Unites States of America v. Apple, Inc. et al
Filing
236
OPPOSITION BRIEF Plaintiffs' Response to Apple's Pretrial Memorandum of Law. Document filed by Unites States of America.(Fairchild, Stephen)
UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
FOR THE SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF NEW YORK
__________________________________________
)
UNITED STATES OF AMERICA,
)
)
Plaintiff,
)
)
v.
)
)
APPLE, INC., et al.,
)
)
Defendants.
)
__________________________________________)
Civil Action No. 12-cv-2826 (DLC)
__________________________________________
)
THE STATE OF TEXAS;
)
THE STATE OF CONNECTICUT; et al
)
)
Plaintiffs,
)
)
v.
)
)
PENGUIN GROUP (USA) INC. et al,
)
)
Defendants.
)
__________________________________________)
Civil Action No. 12-cv-03394 (DLC)
PLAINTIFFS’ RESPONSE TO APPLE’S PRETRIAL MEMORANDUM OF LAW
TABLE OF CONTENTS
TABLE OF AUTHORITIES .......................................................................................................... ii
INTRODUCTION ...........................................................................................................................1
I.
Apple’s Defense Rests on Ignoring the Direct Evidence Against it and Misstating the
Legal Test of its Liability.....................................................................................................2
A.
B.
II.
There Is Significant Direct Evidence of Both a Conspiracy and Apple’s
Participation Therein ............................................................................................... 3
Apple Misstates the Law Governing a Vertical Actor’s Liability for Participating
in a Horizontal Price-Fixing Conspiracy ................................................................ 9
Apple and Publisher Defendants Conspired To Raise Consumer E-Book Prices and
Restrain Retail Price Competition .....................................................................................11
A.
Apple Was Motivated To Conspire with Publisher Defendants in Order To
Restrain Retail E-book Price Competition............................................................ 11
B.
Apple’s Conspiracy with Publisher Defendants Was in its Own Economic Interest
and Is, as a Result, Economically Plausible .......................................................... 13
C.
The Full Body of Circumstantial Evidence Against Apple Supports an Inference
of Conspiracy ........................................................................................................ 14
III.
Apple’s Attempt To Shift the Focus of this Case to Amazon Is Both Misguided and
Replete with Factual Misstatements ..................................................................................15
IV.
Apple Cannot Escape Liability Even Under the Rule of Reason ......................................19
CONCLUSION ..............................................................................................................................24
i
TABLE OF AUTHORITIES
Cases
Apex Oil Co. v. DiMauro, 822 F.2d 246 (2d Cir. 1987) ............................................................... 14
Arnold Pontiac-GMC, Inc. v. Budd Baer, Inc., 826 F.2d 1335 (3d Cir.1987)................................ 6
Bd. of Trade of City of Chicago v. United States, 246 U.S. 231 (1918) ....................................... 12
Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477 (1977) ........................................... 20
Capital Imaging Assocs., P.C. v. Mohawk Valley Med. Assocs., 996 F.2d 537
(2d Cir. 1993) ............................................................................................................... 19, 20, 22
Catalano, Inc. v. Target Sales, Inc., 446 U.S. 643 (1980) ............................................................ 23
Clorox Co. v. Sterling Winthrop, Inc., 117 F.3d 50 (2d Cir. 1997) .................................. 20, 22, 23
Cont’l Ore Co. v. Union Carbide & Carbon Corp., 370 U.S. 690 (1962) ................................... 14
Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Tech. Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451 (1992) ........................................ 21
Fineman v. Armstrong World Indus., 980 F.2d 171 (3d Cir. 1992)................................................ 9
Gatt Commc’ns, Inc. v. PMC Assocs., L.L.C., 711 F.3d 68 (2d Cir. 2013) .................................. 20
Geneva Pharm. Tech. Corp. v. Barr Labs. Inc., 386 F.3d 485 (2d Cir. 2004) ............................. 23
Golden Bridge Tech., Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., 547 F.3d 266 (5th Cir. 2008) ................................... 4
In re Baby Food Antitrust Litig., 166 F.3d 112 (3d Cir. 1999)....................................................... 4
In re Elec. Books Antitrust Litig., 859 F. Supp. 2d 671 (S.D.N.Y. 2012) ...................................... 8
In re Flat Glass Antitrust Litig., 385 F.3d 350 (3d Cir. 2004).................................................. 3, 14
In re High Fructose Corn Syrup Antitrust Litig., 295 F.3d 651 (7th Cir. 2002) .................. 4, 8, 14
In re Ins. Brokerage Antitrust Litig., 618 F.3d 300 (3d Cir. 2010)............................................... 20
In re Publ’n Paper Antitrust Litig., 690 F.3d 51 (2d Cir. 2012)........................................... 3, 4, 13
In re Text Messaging Antitrust Litig., 630 F.3d 622 (7th Cir. 2010) .............................................. 8
In re Travel Agent Comm’n Antitrust Litig., 583 F.2d 896 (6th Cir. 2009).................................. 10
Interstate Circuit, Inc. v. United States, 306 U.S. 208 (1939) ...................................................... 11
K.M.B. Warehouse Distribs. v. Walker Mfg. Co., 61 F.3d 123 (2d Cir. 1995) ............................. 20
Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574 (1986)................................ 1, 14
Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Serv. Corp., 465 U.S. 752 (1984) .................................................. 1, 5
Nat’l Collegiate Athletic Ass’n v. Bd. of Regents of Univ. of Okla., 468 U.S. 85 (1984) ....... 19, 23
Rossi v. Standard Roofing, Inc., 156 F.3d 452 (3d Cir. 1998).................................................... 3, 4
Starr v. Sony BMG Music Entm’t, 592 F.3d 314 (2d Cir. 2010) .................................................... 2
ii
Tops Mkts., Inc. v. Quality Mkts., Inc., 142 F.3d 90 (2d Cir. 1998) ............................................. 20
Toys “R” Us, Inc. v. FTC, 221 F.3d 928 (7th Cir. 2000) ......................................................... 9, 11
United States v. Gen. Motors Corp., 384 U.S. 127 (1966) ..................................................... 10, 11
United States v. Koppers Co., 652 F.2d 290 (2d Cir. 1981) ......................................................... 12
United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150 (1940) ......................................... 2, 12, 19
United States v. Topco Assocs., Inc., 405 U.S. 596 (1972) .......................................................... 23
United States v. Visa U.S.A., Inc., 163 F. Supp. 2d 322 (S.D.N.Y. 2001) ...................................... 1
Virgin Atl. Airways Ltd. v. British Airways PLC, 257 F.3d 256 (2d Cir. 2001) ..................... 21, 22
Statutes
15 U.S.C. § 1 ............................................................................................................................. 9, 25
iii
INTRODUCTION
Nowhere in Apple’s pretrial pleadings does it deny or dispute that there was a horizontal
conspiracy among Publisher Defendants to raise consumer e-book prices and restrain retail price
competition. 1 Instead, Apple argues that, because it believes its behavior would have been no
different even in the absence of Publisher Defendants’ horizontal agreement, Plaintiffs cannot
prove Apple’s liability. Apple’s position is based on a fundamental misunderstanding of
antitrust law. It also is squarely at odds with the evidence before the Court.
In making its assertion that Plaintiffs have not met their evidentiary burden, Apple relies
heavily on the “tends to exclude” language of Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Service Corp., 465
U.S. 752, 764 (1984), and Matsushita Electric Industrial Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S.
