).
20
1375:23-1376:4; 5514:5-11; 5516:8-9.) When the market becomes mature, it
ceases to be interdependent and two-sided in the economic sense. (Tr. 1375:1721; 1880:6-9.)
Based on evidence of these facts, a reasonable jury could conclude that changing the
price on one side of the platform (increasing or decreasing the booking fee paid by the airlines)
does not change demand on the travel agent side. Thus, Plaintiff presented evidence that the
GDS platform does not provide value (or cause indirect network effects) in the ways that twosided markets typically do: (1) The GDS platform does not provide a matchmaking function by
making it easier for both sides to find each other, because the travel agents (and their customers)
already know who the airlines are, and the airlines know who the corporate travel agents are; (2)
the GDS platforms do not build audiences by attracting more airlines and more travel agents,
creating a thicker market and increasing the likelihood that each side will find a suitable match,
again, because the large corporate travel agents already use a GDS and the airlines already use
all three GDSs; and (3) because of the contractual restraints, the GDS platform does not reduce
the costs of both sides doing business with each other. See ABA, Market Definition at 441
(citing David S. Evans & Richard Schmalensee, Catalyst Code: The Strategies Behind the
World’s Most Dynamic Companies 7 (2007)).
Sabre incorrectly argues that the jury’s finding based on market maturity is foreclosed as
a matter of law by Amex. The Court of Appeal’s finding of a two-sided market, after a bench
trial in Amex, does not invalidate the jury’s finding of a one-sided market here, in a different
industry and with very different facts. As noted above, market definition is deeply fact intensive
and requires examining the competitive realities. Todd, 275 F.3d at 199; Amex, 838 F.3d at 196–
97. Amex is one of the few cases that explicitly addresses two-sided markets, and the opinion
21
does not address or appear to consider market maturity, which was not a factual consideration in
that case.
Sabre also asserts that Stiglitz’s mature market theory is barred as a matter of law by
Amex, arguing that under Amex, the theory of a two-sided market is about making a particular
platform larger, not the market overall. Sabre’s argument is incorrect. First, Sabre’s argument
might carry weight if the relevant market were the Sabre platform, but neither US Airways nor
Sabre argued at trial that the relevant market was limited to Sabre’s GDS services. Similarly,
Amex did not hold that the relevant market was the market for American Express card network
services. Rather it held that the relevant market was the entire credit card network services
market, including both cardholders and merchants, and analyzed the effect on competition
accordingly. See Amex, 838 F.3d at 205–06. Second, the federal antitrust laws do not serve to
protect a particular competitor; they protect competition. Id. at 193 (quoting Tops Mkts., 142
F.3d at 96); Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 320 (1962).
The relevant holding of Amex for purposes of this case is that, where the two sides of a
platform are interdependent, excluding one side from the relevant market would be improper.
838 F.3d at 186, 198 (“The interdependency that causes price changes on one side can result in
demand changes on the other side.”). Whether the two sides of a platform are interdependent
such that the relevant market is two-sided is a factual, not a legal, issue. The jury’s factual
determination of the relevant market should not be lightly disturbed. See Brown Shoe, 370 U.S.
at 336 (“Congress prescribed a pragmatic, factual approach to the definition of the relevant
market and not a formal, legalistic one.”); Amex, 838 F.3d at 196 (“[M]arket definition is a
deeply fact-intensive inquiry.”) (alteration in original) (quoting Todd, 275 F.3d at 199). For the
reasons outlined above, the Court declines to do so here.
22
C.
Unreasonable Restraint on Trade (Rule of Reason)
The evidence at trial was sufficient to support the jury’s finding that “Sabre unreasonably
restrained trade by means of the challenged contract provisions.” To analyze whether the
challenged restraints were “unreasonable” restraints on trade, courts employ the burden-shifting
analysis outlined above and known as the rule of reason.
1.
Adverse Effect on Competition
Under the first step of the rule of reason, US Airways had the burden of proving the
anticompetitive effect of the challenged restraints. “A plaintiff may satisfy this requirement in
either of two ways[,]” directly or indirectly. MacDermid, 833 F.3d at 182. “First, a plaintiff
may offer direct evidence of harm to competition by proving higher prices, reduced output, or
lower quality in the market as a whole.” Id. Absent a showing of direct harm, a plaintiff must
show “an adverse effect indirectly by establishing that the [defendants] had sufficient ‘market
power’ to cause an adverse effect, ‘plus some other ground for believing that the challenged
behavior’ has harmed competition.” Id. (quoting Tops Mkts., 142 F.3d at 97). A plaintiff can
meet its initial burden under the rule of reason by showing adverse effect through either method.
