Apple Inc. v. Samsung Electronics Co. Ltd. et al
Filing
2130
Declaration Reply Declaration Of John R. Hauser In Support Of Apples Motion For A Permanent Injunction filed byApple Inc.. (Attachments: # 1 Exhibit A, # 2 Exhibit B, # 3 Exhibit C, # 4 Exhibit D, # 5 Exhibit E, # 6 Exhibit F, # 7 Exhibit G)(Jacobs, Michael) (Filed on 11/9/2012)
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
HAROLD J. MCELHINNY (CA SBN 66781)
hmcelhinny@mofo.com
MICHAEL A. JACOBS (CA SBN 111664)
mjacobs@mofo.com
RACHEL KREVANS (CA SBN 116421)
rkrevans@mofo.com
JENNIFER LEE TAYLOR (CA SBN 161368)
jtaylor@mofo.com
MORRISON & FOERSTER LLP
425 Market Street
San Francisco, California 94105-2482
Telephone: (415) 268-7000
Facsimile: (415) 268-7522
8
9
Attorneys for Plaintiff and
Counterclaim-Defendant APPLE INC.
10
WILLIAM F. LEE
william.lee@wilmerhale.com
WILMER CUTLER PICKERING
HALE AND DORR LLP
60 State Street
Boston, MA 02109
Telephone: (617) 526-6000
Facsimile: (617) 526-5000
MARK D. SELWYN (SBN 244180)
mark.selwyn@wilmerhale.com
WILMER CUTLER PICKERING
HALE AND DORR LLP
950 Page Mill Road
Palo Alto, California 94304
Telephone: (650) 858-6000
Facsimile: (650) 858-6100
11
12
UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
13
NORTHERN DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA
14
SAN JOSE DIVISION
15
16
APPLE INC., a California corporation,
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
Plaintiff,
v.
Case No. 11-cv-01846-LHK (PSG)
REPLY DECLARATION OF
JOHN R. HAUSER IN SUPPORT
OF APPLE’S MOTION FOR A
PERMANENT INJUNCTION
SAMSUNG ELECTRONICS CO., LTD., a
Korean corporation; SAMSUNG
ELECTRONICS AMERICA, INC., a New
York corporation; and SAMSUNG
TELECOMMUNICATIONS AMERICA,
LLC, a Delaware limited liability company,
Defendants.
24
25
26
27
28
REPLY HAUSER DECL. ISO APPLE’S MOTION FOR PERMANENT INJUNCTION
CASE NO. 11-CV-01846-LHK (PSG)
pa-1560004
1
2
I, John R. Hauser, hereby declare as follows:
3
1.
I am the Kirin Professor of Marketing at the MIT Sloan School of Management at
4
the Massachusetts Institute of Technology (“MIT”). I have been retained as an independent
5
expert witness in this case. I previously submitted the Expert Report of John R. Hauser, March
6
22, 2012 (the “Hauser Report”). I have attached a copy of my Report as Exhibit A to this
7
declaration. My CV is attached as Exhibit A to the Hauser Report.
8
9
2.
I was asked by counsel for Apple to design and conduct two surveys—one for
smartphones and one for tablets – to determine the price premium, if any, that Samsung
10
consumers are willing to pay for the features associated with the patents at issue.1 My analysis
11
shows that, for both smartphones and tablets, Samsung consumers are willing to pay a significant
12
price premium for the tested features that are covered by the patents at issue. These results
13
demonstrate that there is substantial demand for these patented features. The results were
14
reported and admitted at trial as Plaintiff’s Exhibit 30 as a part of my testimony.
15
3.
On October 19, 2012, Professor Tülin Erdem, Professor Yoram (Jerry) Wind, and
16
Dr. R. Sukumar submitted expert declarations on behalf of Samsung.2 Counsel for Apple has
17
asked me to respond to these declarations. I provide no new opinions and do not expand the
18
Hauser Report or my deposition or trial testimony in this declaration. I provide this declaration to
19
explain why the criticisms in these declarations are mistaken and inconsistent with work
20
previously done by these individuals. Exhibit B contains a list of materials upon which I have
21
relied in coming up with my opinions in this declaration.