574, 588 (1986). But, as Plaintiffs made clear in their April 26 Pretrial Memorandum of Law
(“Plaintiffs’ Memo”), the “tends to exclude” standard is applicable only when assessing antitrust
liability based on the parallel actions of horizontal rivals. 2 Moreover, even Apple acknowledges
that if direct evidence of agreement is present, the Matsushita analysis is irrelevant. 3 As
Plaintiffs demonstrated in their Proposed Findings of Fact (“Plaintiffs’ PFoF”), such evidence is
abundant in this case, and certainly sufficient to prove by a preponderance of the evidence 4 that
Apple and Publisher Defendants “had a conscious commitment to a common scheme designed to
achieve an unlawful objective” 5—namely, to raise consumer e-book prices and restrain retail
price competition.
1
See Apple Inc.’s Pre-Trial Memorandum of Law (“Apple Memo”); Apple Inc.’s Proposed Conclusions of Law
(“Apple PCoL”); Apple Inc.’s Proposed Findings of Fact (“Apple PFoF”).
2
Plaintiffs’ Memo at 31–32; see also infra Section I.
3
Apple Memo at 22–23.
4
United States v. Visa U.S.A., Inc., 163 F. Supp. 2d 322, 331 (S.D.N.Y. 2001).
5
Monsanto, 465 U.S.at 764 (quotation omitted).
Apple’s position that the agreement challenged in this action should be evaluated under
the rule of reason rather than being condemned per se similarly relies on mixing and matching
the horizontal with the vertical. While Apple is correct that certain aspects of the Apple Agency
Agreements would be subject to rule of reason analysis if they were challenged piecemeal, 6
Apple’s liability in this case arises from its facilitation of Publisher Defendants’ horizontal
agreement to raise consumer e-book prices. Such price-fixing agreements are subject to per se
condemnation, 7 and appropriately so.
From a factual perspective, Apple rests its defense on claims that (1) it had no idea that
Publisher Defendants collectively planned to raise consumer e-book prices, and (2) it took no
actions to help Publisher Defendants move as a group to do so. But those claims are belied by
the overwhelming factual record. Apple’s own e-mails and admissions, coupled with those of
Publisher Defendants and the phone records and testimony produced in this case, provide vivid
details of both Publisher Defendants’ agreement and Apple’s knowing participation in their illicit
scheme to raise consumer e-book prices and restrain retail price competition. Unfortunately for
the e-book consumers of America, Apple and Publisher Defendants were successful in achieving
their goals. Accordingly, Plaintiffs respectfully submit that the Court should enter judgment for
Plaintiffs.
I.
Apple’s Defense Rests on Ignoring the Direct Evidence Against it and Misstating the
Legal Test of its Liability.
As its papers make clear, Apple’s case rests almost entirely on two dubious propositions.
First, rather than confront the array of evidence against it, Apple merely points out that, as a
general matter, direct evidence “is extremely rare in antitrust cases,” and then contends without
6
Apple Memo at 35–37.
7
See United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150, 223 (1940); Starr v. Sony BMG Music Entm’t, 592
F.3d 314, 326 n.4 (2d Cir. 2010).
2
elaboration that “Plaintiffs have no such evidence against Apple.” 8 Second, Apple
mischaracterizes Plaintiffs’ theory on agreement as seeking an inference of Apple’s participation
in the conspiracy based on parallel conduct, and accordingly falling short because Apple did not
act contrary to its own independent interests. 9
Neither proposition is correct. First, there is strong direct evidence both of a horizontal
agreement among Publisher Defendants and of Apple’s knowledge of and participation in that
agreement. Thus, the Court’s analysis of this issue need go no further. 10 But if the Court does
evaluate the reams of circumstantial evidence along with the direct evidence of Apple’s liability,
Plaintiffs do not ask the Court to infer Apple’s participation from parallel conduct. There is no
allegation here that Apple, the sole distributor who participated in this conspiracy, engaged in
parallel conduct with any of its co-conspirators, Publisher Defendants. Thus, there is no
inference from parallel conduct to make or undermine. Accordingly, whether Apple was acting
in its own interest is of no consequence. Rather, Apple’s involvement must be evaluated in light
of “the evidence as a whole.” 11
A. There Is Significant Direct Evidence of Both a Conspiracy and Apple’s Participation
Therein.
In cases where a plaintiff presents direct evidence of a conspiracy, the plaintiff need not
adduce evidence that “tends to exclude” the possibility that the alleged conspirators acted
independently. 12 This is because, when a plaintiff puts forward direct evidence of conspiracy,
8
Apple Memo at 22.
9
Id. at 24–27.
10
See In re Publ’n Paper Antitrust Litig., 690 F.3d 51, 63 (2d Cir. 2012).
11
In re Flat Glass Antitrust Litig., 385 F.3d 350, 369 (3d Cir. 2004).
12
In re Publ’n Paper, 690 F.3d at 63; Rossi v. Standard Roofing, Inc., 156 F.3d 452, 466 (3d Cir. 1998).
3
the degree of inference required is minimized and therefore “the Supreme Court’s concerns over
the reasonableness of inferences in antitrust cases evaporate.” 13
Thus, Apple’s fundamental legal position depends on the absence of direct evidence
against it. But Apple never explains why much of the evidence before the Court, including plain
admissions of its own high-level executives and those of Publisher Defendants, is not properly
considered direct.
Contrary to Apple’s assertion, direct evidence is broader than wiretapped conversations. 14
The critical inquiry is whether evidence on its face reflects an agreement or common
understanding of the parties. “Direct evidence explicitly refers to an understanding between the
alleged conspirators, while circumstantial evidence requires additional inferences in order to
support a conspiracy claim.” 15
Here, there is significant evidence that explicitly refers to an understanding between
Apple and Publisher Defendants. Indeed, much of the evidence—both to support the existence
of a horizontal agreement among Publisher Defendants and to support Apple’s knowing
participation in that agreement—is similar to evidence courts have considered direct proof of
conspiracy in the past. For example, in Monsanto, the Supreme Court held that a supplier
13
Rossi, 156 F.3d at 466.
14
Apple PCoL, at ¶ 15.
15
Golden Bridge Tech., Inc. v. Motorola, Inc., 547 F.3d 266, 271 (5th Cir. 2008). Apple relies on the formulation of
direct evidence found in In re Baby Food Antitrust Litigation, holding that direct evidence is evidence that “requires
no inferences.” In re Baby Food Antitrust Litig., 166 F.3d 112, 118 (3d Cir. 1999); Apple Memo at 22. That
formulation has been rejected by the Second Circuit: “All evidence, including direct evidence, can sometimes
require a factfinder to draw inferences to reach a particular conclusion, though perhaps on average circumstantial
evidence requires a longer chain of inferences.” In re Publ’n Paper Antitrust Litig., 690 F.3d at 63. It also has been
criticized elsewhere. See In re High Fructose Corn Syrup Antitrust Litig., 295 F.3d 651, 661 (7th Cir. 2002)
(referring to In re Baby Food’s distinction between direct and circumstantial evidence as “confusing”).
4
advising distributors that it would cut off access if the distributors failed to maintain a certain
price level was direct evidence of a conspiracy. 16
Similarly, Publisher Defendants here all threatened Amazon that unless it moved to
agency (and accepted increased retail prices) Publisher Defendants would withhold their ebooks. 17 And there also is substantial direct evidence that Apple knew that Publisher Defendants
would make this very threat to Amazon, and in fact encouraged them to do so. For example, Mr.