US Airways presented evidence using both methods. Either would have been sufficient.
a)
Direct Evidence
US Airways adduced direct evidence at trial from which a reasonable jury could conclude
that the challenged restraints had an adverse effect on the market as a whole for GDS services -through supracompetitive pricing or lower quality. A showing of either of these harms is
sufficient for US Airways to show an actual adverse effect on competition and satisfy the first
step of the three-part rule of reason analysis.
At trial, Stiglitz opined and presented data showing that Sabre had charged US Airways
23
and the other legacy airlines,5 over whom Sabre exercised market power, significantly higher
booking fees than would have been charged in a competitive market. (Tr. 1351:8-15; PX-006.)
Stiglitz testified that the magnitude of the excess profit was so large that he “fe[lt] confident that
it’s robust to any slight alteration in the [supporting] data.” (Tr. 1979:6-10.)
Regarding lower quality, the jury heard from both fact and expert witnesses that the
contractual restraints made entry into the marketplace “extraordinarily difficult” (Tr. 1999:25),
reduced the quality of options available in the marketplace and led to technological stagnation.
Several witnesses -- US Airways’ technology expert as well as the respective founders of two
unsuccessful GDS competitors -- described in detail how the GDS’s tools were technologically
inefficient and outdated. (See, e.g., PX-810.0003-.0004; PX-813.0005-.0006; Tr. 2749:17 –
2769:17.)
Sabre challenges the causal link between the challenged restraints and technological
stagnation, arguing that US Airways does not present evidence of causation. Sabre ignores
explicit testimony about the link from a would-be GDS competitor, G2, that the full content suite
of provisions, first in the legacy airlines’ 2006 contracts with Sabre, and then in the 2011
contracts, foreclosed the airlines’ ability to negotiate differentiated content with G2. (See PX813.0001, .0005.) In combination with the testimony cited above, the evidence was sufficient for
the jury to conclude that the challenged restraints brought about technological stagnation and
reduced quality in the marketplace.
Consequently, the evidence was sufficient to show actual harm to competition in the form
5
The “legacy” carriers refers to the older airline carriers that existed prior to deregulation of the
airline industry -- American, Continental, Delta, Northwest, United and US Airways. (Tr.
993:13-22.)
24
of either supracompetitive pricing or lower quality.6
b)
Indirect Evidence
In the alternative, US Airways presented evidence sufficient to support the jury’s finding
that the contract restraints had an anticompetitive effect in the market for GDS services used by
airlines, using the indirect method -- proof of market power “plus some other ground for
believing that the challenged behavior could harm competition in the market.”7 Amex, 838 F.3d
at 195 (citation omitted).
6
When asked to assume hypothetically that the relevant market was two-sided, the jury also
determined that US Airways “proved, by a preponderance of the evidence, that Sabre
unreasonably restrained trade in the relevant market by means of the challenged contract
provisions.” The evidence was sufficient to support this finding as well. US Airways presented
evidence to show that even in a two-sided market, taking into account incentives paid to the
travel agents, Sabre’s net prices were supracompetitive. See supra note 2, at 15-16; (Tr.
1903:11-18; 5486:3-5487:12; PX-777.) US Airways’ evidence regarding reduced quality and
technological stagnation in the market is unaffected by a determination that the market is onesided or two-sided. See supra at 24. US Airways also presented indirect evidence of harm in the
two-sided market, by showing Sabre’s market power plus lack of innovation and technological
stagnation, which harmed both sides of the market. See infra at 27-29.
7
Sabre disputes the “could harm competition” aspect of this statement of the law, which was
also reflected in the Court’s jury instruction. Sabre asserts that MacDermid raised the standard
for the indirect method by requiring “some evidence that the challenged action has already had
an adverse effect on competition.” 833 F.3d at 182. Sabre misunderstands MacDermid.