22
4.
For the purposes of my declaration, I have summarized the main criticisms of
23
Professor Erdem, Professor Wind, and Dr. Sukumar into four categories. These experts state
24
erroneously: (1) that my conjoint surveys did not measure demand for the features associated with
25
26
27
28
1
The relevant patents are: US 7,844,915 (“’915 Patent”), US 7,469,381 (“’381 Patent”),
and US 7,864,163 (“’163 Patent”).
2
Declaration of Tülin Erdem in Support of Samsung’s Opposition to Apple’s Motion for a
Permanent Injunction, October 19, 2012 (“Erdem Report”); Declaration of Yoram (Jerry) Wind,
October 19, 2012 (“Wind Report”); and Declaration of R. Sukumar in Support of Samsung’s
Opposition to Apple’s Motion for a Permanent Injunction and for Damages Enhancements,
October 19, 2012 (“Sukumar Report”).
REPLY HAUSER DECL. ISO APPLE’S MOTION FOR PERMANENT INJUNCTION
CASE NO. 11-CV-01846-LHK (PSG)
pa-1560004
1
1
2
the infringed patents; (2) that conjoint surveys are hypothetical and do not accurately measure
3
what people are willing to pay in the real world; (3) that my surveys lead to unrealistic results
4
because my survey methodology is flawed; and, (4) that my survey design might have led to bias.
5
Below, I address each of these categories.
6
(1) My surveys measure the extent to which demand is driven by features associated with
7
the infringed patents.
8
9
5.
My assignment was to measure the price premium that Samsung owners would be
willing to pay for the patent-related features. To do this, I used the widely known technique
10
called conjoint analysis. As Professor Wind has written, “[p]ut simply, conjoint is a method that
11
lets us separate out the various features of a product to see how the consumer values each feature
12
against the others.”3
13
6.
Professor Wind and Dr. Sukumar assert that my conjoint study was not designed to
14
measure consumer demand, but only to measure willingness to pay.4 This distinction has no basis
15
because the very definition of consumer demand is based on the concept of willingness to pay.
16
17
7.
At his deposition, Professor Wind acknowledged that willingness to pay is directly
related to consumer demand:
18
“Q: How does the, how does measuring the willingness to pay for a
product with these features relate to your question of determining
whether it is a feature that makes a significant contribution to the
purchaser’s decision to purchase?
19
20
A: Well, if the people would be willing to pay more for a product
with the feature and actually buy a product at a higher price, then
obviously it is indicated that this feature is important for them, and
therefore, it affects their willingness to buy the product.”5
21
22
23
“Q: It is an accepted definition – in economic literature, one of the
accepted definitions for demand is based on willingness to pay,
correct?
24
25
26
27
28
3
Testimony of Yoram (Jerry) Wind before the Copyright Royalty Board, Library of
Congress In the Matter of Adjustment of Rates and Terms for Preexisting Subscription Services
and Satellite Digital Audio Radio Services (“Wind Copyright Board Testimony”); available at:
http://www.loc.gov/crb/proceedings/2006-1/soundex-wind.pdf.
4
Sukumar Report ¶ 5, Wind Report ¶¶ 40–45.
5
Deposition of Yoram (Jerry) Wind, November 7, 2012 (“Exhibit C”), at 20:9-19.
REPLY HAUSER DECL. ISO APPLE’S MOTION FOR PERMANENT INJUNCTION
CASE NO. 11-CV-01846-LHK (PSG)
pa-1560004
2
1
A: Yes.”6
2
3
8.
It is a fundamental economic principle that demand is defined in terms of a
4
consumer’s willingness to pay. The following quotes from bestselling economics textbooks
5
explain the relationship between demand and willingness to pay:
6
“[T]he height of the demand curve measures the value buyers place
on the good, as measured by their willingness to pay for it.”7
7
“[Y]ou will sometimes find it useful to think of a demand curve as a
curve that represents a consumer’s ‘willingness to pay’ for a
good.”8
8
9
“The demand curve reflects a consumer’s marginal willingness to
pay: the maximum amount a consumer will spend for an extra
unit.” 9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
9.