Cue had advised Random House that if Amazon balked at moving to an agency relationship,
“windowing could be used to establish a distributor [i.e., agency] model.” 18 Similarly, in March
2010, Apple’s Counsel Kevin Saul suggested to a smaller publisher that to comply with Apple’s
MFN, the publisher could “get others on an agency model, or withhold content.” 19 And, of
course, Mr. Jobs indicated Apple’s knowledge that Publisher Defendants would demand agency
terms from Amazon and every other e-book retailer when he told his biographer, before any
publisher had actually delivered the ultimatum, that Publisher Defendants “went to Amazon and
said, ‘You’re going to sign an agency contract or we’re not going to give you the books.’” 20
There also is overwhelming direct evidence that Apple understood Publisher Defendants
collectively would use their price-setting authority under an agency model to raise consumer
prices. Not least, Mr. Jobs admitted to his authorized biographer that Apple had “told the
16
465 U.S. 752, 765 (1984). Although Monsanto often is cited for its language on inferring agreement, the Court
actually upheld a jury verdict citing “substantial direct evidence of agreements to maintain prices.” Id. (emphasis in
original).
17
Plaintiffs’ PFoF, at ¶¶ 180-83.
18
Id. at ¶ 107. Given that Mr. Cue repeatedly made identical or near-identical communications to Publisher
Defendants, it is a reasonable inference that Mr. Cue gave the same advice to those publishers who actually
threatened Amazon.
19
Id. at ¶ 180.
20
PX-0514, at pp. 503–04. See also infra note 71 and accompanying text.
5
publishers, ‘We’ll go to the agency model, where you set the price, and we get our 30%, and yes,
the customer pays a little more, but that’s what you want anyway.’” 21
Courts also treat contemporaneous writings by co-conspirators that detail conspiratorial
meetings as direct evidence of a conspiracy. 22 Again, there is ample direct evidence in this form
of both Publisher Defendants’ horizontal agreement and Apple’s knowing participation therein.
For example, Apple Counsel Kevin Saul’s notes from Apple’s December 15–16 meetings with
Publisher Defendants include an entry that HarperCollins proposed the agency model to “fix
Amazon pricing.” 23
Just days later, after speaking with three Publisher Defendant CEOs on December 21,
2009, Apple’s Mr. Cue sent a summary of the conversations to Mr. Jobs. Mr. Cue explained that
each Publisher Defendant understood that Apple’s industry-wide agency proposal “solves
Amazon issue.” 24 Ms. Reidy of Simon & Schuster circulated her own summary of her
December 21 conversation with Mr. Cue, writing that Mr. Cue “relay[ed] his conclusions” based
on “having met with all the major publishers.” Mr. Cue told Ms. Reidy that it was “important to
Apple that there be ‘some level of reasonable pricing’” and that Apple believed “the only way to
get this is for the industry to go to the agency model.” 25
Less than two weeks later, Mr. Cue sent Publisher Defendants and Random House
substantively identical emails demanding that they move all retailers to agency because
otherwise Apple would remain exposed to price competition from retailers who remained on the
21
PX-0514, at p. 503 (emphasis added). See also Plaintiffs’ Memo at 26; Plaintiffs’ PFoF, at ¶¶ 92, 214; Plaintiffs’
Proposed Conclusions of Law, at ¶ 37.
22
See, e.g., Arnold Pontiac-GMC, Inc. v. Budd Baer, Inc., 826 F.2d 1335, 1338 (3d Cir.1987).
23
PX-0036, at APLEBOOK-01601745.
24
Plaintiffs’ PFoF, at ¶ 108.
25
Id. at ¶ 105 (emphasis added).
6
wholesale model. 26 In a follow-up conversation on January 9 documented by Ms. McIntosh of
Random House, Keith Moerer described Apple’s plan as a “way that would move the whole
market off 9.99.” 27 Likewise, Hachette’s Ms. Thomas made notes of a January 19, 2010
conversation with Mr. Cue, including his observation that the Apple Agency Agreements were
“the best chance for publishers to challenge the 9.99 price point.” 28
On January 24, Mr. Jobs invited News Corporation’s James Murdoch to “[t]hrow in with
Apple and see if we can all make a go of this to create a real mainstream ebooks market at
$12.99 and $14.99.” 29 And on January 26, the day that HarperCollins became the fifth and final
Publisher Defendant to sign an Apple Agency Agreement, Apple lead negotiator Eddy Cue
praised Simon & Schuster CEO Ms. Reidy as the “real leader of the book industry.” Ms. Reidy
responded by thanking Mr. Cue and expressing her hope that the iPad launch event the next day
would “sustain us as we move through the next steps in the process of changing this industry.” 30
Thus, Apple’s attempt to distinguish this case from Interstate Circuit and Toys “R” Us on the
ground that “Plaintiffs do not allege that Apple participated in or knew of a single one of the
meetings or conversations that allegedly formed the basis of the purported conspiracy” 31 is
baseless.
26
Id. at ¶ 109.
27
Id. at ¶ 115.
28
PX-0521, at HBG00013352.
29
PX-0032, at APLEBOOK-03345078 (emphasis added). Apple’s contention that Mr. Jobs’ e-mail correspondence
with Mr. Murdoch “reflects two executives wrestling with the realities of the e-books business” is unconvincing.
Apple Memo at 31. Mr. Jobs plainly states that Publisher Defendants can either continue having Amazon price new
release e-books at $9.99, or “throw in with Apple” in order to “create a real mainstream ebooks market at $12.99
and $14.99.” Mr. Jobs’ e-mail is direct evidence that Apple and Publisher Defendants knew that the price tiers
would be the actual prices Publisher Defendants would charge for e-books. Indeed, Mr. Jobs’ acute awareness of
Publisher Defendants’ unhappiness with the $9.99 pricing belies any credible claim that Mr. Jobs could have been
unaware of Publisher Defendants’ pricing plans under agency.
30
PX-0613, at DOJ-SS0075849.
31
Apple Memo at 22.
7
Of course, direct admissions of wrongdoing by employees of the conspirators also
constitute direct evidence of a conspiracy. 32 Here, the then-CEOs of both Defendants have
expressly acknowledged the contours of the common scheme. Penguin’s CEO David Shanks
admitted that Apple was the “facilitator and go between” for Publisher Defendants. 33 And at the
iPad’s launch, Mr. Jobs confidently asserted that Apple’s e-book prices would “be the same” as
Amazon’s, with the context clear that Amazon’s prices would be increased. 34 The next day,
moreover, Mr. Jobs actually admitted that not only would prices be “the same,” but that “the
customer pays a little more.” 35
In its ruling on Defendants’ motions to dismiss the parallel class case, this Court
recognized that, if proved, many of Plaintiffs’ allegations were properly thought of as direct
evidence. 36 This category included Mr. Jobs’ “prescient prediction” that Amazon’s e-book
prices would be the same as Apple’s, as well as statements by Publisher Defendants that
Amazon’s pricing was a “big problem” for the industry and the identical demands made by
Publisher Defendants (four on the same day) that Amazon switch to the agency model. 37 The
direct evidence before the Court today is considerably wider and stronger than the allegations at
issue in Defendants’ motions to dismiss. 38
Even under Apple’s misstatement of Matsushita and Monsanto, direct evidence vitiates
the standard it seeks to apply. Given the overwhelming direct evidence that Apple participated
32
In re Text Messaging Antitrust Litig., 630 F.3d 622, 628 (7th Cir. 2010); In re High Fructose Corn Syrup, 295
F.3d at 662.