MacDermid was primarily concerned with what “plus factors” would be sufficient under the
indirect test. The difference in language between MacDermid and the Second Circuit’s other
cases outlining the indirect test is not substantive. See, e.g., Amex, 838 F.3d at 195 (“could harm
competition”); Tops Mkts., 142 F.3d at 96 (“sufficient market power to cause an adverse effect
on competition”) (citation omitted); Capital Imaging Assocs., 996 F.2d at 546 (“potential for
genuine adverse effects on competition”); K.M.B. Warehouse Distribs., 61 F.3d at 129 (“will
harm competition market-wide”). The indirect test is a “proxy” for showing through direct
evidence that an adverse effect has already occurred. Tops Mkts., 142 F.3d at 97. “[D]espite the
differences in phrasing, our cases have always required, as a practical matter, some evidence that
the challenged action has already had an adverse effect on competition . . . .” MacDermid, 833
F.3d at 182. The indirect test is a method of testing for adverse effect “even if consumers have
not yet felt that effect.” Id. An effect not yet felt by consumers may be difficult to prove
empirically, but may be proved indirectly and circumstantially, with proof of market power plus
some basis to believe that the challenged behavior could harm competition. See id. at 182–83
(“How ‘actual harm’ is shown [i.e. directly or indirectly] determines whether proof of market
power is also required.”).
25
Market power may be evidenced by the “power to control prices.” Visa, 344 F.3d at 239
(citation omitted). Controlling prices means “the ability to raise prices above those that would be
charged in a competitive market,” Nat’l Collegiate Athletic Ass’n v. Bd. of Regents of Univ. of
Okla., 468 U.S. 85, 109 n.38 (1984), or the “ability to raise price significantly above the
competitive level without losing all of one’s business.” K.M.B. Warehouse Distribs., 61 F.3d at
129 (citation omitted). “Market power is [also] the power to force a purchaser to do something
that he would not do in a competitive market.” Amex, 838 F.3d at 200 (citation omitted).
“Market power may be shown by evidence of specific conduct indicating the defendant’s
power to control prices or exclude competition.” K.M.B. Warehouse Distribs., 61 F.3d at 129
(internal quotation marks omitted). For example, higher profits than would be earned in a
competitive market may be indicative of market power. See FTC v. Actavis, Inc., 133 S. Ct.
2223, 2236 (2013) (recognizing that “presence of higher-than-competitive profits” is “a strong
indication of market power”). Other indicia that may be relevant include:
a large market share in the relevant market, K.M.B. Warehouse Distribs., 61 F.3d
at 129;
few or insignificant competitors in the market, In re Ciprofoxacin Hydochloride
Antitrust Litig., 363 F. Supp. 2d 514, 535 (E.D.N.Y. 2005) (“Antitrust law looks
at entry into the market as one mechanism to limit and deter exploitation of
market power by those who may temporarily possess it.”) (quoting Andrx.
Pharma., Inc. v. Biovail Corp. Int’l, 256 F.3d 799, 814 (D.C. Cir. 2001));
the ability to exclude competitors, Visa, 344 F.3d at 239;
high barriers to entry making it difficult for new competitors to enter the relevant
market, In re Payment Card Interchange Fee & Merch. Disc. Antitrust Litig., 562
26
F. Supp. 2d 392, 402 (E.D.N.Y. 2008); and
the lack of new entrants in a profitable industry, see Visa, 344 F.3d at 240; 2B
Phillip E. Areeda et al., Antitrust Law ¶ 501, at 109 (4th ed. 2014) (“If the firms
[in a competitive market] are making excess profits at the going market price,
additional capacity will be drawn into the industry . . . .”).
To show harm to competition indirectly, a plaintiff must show, in addition to market
power, some basis to believe that the challenged behavior could harm competition. The plus
factors necessarily depend on the nature of the challenged behavior but could include “the
inherently anticompetitive nature of a defendant’s behavior,” actions that reduce consumer
choice or behaviors that significantly restrict a competitor’s ability to enter the relevant market.
MacDermid, 833 F.3d at 183–84 (quoting K.M.B. Warehouse Distribs., 61 F.3d at 129).
At trial, US Airways presented evidence that Sabre had market power based on: (a)
Sabre’s 50% market share in the three-competitor GDS market (Tr. 1365:14-1366:8); (b) the lack
of new entrants (i.e. competitors) into the GDS industry despite high returns that typically would
attract new entrants (Tr. 1252:5-1253:21); (c) Sabre’s ability to charge significantly more than
would be expected in a competitive market, calculated as cost plus a reasonable return (Tr.