33
PX-0542, at PEN-LIT-00199145.
34
PX-0615, at 1:57.
35
PX-0514, at p. 503.
36
In re Elec. Books Antitrust Litig., 859 F. Supp. 2d 671, 686–87 (S.D.N.Y. 2012).
37
Id.
38
Other examples of direct evidence of the conspiracy among Apple and Publisher Defendants can be found in
Plaintiffs’ Proposed Conclusions of Law, at ¶¶ 14, 37.
8
in and facilitated Defendants’ agreement, it is unnecessary for the Court to determine whether
Plaintiffs’ evidence “tends to exclude” the possibility of independent conduct. 39
B. Apple Misstates the Law Governing a Vertical Actor’s Liability for Participating in a
Horizontal Price-Fixing Conspiracy.
Even without the abundance of direct evidence in this record, the Court would be correct
to reject Apple’s claim that so long as it “acted independently in pursuit of its own business
interests . . . any inference of a conspiracy” is “preclude[d].” 40 Apple confuses the relevant legal
standard for inferring conspiracy among horizontal competitors accused of parallel conduct (e.g.,
Publisher Defendants) with the standard for inferring whether Apple was “in the center as the
ringmaster” of that agreement. 41 Here, there is no allegation of parallel conduct between Apple
and any other defendant—no such allegation would make sense, as Apple could act in parallel
only with its own rivals, other e-book retailers in this case. Rather, the allegation before the
Court, similar to Toys “R” Us, is that Apple facilitated a conspiracy of its suppliers to restrain
Apple’s competitors. Apple’s legal argument thus is untethered from both precedent and logic. 42
In Apple’s reading of the law, because it “acted at all times in its independent economic
interest,” it cannot be held liable under Section 1 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1. 43 Apple
has collected 31 cases that purportedly stand for this proposition. But in each case, the actual
issue before the court was whether a conspiracy among rivals could be inferred from parallel
conduct. In those circumstances, the “independent economic interest” rule makes sense because
39
See Apple Memo at 22–23.
40
Id. at 24.
41
Toys “R” Us, Inc. v. FTC, 221 F.3d 928, 934 (7th Cir. 2000).
42
See Fineman v. Armstrong World Indus., 980 F.2d 171, 214 n.32 (3d Cir. 1992) (distinguishing horizontal case
where finding of action contrary to self-interest helps rule out parallel behavior from case where one firm is in
vertical relationship with co-conspirators).
43
Apple Memo at 25.
9
it can help distinguish between independent business action and parallel behavior that is part of a
conspiracy. Thus, for example, in assessing the plausibility of a conspiracy among airlines—
clearly horizontal rivals—the Sixth Circuit held that it could not infer agreement from the
airlines’ parallel reduction of commission rates because doing so would have advanced each
defendant’s economic self-interest if undertaken individually. 44
In United States v. General Motors Corp., on the other hand, the Supreme Court found a
group boycott to be illegal per se where a group of car dealers had joined together with their
manufacturer, General Motors, to stop some dealers from reselling their automobiles to
discounters. 45 To effectuate the conspiracy:
General Motors sought to elicit from all the dealers agreements, substantially
interrelated and interdependent, that none of them would do business with the
discounters. These agreements were hammered out in meetings between
nonconforming dealers and officials of General Motors’ Chevrolet Division, and
in telephone conversations with other dealers. It was acknowledged from the
beginning that substantial unanimity would be essential if the agreements were to
be forthcoming. . . . [O]ne of the purposes behind the concerted effort . . . was to
protect [defendants] from real or apparent price competition. 46
Similarly, Apple facilitated and supported an agreement among Publisher Defendants to move
Amazon and other retailers to agency and then set consumer e-book prices—at all e-book stores,
not just Apple’s iBookstore—at the caps established in the Apple Agency Agreements. Apple
and Publisher Defendants all recognized that the success of the conspiracy required substantial
uniformity and unanimity both as to Publisher Defendants’ participation in, and the terms of, the
44
In re Travel Agent Comm’n Antitrust Litig., 583 F.3d 896, 908 (6th Cir. 2009). This is just one example from the
litany of cases Defendant cites on this point. They are all variations on this same theme. See Apple Memo at 26 n.6
& App. A.
45
384 U.S. 127, 143–44 (1966). Just as in this case, the conspiracy was multi-level but fundamentally horizontal.
46
Id. at 144, 147.
10
conspiracy. 47 Apple and Publisher Defendants then acted in concert to provide an “elegant
solution” to Apple’s desire to avoid competing on price against retailers such as Amazon. 48
General Motors defended its conduct with an argument nearly identical to Apple’s: that
its conduct was in its own independent economic interest. But the Supreme Court held that “by
no stretch of the imagination” could General Motors’ conduct in relation to its dealers be
described as “merely ‘parallel,’” and that it was of “no consequence . . . that each party acted in
its own lawful interest. Nor is it of consequence for this purpose whether the [challenged
conduct was] economically desirable.” Id. at 142, 145. 49 Just like General Motors, Apple may
not escape liability because restraining price competition by its rivals was in its independent selfinterest.
II.
Apple and Publisher Defendants Conspired To Raise Consumer E-Book Prices and
Restrain Retail Price Competition.
A. Apple Was Motivated To Conspire with Publisher Defendants in Order To Restrain
Retail E-book Price Competition.
In conjunction with its independent interest argument, Apple contends—without
citation—that the most important question in a Section 1 case is “What motivated the
defendant’s actions?” 50 Since Apple contends that its motivation was merely “its independent
economic interest,” 51 Apple apparently believes that it has found another basis for avoiding
liability. But in a per se case “a finding of intent to conspire to commit the offense is sufficient;
47
Plaintiffs’ PFoF, at ¶¶ 153–70.
48
Kevin Saul Dep., at 163:14–16.
49
Similarly, both Toys “R” Us and the theatres in Interstate Circuit advanced their independent business interests by
facilitating their respective conspiracies—they both blunted price competition from discounters. Toys “R” Us, 221
F.3d at 936; Interstate Circuit, Inc. v. United States, 306 U.S. 208, 226 (1939). Apple’s participation in its
conspiracy with Publisher Defendants similarly allowed it to avoid price competition with Amazon.
50
Apple Memo at 25. On the prior page, however, Apple downplays the importance of intent, stating: “Motivation
to enter a conspiracy is never enough to establish a traditional conspiracy.” Id. at 24.
51
Id. at 25.