1241:7-17; 2361:14-19; PX-109A); (d) economic profits of 76% over a reasonable return (Tr.
1250:21-1251:17; 2332:10-2333:10); (e) Sabre’s ability to price discriminate, for example, by
charging US Airways significantly more than Southwest Airlines8 (Tr. 1245:25-1246:25); and (f)
8
At trial, US Airways presented evidence that Sabre did not have market power over Southwest
Airlines and, therefore, that Southwest’s booking fee of $1.35 represented a reasonably
competitive booking fee. (Tr. 1351:8-15.) Stiglitz explained that Southwest was not subject to
the same contractual restraints as the legacy airlines and had a different business model than the
legacy carriers. Southwest relies less on business travelers who book through corporate travel
agents and in turn through the GDSs, and relies more on the Southwest website to connect
directly to travelers. (Tr. 1301:18-1302:12; 1306:13-1307:9.)
27
Sabre’s power over customers to force them to do things they would not do in a competitive
market, such as signing contracts with terms they would not otherwise accept (Tr. 1251:16-25;
212:17-24; 474:6-10; 523:6-10; 835:9-15).
US Airways also introduced evidence that the contractual restraints raised barriers to
entry and reduced consumer choice. US Airways presented evidence that the full content
provisions introduced in 2006 were in response to new competitors. (Tr. 3311:3-11.) In addition
to the G2 testimony summarized above, US Airways presented testimony from another would-be
GDS competitor, Farelogix, that efforts to attract airlines to Farelogix’s direct connect product
were unsuccessful despite charging significantly lower prices to airlines because of the full
content agreements that the airlines had with Sabre and the other GDSs. (Tr. 2569:1-2571:23;
2577:21-2580:11.) A reasonable jury could have concluded that the full content provisions were
anticompetitive by preventing the airlines from steering travel agents away from the GDSs to
lower cost distribution channels (like Farelogix) with inducements of lower fares or greater
benefits to reflect the airlines’ lower distribution costs. The full content provisions precluded
this result and reduced consumer choice by requiring that the same fares and benefits available
anywhere be available on the GDS platform. The provisions also kept GDS competitors, like G2
and Farelogix, from establishing themselves in the market by preventing new entrants from
competing with better content or price. (See, e.g., PX-128.0011; Tr. 2577:12-2580:11; PX813.0005.) Thus, US Airways presented evidence at trial from which a reasonable jury could
conclude, on the basis of indirect evidence, that the contested restraints caused antitrust harm.
In response, Sabre first argues that the challenged provisions are not anticompetitive
because “they did not prevent an equally efficient competitor from competing against Sabre” and
simply put Sabre on a “level playing field” with other competitors. Sabre applies an incorrect,
28
heightened legal standard, for which it cites no authority. US Airways is not required to show
that the barriers to entry would prevent an “equally efficient competitor” from entering the
marketplace. Showing market power plus that the challenged behavior “heightened existing
barriers or created new ones” would be sufficient to show harm to competition. MacDermid,
833 F.3d at 186 n.56. As described above, a reasonable jury could have concluded that US
Airways’ evidence met this standard.
Next, Sabre argues that the antitrust laws do not impose a duty to agree to contract terms
that “degrade its product and place it at a competitive disadvantage.” But the law does not
permit Sabre to use contractual restraints to give it an unfair and unlawful competitive
advantage. Additionally, the authorities Sabre cites deal with the supposed procompetitive
effects of the restraints at issue, which are relevant at the second step of the rule of reason, not
this first step. See Amex, 838 F.3d at 194–95.
Sabre also argues that full content requirements are common industry practice and,
therefore, not inherently anticompetitive. Sabre ignores the Second Circuit’s suggestion that
“actions that reduce consumer choice are inherently anticompetitive.” MacDermid, 833 F.3d at
183 (citing Ross v. Bank of Am., N.A. (USA), 524 F.3d 217, 223–24 (2d Cir. 2008)). As
described above, US Airways adduced sufficient evidence for a reasonable jury to conclude that
the challenged restraints created barriers to entry and reduced consumer choice by keeping
competitors from establishing a toehold in the market.
Sabre also argues that a jury finding of market power was foreclosed as a matter of law
by Amex because the Second Circuit rejected Stiglitz’s so-called “insistence” theory -- which
Sabre describes as the argument that Sabre had market power because travel agencies “insist” on
using Sabre. See Amex, 838 F.3d at 202. First, Stiglitz did not present nor did US Airways rely
29
on a so-called “insistence” theory at trial. Second, Sabre ignores the ample evidence of Sabre’s
market power that US Airways did present, as discussed above.
Finally, Sabre attempts to forestall any argument of market power based on evidence that
Sabre forced US Airways to do something -- agree to the full content provisions -- that it would
not do in a competitive market. This was just one of many ways that US Airways argued for,
and presented indirect evidence of, market power in addition to its direct evidence of harm to
competition.
In summary, US Airways presented evidence of harm to competition, through both the
direct and indirect method, either of which would have been sufficient. To show harm directly,
it presented evidence of increased prices and lower quality services. To show harm indirectly,
Plaintiff adduced evidence of several indicia of market power (Sabre’s market share, pricing
practices, economic profits, technological stagnation and lack of entry into the marketplace, price
discrimination and leverage over customers) as well as several “plus factors,” (increased barriers
to entry and reduced consumer choice) when only one was needed. Sabre’s arguments do not
undermine the sufficiency of the evidence to support the jury’s finding.
2.
Competitive Benefits
After US Airways satisfies the first step in the rule of reason by showing that the
challenged restraint had an anticompetitive effect, the burden shifts to Sabre “to offer evidence
of any procompetitive effects of the restraint at issue.” Amex, 838 F.3d at 195. The question at
this stage is whether “there [is] strong evidence that the challenged practice creates substantial
efficiencies by reducing participants’ costs or improving product or service quality[.]” 7 Phillip
E. Areeda and Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 1507a, at 426 (3rd ed. 2010) [hereinafter
30
“Areeda (2010)”].9
Sabre presented evidence that the full content provisions led to increased competition
among airlines by enabling travel agents to shop efficiently among multiple airlines and compare
fares to get the lowest fare. (See, e.g., Tr. 4813:8-4816:16.) Although the evidence was
sufficient for Sabre to meet its burden, the jury as factfinder was entitled not to credit Sabre’s
witnesses or arguments and conclude that the procompetitive benefits were not substantial or
would have existed even without the restraints at issue. See Tolbert v. Queens Coll., 242 F.3d
58, 70–71 (2d Cir. 2001) (jury not required to credit testimony of witnesses). If the jury
determined that Sabre did not meet its burden of proving a procompetitive effect, the inquiry
under the rule of reason would have ceased at this step, supporting the jury’s finding that the
challenged restraints caused harm in the relevant market. The Court assumes only for the
purpose of completing the sufficiency of the evidence analysis under rule of reason that the jury
credited Sabre’s evidence and found that the full content provisions created substantial
procompetitive efficiencies.10
3.
Reasonably Available Less Restrictive Alternative and Weighing the
Competitive Harm
Assuming the jury found that Sabre met its burden at step two of the rule of reason, the
burden then shifts back to US Airways to “prove that any legitimate competitive benefits offered
9
At the time of this Opinion’s issuance, volumes 6 to 14 of Phillip E. Areeda and Herbert
Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law, have not been released in the Fourth edition.
10
Contrary to Sabre’s assertion, the Court did not rule “as a matter of law” that Sabre had met its
burden regarding the existence of procompetitive effects. The sentence that Sabre cites appears
in the Court’s summary judgment opinion in the middle of a paragraph listing the arguments
Sabre made about the procompetitive effects of the agreement. US Airways, Inc. v. Sabre
Holdings Corp., 105 F. Supp. 3d 265, 283 (S.D.N.Y. 2015). The only conclusion was that
Sabre’s assertions regarding procompetitive effects were sufficient to meet its burden to offer
evidence that the contract had procompetitive effects in step two of the rule of reason for
purposes of summary judgment. Id.
31
by defendant[] could have been achieved through less restrictive means.” Amex, 838 F.3d at 915
(citation omitted). If the same efficiencies -- in this case, efficient comparison shopping and
booking -- could be achieved by “reasonably available alternatives that have less potential to
harm competition,” Areeda (2010), ¶1507a, at 426, then US Airways has proved that the terms
unreasonably restrained trade. US Airways adduced evidence at trial of reasonably available
alternatives. Having done so, the Court’s evaluation of the sufficiency of the evidence of harm
to competition is finished, as the weighing of those alternatives against the challenged restraints
and the determination of which is less restrictive to competition is solely a question for the jury.