11
a requirement that intent go further and envision actual anti-competitive results would reopen the
very questions of reasonableness which the per se rule is designed to avoid.” 52
Thus, it is irrelevant whether Apple intended to advance its independent economic
interests. Rather, the key issue is whether Apple intended to advance those interests by
conspiring with Publisher Defendants. On that score, the record is clear: Apple believed that
facilitating Publisher Defendants’ conspiracy to “fix Amazon pricing” 53 would allow it to
accomplish its goals of opening an iBookstore and realizing generous margins, while avoiding
having to compete against Amazon on price. 54
Nor may Apple avoid antitrust liability by arguing it was bringing order and stability to
“a market in turmoil.” 55 The “uncertain and unsettled” e-books market Apple “sought to enter” 56
was similar to the “acute” market conditions the conspiring oil companies faced in SoconyVacuum. 57 Just as the Supreme Court rejected the oil companies’ claims that their acts to cure a
competitive “evil” shielded them from Section 1 liability, Apple’s self-appointed role to “create a
real mainstream ebooks market at $12.99 and $14.99” does not shield it here. 58
52
United States v. Koppers Co., 652 F.2d 290, 296 n.6 (2d Cir. 1981). Intent may be considered under the rule of
reason, but the Supreme Court has long been clear that a “good intention” will not “save an otherwise objectionable
regulation or the reverse.” Bd. of Trade of City of Chicago v. United States, 246 U.S. 231, 238 (1918).
53
PX-0036, at APLEBOOK-01601745.
54
Plaintiffs’ PFoF, at ¶ 23. In any event, Apple’s conceded intent to advance its own interests by means of
eliminating a rival’s ability to differentiate its offerings based on price, Apple Memo at 25, hardly seems appropriate
to serve as a shield from antitrust liability.
55
Apple Memo at 8; see also id. at 24, 31.
56
Id. at 24.
57
United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150, 170–77 (1940) (describing market conditions in oil and
gasoline industry including, inter alia, a series of “price wars” in retail markets).
58
Plaintiffs’ PFoF, at ¶ 168 (citing PX-0032, at APLEBOOK-03345078).
12
B. Apple’s Conspiracy with Publisher Defendants Was in its Own Economic Interest and
Is, as a Result, Economically Plausible.
Even if the “tends to exclude” standard from Matsushita did apply, here, where the
“conspiracy is economically sensible for the alleged conspirators to undertake,” the standard is
“more easily satisfied.” 59 In fact, Apple itself supplies many “economically sensible” reasons
for it to have conspired with Publisher Defendants. Apple admits that Amazon already was in
the market and competing aggressively. 60 And so long as Amazon retained independent control
of its retail prices, Apple believed it could not purchase e-books on standard wholesale terms, be
“competitive” with Amazon, 61 and still earn its desired 30% gross margins. Thus, Apple
“decided to use the agency model.” 62 But agency was just a means to a “higher consumer
prices” end for Publisher Defendants—who Apple admits were “deeply unhappy” with
Amazon’s low prices 63—and they could achieve that end only if they were able to move Amazon
and other retailers to agency, too. 64 And no Publisher Defendant believed it would have the
bargaining power to do so absent collective action. 65 Publisher Defendants initially opposed
Apple’s inclusion of an MFN, price tiers, and anti-windowing provisions, 66 but subsequently
agreed to Apple’s terms in order to obtain the ability to raise retail prices.
59
In re Publ’n Paper, 690 F.3d at 63.
60
Apple Memo at 24.
61
Id. at 25. Apple uses the word “competitive” in its colloquial (rather than economic) sense, to mean “roughly
equivalent to.” See id. For purposes of economics and antitrust law, “competitive” prices are those determined by
competition (regardless of their proximity to one another). See Richard Gilbert Direct Testimony, at ¶ 57. Retail
e-book prices that are “competitive” in the antitrust sense is exactly what Apple sought to avoid.
62
Apple Memo at 25.
63
Id. at 24.
64
Plaintiffs’ PFoF, at ¶¶ 180–81.
65
See, e.g., Plaintiffs’ PFoF, at ¶¶ 45, 176.
66
All of which Publisher Defendants believed to be contrary to their own individual self-interests, a fact that
supports an inference of a horizontal conspiracy among Publisher Defendants. See Plaintiffs’ Proposed Conclusions
of Law, at ¶¶ 25–26.
13
This is an economically sensible conspiracy, especially for Apple. In contrast, the
Supreme Court held in Matsushita that the alleged conspiracy—that “a large number of firms
have conspired over a period of many years to charge below-market prices”—was implausible
precisely because it was contrary to the alleged conspirators’ interests. 67 Accordingly, even if
the “tends to exclude” standard did apply, it would set a low bar.
C. The Full Body of Circumstantial Evidence Against Apple Supports an Inference of
Conspiracy.
Apple contends that no inference of conspiracy may be made here because none of the
supposed “five pegs” of Plaintiffs’ circumstantial case by itself “tends to exclude the possibility
that Apple acted independently.” 68 But in determining whether a conspiracy existed among
Apple and Publisher Defendants, the Court does not evaluate each piece of evidence in isolation
and determine whether it by itself “tends to exclude” the possibility of concerted action. Instead,
“[a] court must look to the evidence as a whole and consider any single piece of evidence in the
context of other evidence.” 69
So, for example, Apple may be correct when it argues that, standing alone, the price tiers
in the Apple Agency Agreements do not tilt the balance of evidence toward finding a conspiracy.
But there is other evidence that makes clear that Apple and Publisher Defendants all understood
that the common retail price tiers they were negotiating would be the de facto retail prices for
most if not all of their newly released and bestselling e-books once the Apple Agency
67
475 U.S. at 589–95.
68
Apple Memo at 27.
69
In re Flat Glass Antitrust Litig., 385 F.3d 350, 369 (3d Cir. 2004); see also Cont’l Ore Co. v. Union Carbide &
Carbon Corp., 370 U.S. 690, 699 (1962) (“The character and effect of a conspiracy are not to be judged by
dismembering it and viewing its separate parts, but only by looking at it as a whole.”) (citation omitted); Apex Oil
Co. v. DiMauro, 822 F.2d 246, 252–53 (2d Cir. 1987); In re High Fructose Corn Syrup, 295 F.3d at 661.
14
Agreements went into effect. 70 And while Apple may be right that MFNs may be used in other
instances to bargain for lower prices, context makes clear that was not true here. Instead, Apple
knew that this MFN would incentivize Publisher Defendants to follow through on moving their
other retailers to the agency model and raising prices across all retailers. 71
Likewise, Mr. Cue’s December 21, 2009 communications with the CEOs of Macmillan,
Simon & Schuster, and Random House in which he made statements that “book prices are
becoming too low,” that “new release eBooks should be priced at $12.99,” and that, to achieve
“some level of reasonable pricing,” the industry should “go to the agency model” 72—
communications that Apple omits from both its memorandum of law and its proposed findings of
fact 73—may not by themselves condemn Apple here. But when paired with the fact that
Defendants agreed to an agency model that they used to raise the consumer price of most
bestselling e-books from $9.99 to $12.99, those communications (whether characterized as direct
or circumstantial evidence) support inferences of unlawful intent and agreement. 74
III.
Apple’s Attempt To Shift the Focus of this Case to Amazon Is Both Misguided and
Replete with Factual Misstatements.
Despite Amazon’s clear testimony, and even clearer actions, showing that it preferred the
wholesale model to agency, Apple argues that Amazon in fact desired to give up the opportunity
to compete on price in the trade e-books market by moving to an agency relationship with
70
Plaintiffs’ PFoF, at ¶¶ 130–32.
71
PX-0065, at APLEBOOK-00369168; PX-0514, at pp. 503–04; PX-0101, at APLEBOOK-03345032; Apple (Eddy
Cue) CID Dep., at 87:7–12; Eddy Cue Dep., at 300:25–302:14.
72
Plaintiffs’ Memo at 2.
73
See Apple Memo at 10; Apple PFOF, at ¶¶ 82–95.
74
Mr. Jobs’s January 24, 2010 e-mail exchange with James Murdoch, see supra note 29 and accompanying text,
even if viewed as circumstantial rather than direct evidence, similarly supports these inferences.
15
Publisher Defendants. 75 Even if that assertion were true—and it plainly is not—it would be
irrelevant. The victims of Defendants’ conspiracy were e-books consumers, who were forced to
choose between paying more for e-books and buying fewer of them. Whether Amazon willingly
followed Apple and Publisher Defendants down this road—as other retailers such as Barnes &
Noble surely did—is immaterial to the question of whether Apple facilitated a conspiracy to raise
consumer e-book prices and restrain retail price competition, and Apple cites no authority that
suggests otherwise.
Contrary to Apple’s revisionist history, Amazon’s executives have testified consistently
that they “strongly resisted moving to agency and would not have done so but for these
publishers insisting on it simultaneously.” 76 Equally telling, Amazon maintained wholesale
relationships with all publishers save Publisher Defendants and (eventually) Random House,
endured the public and painful “buy button” dispute with Macmillan, and lost access to
Penguin’s newly released e-books for most of April and May 2010 while negotiating new terms.
These are not the actions of a company that secretly desires agency.
Grasping for evidence to the contrary, Apple resorts to selective quotations. Apple shares
with the Court Amazon’s statement to HarperCollins CEO Brian Murray, for example, that when
it came to the agency model, Amazon was “trying not to be closed minded . . . .” 77 But that email’s very next words (replaced by Apple’s ellipsis) read: “but on the face of it we were not
interested. Nothing we’ve seen gives us confidence that publishers will do a good job with
75
See Apple Memo at 33–35. Apple’s current argument contrasts sharply with its and Penguin’s prior claims in this
litigation that Amazon desired to price e-books below cost until it had chased out all competing retailers and
monopolized the market. See PX-0374, at 8–9 (Apple’s Tunney Act submission concerning the proposed Final
Judgment as to Hachette, HarperCollins, and Simon & Schuster); PX-0791, at 4–5 (Penguin’s answer to the United
States’ Complaint).
76
David Naggar Direct Testimony, at ¶ 35; see also Russell Grandinetti Direct Testimony, at ¶¶ 40, 47.
77
Apple PFoF, at ¶ 179.
16
consumer pricing.” 78 Likewise, Apple describes a Brian Murray e-mail as stating that Amazon
“was going to dive into and evaluate the pros and cons of an agency model at an offsite meeting
but that it could not get back to Mr. Murray [for] at least two weeks.” 79 What that e-mail
actually says is: “Amazon is preparing the pros and cons of moving to an agency model for
Bezos. This isn’t a change that they want to do and they haven’t decided if they will fight this
or not. They won’t have a position for a week or two.” 80 Similarly, Apple quotes two sentences
of a Madeline McIntosh e-mail: “It would be a good time to share Amazon thoughts on the
pros/cons of an agency model. In this case what I mean by that is vendor sets price, Amazon
charges a commission per sale.” 81 The next sentence of that e-mail, omitted by Apple, reads: “I
ask this in the belief that Amazon would never accept such a model because it would mean
losing pricing control.” 82
Apple engages in similarly loose treatment of the document on which it relies most
heavily in claiming that Amazon secretly desired agency all along, a January 31, 2010 e-mail
exchange between Random House’s Madeline McIntosh and Amazon’s Laura Porco. 83 Apple
argues that, because Amazon in early 2009 considered pursuing a “profit share” or revenue share
model for e-books—under which Amazon and the publisher each would take a set percentage of
retail revenues instead of Amazon paying the publisher a set wholesale price for each e-book
78
DX-0266, at AMZN-MDL-0161113.
79
Apple PFoF, at ¶ 179 (citing DX-252).
80
DX-252 (emphasis added).
81
Apple PFoF, at ¶ 172 (quoting DX-532).
82
DX-532.
83
DX-278 (AMZN-MDL-0156193), directly or indirectly quoted, cited, or otherwise relied on in: Apple Memo at
15, 35; Apple PFoF, at ¶¶ 57, 191–93, 202, 214.
17
sold—Amazon was pleased to be forced by Publisher Defendants to accept an agency model
with the same revenue split. 84
Apple, however, improperly conflates a revenue share model (under which the retailer
may set the consumer price) with agency (where the publisher sets the consumer price). As
Apple’s own witness, Theresa Horner, Vice President of Digital Content for
Barnesandnoble.com, 85 explains: “a ‘revenue share’ model” is one “where B&N would set an
eBook price in our eBookstore and keep a percentage commission on that sale price,” 86 whereas
“an agency model” is one “in which the publisher set[s] the price and B&N, as an agent, earn[s]
a 30% commission on each eBook sale.” 87 In this case, it is disingenuous for Apple to argue
that, because Amazon might have accepted a 30% split on consumer prices that it set, it also
must have willingly embraced a model where it earned a 30% split on consumer prices Publisher
Defendants set. 88 That Ms. McIntosh and Ms. Porco thought 30% to be a generous split for
Amazon (or Apple) says nothing at all about whether Amazon welcomed ceding retail pricing
authority to Publisher Defendants. 89 And the record clearly is to the contrary.
84
Apple Memo, at 15, 33–35; Apple PFoF, at ¶¶ 190–95, 202.
85
Horner Decl., at ¶ 1.
86
Id. at ¶ 9.
87
Id. at ¶ 17.
88
Apple plays the same game when it suggests that Amazon’s self-publishing Kindle Direct program operates on an
agency model. Apple Memo at 33–34; Apple PFoF, at ¶¶ 175, 284. While self-publishers using Kindle Direct set a
“list price” and are paid a share of revenues, Amazon retains control of the actual retail price consumers pay and
Amazon, not the self-publisher, executes all transactions with consumers; Kindle Direct does not operate on an
agency model. See https://kdp.amazon.com/self-publishing/help?topicId=APILE934L348N (“5.3.4 Customer
Prices. To the extent not prohibited by applicable local laws, we have sole and complete discretion to set the retail
customer price at which your Digital Books are sold through the Program. We are solely responsible for processing
payments, payment collection, requests for refunds and related customer service, and will have sole ownership and
control of all data obtained from customers and prospective customers in connection with the Program.” (bold in
original; italics added)).
89
It bears noting that this e-mail exchange strongly supports both (i) that accepting an Apple Agency Agreement
was contrary to the economic interests of any Publisher Defendant absent the conspiracy, and (ii) that collective
action was required, and used, to force Amazon to accept agency. Ms. McIntosh notes in her opening e-mail: “I
guess what we never figured in was the idea that five publishers would band together and insist on receiving worse
18
Apple’s attempts—shifting but unceasing from the very beginning of this litigation—to
put Amazon on trial lack any basis in fact or law, and do not erase the substantial harm suffered
by consumers from Apple’s price-fixing conspiracy with Publisher Defendants.
IV.
Apple Cannot Escape Liability Even Under the Rule of Reason.
In its brief, Apple offers just one conclusory footnote on the “quick look” doctrine. 90 But
if the Court does not find per se illegality here, no more than a quick look is required to
determine the anticompetitive character of the common scheme at issue. Specifically, there is no
need for the Court to conduct a full blown market analysis under the rule of reason because the
conduct in question resembles past anticompetitive schemes such as those found in Toys “R” Us,
Interstate Circuit, and General Motors, and its effect—raising consumer prices and restraining
retail price competition—strikes a blow to “the central nervous system of the economy.” 91
Accordingly, under the quick look doctrine, Apple’s conspiracy with Publisher Defendants
should be held to violate Section 1 absent “some competitive justification even in the absence of
a detailed market analysis.” 92 As discussed infra, Apple has no such justification for its conduct.