US Airways introduced evidence of several potentially less restrictive alternatives for
travel agents to compare and book airline tickets efficiently without the full content provisions.
US Airways’ witnesses testified that alternatives included: allowing the airlines to impose a
surcharge on tickets booked through Sabre to reflect the higher cost of the booking channel (Tr.
1347:20-1348:13; 1542:17-23; 5191:11-5193:11); or Sabre charging separately for searching and
booking (Tr. 1336:16-18; 1337:5-1338:4). A surcharge would permit the airline to recoup some
of the higher cost of booking through Sabre and lower prices to travelers who book through
lower cost channels. Sabre could address its concern with free-riding by simply charging
separately for searching and booking on its platform. These alternatives would allow for greater
competition by allowing airlines to pass on savings from lower booking fees to their customers
and permitting competitors to differentiate their products by cost. This in turn could spur greater
technological innovation and quality.
In the alternative, if the jury found that these alternatives were not less restrictive or
reasonably available -- as Sabre argued -- they would become part of the jury’s ultimate
weighing of the competitive harms and benefits of the challenged behavior. Visa, 344 F.3d at
32
238 (“The principal question in a rule of reason case is often whether the anticompetitive effects
of a restraint are outweighed by some procompetitive justification.”). “The true test of legality is
whether the restraint imposed is such as merely regulates and perhaps thereby promotes
competition or whether it is such as may suppress or even destroy competition.” Am. Needle,
Inc. v. Nat’l Football League, 560 U.S. 183, 203 n.10 (2010) (quoting Bd. of Trade of Chi. v.
United States, 246 U.S. 231, 238 (1918) (Brandeis, J.)).
The weighing of the evidence at this final stage lies solely with the factfinder. See Amex,
838 F.3d at 195 (“Ultimately, it remains for the factfinder to weigh the harms and benefits of the
challenged behavior.”) (citation omitted). Through the rule of reason, “the factfinder weighs all
of the circumstances of a case in deciding whether a restrictive practice should be prohibited as
imposing an unreasonable restraint on competition.” Leegin Creative Leather Prod., Inc. v.
PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 885 (2007) (citation omitted). Thus it was for the jury to weigh the
harms and benefits, and not for the Court to substitute its judgment.
The jury, after eight weeks of testimony, found on its verdict form that “US Airways
proved, by a preponderance of the evidence, that Sabre unreasonably restrained trade by means
of the challenged contract provisions.” Sabre has not met its burden of showing that, viewing the
evidence in the light most favorable to US Airways, a reasonable juror would have been
compelled to accept Sabre’s view that the restraints did not harm competition.
D.
Antitrust Injury
The evidence was sufficient to support the jury’s finding that US Airways “was injured as
a result of Sabre’s unreasonable restraint of trade.” A plaintiff claiming antitrust injury must
prove “injury of the type the antitrust laws were intended to prevent and that flows from that
which makes defendants’ acts unlawful.” Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bow-O-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S.
33
477, 489 (1977). Stated differently, “an antitrust plaintiff must prove that its injury was, in fact,
caused by the defendant’s violation of the antitrust laws.” U.S. Football League v. Nat’l
Football League, 842 F.2d 1335, 1377 (2d Cir. 1988). However, “[i]t is enough that the
illegality is shown to be a material cause of the [antitrust] injury; a plaintiff need not exhaust all
possible alternative sources of injury in fulfilling [its] burden of proving compensable injury.”
In re Publ’n Paper Antitrust Litig., 690 F.3d 51, 66 (2d Cir. 2012) (citation omitted) (alteration
in original). “[A]n antitrust defendant’s unlawful conduct need not be the sole cause of the
plaintiffs’ alleged injuries; to prove a ‘causal connection’ . . . the plaintiff need only ‘demonstrate
the [the defendant’s] conduct was a substantial or materially contributing factor’ in producing
that injury.” Id. (citation omitted).