Apple’s efforts to escape liability under the rule of reason suffer from similar defects as
its per se arguments. First, Apple erroneously suggests that a plaintiff’s initial showing under
the rule of reason must be more than “a substantially harmful effect on competition.” 93 Second,
Apple pretends that the restraint subject to review in this case is the vertical agency agreement
between Apple and each Publisher Defendant instead of the horizontal agreement to raise
terms.” DX-278, at AMZN-MDL-0156194. Ms. Porco responds by commenting on how well served Random
House was by essentially cheating on the conspiracy by sticking with the higher wholesale prices and lower retail
prices of the traditional wholesale model: “And, who would have thought you would be sitting soo pretty…..able to
write your own ticket. Sweet relative advantage. Brilliant.” Id. at AMZN-MDL-0156193.
90
Apple Memo at 37 n.10.
91
Socony-Vacuum, 310 U.S. at 224 n.59.
92
Nat’l Collegiate Athletic Ass’n v. Bd. of Regents of Univ. of Okla., 468 U.S. 85, 109–10 (1984).
93
Capital Imaging Assocs., P.C. v. Mohawk Valley Med. Assocs., 996 F.2d 537, 546 (2d Cir. 1993).
19
consumer e-book prices and restrain retail price competition using the agency model. Third,
Apple offers, as supposed procompetitive effects of Defendants’ conduct, events unrelated to the
market for trade e-books or otherwise not cognizable under the rule of reason.
As an initial matter, Apple argues that Plaintiffs must show price effects on “all trade ebook titles,” 94 to satisfy the initial burden under the rule of reason to show actual adverse effects
“on competition as a whole in the relevant market.” 95 The “competition as whole” language,
however, simply puts into practice the longstanding principle that antitrust laws protect
competition, not competitors. 96 This principle seeks to ensure that a plaintiff shows “more than
just that he was harmed by defendant’s conduct.” 97 It does not require that all products within
the relevant market reflect the effects of Defendants’ conspiracy, nor does it have any weight in a
law enforcement action that does not seek damages. Apple offers no authority to the contrary.
At the same time, Apple mostly ignores the actual detrimental effects that the analyses by
Professor Gilbert and Professor Ashenfelter demonstrate: significantly higher retail prices for
Publisher Defendants’ e-books after Publisher Defendants collectively moved to agency. 98 Even
94
Apple Memo at 38 (emphasis in original).
95
Id. (citing Capital Imaging, 996 F.2d at 543). Apple skips any analysis of the other valid method by which
Plaintiffs can meet their initial burden—showing market power in a defined market, Tops Mkts., Inc. v. Quality
Mkts., Inc., 142 F.3d 90, 96 (2d Cir. 1998)—with a cursory aside stating that it does not possess market power and a
curious citation to a footnote in a recent case addressing standing, not the rule of reason. Apple Memo at 37 (citing
Gatt Commc’ns, Inc. v. PMC Assocs., L.L.C., 711 F.3d 68, 75 n.8 (2d Cir. 2013)). The appropriate measure of
market power here, though, is the collective market power of Publisher Defendants, whose power they and Apple
exploited to limit retail price competition. See, e.g., In re Ins. Brokerage Antitrust Litig., 618 F.3d 300, 332–33 (3d
Cir. 2010) (explaining that the facilitators in Interstate Circuit and Toys “R” Us sought to “exploit the . . . collective
market power” of the horizontal competitors whose conspiracies they helped facilitate). Plaintiffs accordingly also
carry their burden on this alternative basis.
96
Clorox Co. v. Sterling Winthrop, Inc., 117 F.3d 50, 57 (2d Cir. 1997) (citing Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-OMat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477, 488 (1977)).
97
Id. at 57 (quoting K.M.B. Warehouse Distribs. v. Walker Mfg. Co., 61 F.3d 123, 127 (2d Cir. 1995)).
98
Plaintiffs’ PFoF, at ¶¶ 220–22. Apple baldly claims that “[a]verage prices for trade e-books have fallen, and
output, whether measured in the number of sales, the number of titles, or the types and quality of e-books offered,
has increased substantially. These facts are undisputed.” Apple Memo at 5. To the contrary, the analysis on which
Apple relies to make these assertions is so flawed and unreliable that it should be excluded. See Pls.’ Mot. in
20
Apple’s expert, Dr. Burtis, confirmed that “average prices for Publisher Defendants’ ebooks
increased” after the Apple Agency Agreements went into effect. 99
Apple tries to cabin those effects to only “prices of defendant publishers’ new release
titles” and tries to minimize them with the claim that “these titles were only a fraction of the
relevant market.” 100 Professors Gilbert and Ashenfelter, however, found price effects across
Publisher Defendants’ entire e-book catalogs, not just their new releases. 101
In any event, it was Amazon’s “wretched” $9.99 pricing of newly released and
bestselling titles that Publisher Defendants so despised. 102 Indeed, all Defendants recognized the
importance of these titles: they were the ones covered by the pricing tiers and retail price MFN
in the Apple Agency Agreements. Contrary to Apple’s suggestion, the conspiracy’s price effects
on those e-books, and on all of Publisher Defendants’ e-books, more than surpass Plaintiffs’
initial burden of showing actual detrimental effects of the conspiracy. 103
Apple’s brief fails even to address the findings of Professors Gilbert, Ashenfelter, and
Baker that the output of Publisher Defendants’ e-books fell relative to what it would have been
but for the conspiracy. 104 Apple instead retreats again behind its manufactured standard that
Plaintiffs must show effects on all products in the market as a whole. Even if that were correct,
though, Plaintiffs have produced just that type of market-wide output effects evidence in the
Limine to Preclude Dr. Michelle Burtis from Offering at Trial Any Opinion on Competitive Effects, Apr. 26, 2013,
at 3–4, 7–9.
99
Plaintiffs’ PFoF, at ¶ 223.
100
Apple Memo at 39.
101
Plaintiffs’ PFoF, at ¶¶ 220–22.
102
Id. at ¶¶ 25–31.
103
See, e.g., Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Tech. Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451, 478 (1992) (listing higher prices as a
type of harm antitrust laws aim to prevent); Virgin Atl. Airways Ltd. v. British Airways PLC, 257 F.3d 256, 264 (2d
Cir. 2001) (identifying increased prices, reduced output, and decreased quality as ways to demonstrate actual
anticompetitive effects).
104
Plaintiffs’ PFoF, at ¶¶ 241–43.
21
form of Professor Ashenfelter’s analysis showing that growth rate for e-books slowed after
Publisher Defendants went to agency as part of their conspiracy. 105 This evidence independently
satisfies Plaintiffs’ initial burden to show that Apple and Publisher Defendants’ conduct harmed
competition and not just an individual competitor, 106 and thus demonstrates actual detrimental
effects under the rule of reason. 107
Compounding its error of misstating Plaintiffs’ initial burden, Apple mistakenly focuses
on claimed procompetitive effects of “the agency model,” 108 which Plaintiffs do not challenge.