At trial, US Airways presented evidence supporting its theory of causation and from
which a reasonable jury could conclude that, as a result of the challenged full content provisions,
US Airways was forced to pay supracompetitive prices, thereby suffering an antitrust injury. As
discussed above, US Airways presented evidence that Sabre had market power when the GDS
industry was deregulated and that Sabre used that power to impose the full-content contractual
terms in the 2006 US Airways agreement, which further ingrained its market power and enabled
it to charge US Airways supracompetitive booking fees and continue to impose the challenged
contractual terms in the parties’ 2011 Contract. US Airways presented evidence, that by
preventing airlines from differentiating content or fares (i.e. offering more services or lower
fares), steering customers to lower cost booking channels or recouping some of the cost through
surcharges, Sabre was able to charge supracompetitive prices and raise barriers to entry to
exclude new competitors, which in turn led to stagnated technology and less consumer choice.
Sabre relies on overly formalistic reasoning to argue that US Airways could not have
34
proved injury because “the allegedly supra-competitive prices were negotiated and fixed before
the challenged terms in the 2011 Contract took effect,” thereby making it impossible for the
terms of the contract to have caused the supracompetitive prices. Sabre’s argument is that, as a
matter of logic, the full-content provisions in the 2011 Contract (when they were not yet in
effect) could not have caused Sabre to impose the supracompetitive booking fee contained in the
same contract. Sabre’s argument ignores weeks of trial testimony, the factual context in which
the 2011 agreement arose, US Airways actual argument (Tr. 48:13-24; 50:7-25; 63:2-66:21;
5653:8-5677:20), the Court’s causation instruction (Tr. 5630:21-5633:2) and the well-worn legal
principle that jury instructions are to be “taken as a whole.” Boyce v. Soundview Tech. Grp.,
Inc., 464 F.3d 376, 390 (2d Cir. 2006). Sabre made the same argument to the jury (Tr. 5752:125754:12), which the jury rejected. Sabre has presented no reason to overturn the jury’s finding.11
Sabre also attempts to argue that US Airways’ theory of causation based on both the 2006
and 2011 contracts would require illogical and impermissible speculation. Sabre’s arguments are
too restrictive. For example, Sabre argues that, because US Airways also had full content
agreements with other outlets, Sabre’s contractual restraints did not prevent US Airways from
11
The fallacy of Sabre’s argument is illustrated by the factual context. The parties entered into
the 2011 Contract on February 23, 2011. US Airways promptly filed this action on April 21,
2011, challenging the full content provisions in the 2006 contract and its successor, the 2011
Contract. On Sabre’s motion for summary judgment, the Court accepted Sabre’s argument that
US Airways’ claim for damages arising out of the 2006 agreement was outside the 4-year statute
of limitations, in part, because the claims accrued on the date that the 5-year contract took effect,
and rejected US Airways’ argument that the cause of action accrues on the date the overcharges
are paid. See US Airways, 105 F. Supp. 3d at 277–78. The Court accordingly limited the
damages period to damages incurred under the 2011 Contract. Id. at 279. Sabre implies that if
US Airways believed that it was charged supracompetitive prices under the 2011 Contract, it
should have alleged that they were caused by the 2006 contractual restraints (which were
extended in the 2011 contract). Sabre’s argument would mean that, no matter how many times
the parties extended their 5-year contract, US Airways would never have a timely claim -overpayments on any given contract would necessarily occur more than 4 years after the
inception of the preceding contract.
35
offering lower fares on its website or from providing exclusive content to others, even though
this is precisely what the challenged full content provisions required. However, US Airways
needs to show only that Sabre’s actions were a material cause of its injury. That other
competition-reducing restraints may also be present in the marketplace does not excuse a
defendant’s anti-competitive behavior. Sabre’s additional arguments, although framed as
arguments about “causal links,” veer into weighing conflicting evidence, which is a function that
properly lies with the jury. US Airways evidence was sufficient to support the jury’s finding that
Sabre’s anti-competitive behavior caused US Airways’ injury.
E.
Damages
The jury’s damages award of $5,098,142 to US Airways was proper and entirely within
its purview. “[O]nce proof of injury causation has been established, courts have allowed
antitrust plaintiffs considerable latitude in proving the amount of damages. Proof of amount of
damages thus need not conform to a particular theory or model, and exact proof of the amount of
damages is not required.” U.S. Football League, 842 F.2d at 1378 (citations omitted). A
plaintiff’s proof of amount of damages “must be traced to some degree to unlawful acts.” Id.
“An antitrust plaintiff must thus provide only sufficient evidence to support a just and reasonable
estimate of damages.” Id. (internal quotation marks omitted).