Rather, Plaintiffs challenge the conspiracy among Apple, Penguin, and the other Publisher
Defendants to raise consumer e-book prices and to blunt retail price competition. Apple and
Publisher Defendants used the agency model as a tool to accomplish their illegal objectives. In
any event, the procompetitive effects Apple would claim mostly derive from Amazon redoubling
its competitive efforts with respect to titles not controlled by Publisher Defendants. 109 Not
surprisingly, Apple offers no legal authority for its perverse position that conspirators may be
saved from antitrust liability if their target tries to cope with the conspiracy by competing harder
elsewhere.
Throughout its memorandum, Apple also conflates benefits arising from the iPad—which
would have existed and would have functioned as an e-reader under any circumstances, 110 and so
cannot be credited to Defendants’ unlawful agreement—with benefits from Apple’s entry as an
105
Id. at ¶ 246.
106
Clorox, 117 F.3d at 57.
107
Capital Imaging, 996 F.2d at 546 (“Rule of reason analysis requires the antitrust plaintiff to bear the initial
burden of demonstrating that the defendants’ conduct or policy has had a substantially harmful effect on
competition. The plaintiff may satisfy this burden without detailed market analysis by offering proof of actual
detrimental effects, such as a reduction of output.” (quotations omitted)); Virgin Atl., 257 F.3d at 264 (showing
output effect is a method for plaintiff to meet initial burden).
108
Apple Memo at 37.
109
Apple Memo at 37–38.
110
Plaintiffs’ PFoF, at ¶¶ 32–35.
22
e-book retailer. 111 Whatever the benefits the iPad may have brought consumers (such as the
capabilities of the iPad itself and enhanced device competition), those benefits fall outside of the
relevant market of trade e-books. Only procompetitive effects within the relevant market weigh
against anticompetitive effects in the same relevant market. 112
Relatedly, Apple appears to argue that its entry alone qualifies as a procompetitive
benefit. 113 This “entry for entry’s sake” argument loses sight of the ultimate touchstone of a rule
of reason analysis: whether the examined restriction harms consumers—a focus that “cannot be
overemphasized.” 114 Apple’s entry did not meaningfully benefit consumers because it did not
yield price competition—Publisher Defendants’ e-book prices were the same (and higher) across
all retailers, just as Mr. Jobs envisioned. 115
Finally, even if Apple’s procompetitive justifications are credited, Plaintiffs still prevail,
both because any procompetitive benefits are swamped by the harm suffered by consumers, and
by a showing under the third step of the rule of reason analysis that less restrictive alternatives to
the conspiracy existed. 116 Specifically, Apple could have either (i) negotiated agency
111
See, e.g., Apple Memo at 5, 7, 36.
112
See United States v. Topco Assocs., Inc., 405 U.S. 596, 610 (1972).
113
Apple Memo at 23–24. High, protected margins generally increase the willingness of firms to enter markets. If
this were a justification for price-fixing and other naked restraints, thought, the Sherman Act would be gravely
compromised. As the Supreme Court explained in Catalano, Inc. v. Target Sales, Inc.: “in any case in which
competitors are able to increase the price level or to curtail production by agreement, it could be argued that the
agreement has the effect of making the market more attractive to potential new entrants. If that potential justifies
horizontal agreements among competitors imposing one kind of voluntary restraint or another on their competitive
freedom, it would seem to follow that the more successful an agreement is in raising the price level, the safer it is
from antitrust attack. Nothing could be more inconsistent with our cases.” 446 U.S. 643, 649 (1980); see also Nat’l
Collegiate Athletic Ass’n, 468 U.S. at 115–17 (rejecting argument that restraint on number of television broadcasts
of football games could be justified by a desire to protect live attendance receipts).
114
Clorox, 117 F.3d at 56 (citation omitted).
115
Plaintiffs’ PFoF, at ¶¶ 171, 217–30.
116
Geneva Pharm. Tech. Corp. v. Barr Labs. Inc., 386 F.3d 485, 506–07 (2d Cir. 2004) (listing steps of rule of
reason analysis).
23
agreements without serving as “the facilitator and go between” for Publisher Defendants, 117 and
without insisting on contractual provisions that predictably served to increase Publisher
Defendants’ incentives to collectively force Amazon onto the agency model, or (ii) simply
entered the market on traditional wholesale terms and competed on price against Amazon and
others, the way new competitors typically enter markets. Those options may not have been as
profitable to Apple as the unlawful one it chose instead, but at least they would not have forced
e-book consumers to foot the bill for Apple’s insistence on 30% margins and protection from
price competition. And the antitrust laws do not require that a “less restrictive alternative” be as
profitable as the conduct challenged.
CONCLUSION
Contrary to Apple’s alarmist rhetoric, 118 there is nothing “dangerous” about condemning
Apple’s role in its common scheme with Publisher Defendants to raise consumer e-book prices
and restrain retail price competition. Protecting consumers from the harmful effects of such
agreements is exactly what the antitrust laws are meant to do.
Apple’s argument that it should evade antitrust liability because it never acted contrary to
its own economic interests effectively would offer antitrust immunity to any cartel ringmaster.
No firm would organize a horizontal conspiracy among its suppliers—as Plaintiffs allege Apple
did here—unless it was in its own interests. And Apple’s related suggestion that finding it liable
here could chill procompetitive conduct in the future likewise is misplaced. A distributor who
learns that a group of manufacturers would like to use its entry (or perhaps its expansion—Apple
offers no reasoned limiting principle to the new carve-out from the Sherman Act it would create)
to change their long-held business practices for the express purpose of raising consumer prices
117
PX-0542, at PEN-LIT-00199145.
118
Apple Memo at 6.
24
should pause before participating in such a venture. Apple did not pause. Instead, it embraced a
Publisher Defendant’s proposal to “fix Amazon[’s] pricing” 119 and offered Publisher Defendants
a way collectively to “solve[ the] Amazon issue.” 120 And, as Mr. Jobs proudly proclaimed to his
biographer, “we pulled it off.” 121
Accordingly, the Court should declare that Apple has violated the Sherman Act, 15
U.S.C. § 1, and order all equitable relief necessary to undo the effects of Defendants’ agreement
and prevent Apple from similarly violating the antitrust laws in the future.
119
PX-0036, at APLEBOOK-01601745.
120
Plaintiffs’ PFoF, at ¶ 108.
121
PX-0514, at p. 504.
25
Dated: May 3, 2013
Respectfully submitted,
Mark W. Ryan
Lawrence E. Buterman
Daniel McCuaig
United States Department of Justice
Antitrust Division
450 Fifth Street, NW, Suite 4000
Washington, DC 20530
(202) 532-4753
Mark.W.Ryan@usdoj.gov
On Behalf of the United States of America
Gabriel Gervey
Eric Lipman
David Ashton
Assistant Attorneys General
Office of the Attorney General of Texas
P.O. Box 12548
Austin, TX 78711
(512) 463-1262
Gabriel.Gervey@texasattorneygeneral.gov
W. Joseph Nielsen
Gary M. Becker
Assistant Attorneys General
Office of the Attorney General of Connecticut
55 Elm Street
Hartford, CT 06106
(860) 808-5040
Joseph.Nielsen@ct.gov
On Behalf of the Plaintiff States
26
Disclaimer: Justia Dockets & Filings provides public litigation records from the federal appellate and district courts. These filings and docket sheets should not be considered findings of fact or liability, nor do they necessarily reflect the view of Justia.
Why Is My Information Online?