US Airways offered multiple benchmarks for a reasonable booking fee at trial from
which overcharges could be calculated, including: (i) the $1.35 booking fee that Southwest pays,
an airline over which Stiglitz testified Sabre did not have market power (Tr. 1351:8-15; 1301:241302:7; PX-1184); (ii) Professor Jerold Zimmerman’s reasonable profit booking fee of $1.18 (Tr.
1351:4-5); (iii) an $0.80 plus a search fee based on the fee Expedia paid to Sabre (Tr. 1351:2325); and (iv) a zero-dollar booking fee that Stiglitz testified would prevail in a but-for world and
36
is based on Spirit airline’s agreement with Sabre. (Tr. 1353:23-1354:2.) These benchmarks
yield damages ranging from $44.5 million to $73.2 million. (PX-1184.)
Sabre argues that no reasonable jury could have concluded that US Airways provided a
non-speculative method to assess damages. Sabre attempts to undercut each benchmark, arguing
that it is non-comparable or otherwise analytically flawed. Sabre made these arguments to the
jury -- implicitly through cross-examination or through their own witnesses -- and the jury
rejected them. Sabre also argues that Amex forecloses US Airways’ zero-booking-fee model.
Sabre contends that the zero model assumes that costs would be shifted from US Airways to
travel agencies, and under Amex, 838 F.3d at 205, Plaintiffs have to show that the challenged
provisions made consumers on both sides of the platform worse off. Sabre argues that Plaintiff’s
burden to show net harm applies, as opposed to harm to one side of the market, whether the
market is one-sided or two-sided. However, Sabre’s argument relies on their own expert’s
opinion that the incentive payments must be taken into account regardless of whether the market
is one-sided or two-sided, an opinion with which Stiglitz disagreed. (See Tr. 4856:24-4858:6.)
Amex does not mandate a showing of net harm in a one-sided market. Sabre’s central argument,
however, is that the quantum of the jury’s award of $5.1 million shows that the jury “plainly
rejected” Stiglitz’s and Professor Daniel McFadden’s models. Sabre’s arguments are
unpersuasive.
Sabre cross-examined US Airways’ damages experts at length. Sabre’s conclusion that
the jury’s award shows that the jury rejected the award models is but one inference that can be
drawn from the quantum of the award. The award of only a portion of the damages requested
could also mean that Sabre’s arguments about the appropriateness of the benchmarks were
credited to some extent by the jury. See State of New York v. Hendrickson Bros., 840 F.2d 1065,
37
1078 (2d Cir. 1988) (“Given the adequacy of the proof that the [plaintiff] suffered some injury,
the jury was not required to deny all recovery simply because it determined that the [plaintiff]
was not entitled to the entire amount requested.”). Also, “damage issues in [antitrust] cases are
rarely susceptible of the kind of concrete, detailed proof of injury which is available in other
contexts.” State of New York v. Julius Nasso Concrete Corp., 202 F.3d 82, 88 (2d Cir. 2000)
(citation omitted). “One of the limitations involved in proving antitrust damages is establishing
what the market price of the commodity or service would have been in an unmanipulated market.
Where, however, there is a dearth of market information unaffected by the [anticompetitive]
action of the defendants, the plaintiff’s burden of proving damages, is, to an extent, lightened.”
Id. (internal quotation marks omitted). Even if damages experts attempt to quantify a precise
amount of damages, the jury is not required to accept and award the amount or reject it and
award zero. The Second Circuit has long recognized that the “calculation of damages is the
province of the jury” and “considerable deference” should be given to the jury’s award. Restivo
v. Hessemann, 846 F.3d 547, 587 (2d Cir. 2017). That deference dictates upholding the jury’s
award.
IV.
CONCLUSION
For the foregoing reasons,12 Sabre’s motion for judgment as a matter of law, or in the
alternative for a new trial, on Count I pursuant to Rules 50 and 59 of the Federal Rules of Civil
Procedure is DENIED.
SO ORDERED.
Dated: March 21, 2017
New York, New York
12
Any of Sabre’s many arguments that were not addressed herein have been considered and
rejected.
38
Disclaimer: Justia Dockets & Filings provides public litigation records from the federal appellate and district courts. These filings and docket sheets should not be considered findings of fact or liability, nor do they necessarily reflect the view of Justia.
Why Is My Information Online?