Measuring consumer preference lies at the heart of conjoint analysis. As I
explained in my Report, “[t]he general idea behind conjoint analysis is that consumers’
preferences for a particular product are driven by features embodied in that product.”10 I
surveyed actual consumers of the Samsung smartphones and tablets that were accused in this case
to ascertain how their preferences for product features of Samsung smartphones and tablets would
inform their choices. The price premiums that I calculated were derived from their choices and
showed their willingness to pay—and hence demand—for the features I tested.
10.
Professor Wind’s assertion that I acknowledged my analysis did not show
consumers bought Samsung smartphones or tablets because they were equipped with the patented
features misconstrues my testimony.11 I stated only that I did not ask those taking the survey to
compare Samsung smartphones and tablets with other devices. Such a comparison is not
necessary to measure the demand for the patented features in Samsung’s smartphones and tablets.
In fact, restricting respondents’ choices to Samsung smartphones and tablets, and limiting the
24
25
26
27
28
6
Exhibit C, at 117:5-8.
N. Gregory Mankiw, Principles of Economics, South-Western Cengage Learning, 6th
edition, 2012, p. 138.
8
David Besanko and Ronald R. Braeutigam, Microeconomics, John Wiley & Sons, 2nd
edition, 2005, p. 138.
9
Jeffrey M. Perloff, Microeconomics, Pearson Education, 5th edition, 2009, p. 271.
10
Exhibit A ¶ 17.
11
Wind Report ¶ 14.
7
REPLY HAUSER DECL. ISO APPLE’S MOTION FOR PERMANENT INJUNCTION
CASE NO. 11-CV-01846-LHK (PSG)
pa-1560004
3
1
2
universe of respondents surveyed to those who recently purchased one of the smartphones or
3
tablets accused in this case, results in the most directly relevant measure of demand for the
4
patented features in the accused products.
5
6
7
8
9
11.
Notably, Dr. Sukumar’s conjoint survey on behalf of Samsung also did not ask
those surveyed to compare the surveyed product with other devices.12
(2) Conjoint surveys accurately measure real world demand.
12.
In his declaration, Professor Wind asserts that the price premiums measured by my
surveys are not reliable due to the fact that “there are no actual consequences to purchasing more
10
expensive products in a hypothetical survey.”13 In short, he suggests that the surveys are
11
unreliable because actual dollars were not used. This is mistaken, inconsistent with Professor
12
Wind’s own practice, and inconsistent with a large body of academic research in this area. As
13
explained in my Report, the conjoint surveys that I undertook are based on methodology
14
commonly used in the field of marketing research. Conjoint analysis was introduced to the field
15
of marketing research in 1971 and is generally recognized by marketing science academics and
16
industry practitioners to be the most widely studied and applied form of quantitative consumer
17
preference measurement.
18
13.
Importantly, it has been shown to provide valid and reliable measures of consumer
19
preferences, and these preferences have been shown to provide valid and reliable forecasts of
20
what consumers will do (or would have done) under scenarios related to those measured.14 For
21
example, under the auspices of MIT’s Virtual Consumer Initiative, my colleagues and I undertook
22
large-scale tests of the validity of Web-based conjoint analysis. Predictions were highly accurate,
23
predicting future choices consumers would make in a subsequent test with real money at stake
24
and predicting what would happen in the marketplace. One of the scientific papers discussing the
25
26
27
28
12
R. Sukumar, Report: Results from A Survey Measuring Use and Valuation of Four
Patented Features (Patented Features: 460, 893, 711, 871) and A Survey of World Clock Patented
Feature Usage (Patented Feature 055), March 22, 2012 (“Sukumar Survey Report”), Exhibit G:
Screen Capture from On-line Survey.
13
Wind Report p. 36.
14
John R. Hauser and Vithala Rao, “Conjoint Analysis, Related Modeling, and
Applications,” Advances in Marketing Research: Progress and Prospects, Jerry Wind and Paul
Green, Eds., (Kluwer Academic Publishers) 2004, pp. 141–168.
REPLY HAUSER DECL. ISO APPLE’S MOTION FOR PERMANENT INJUNCTION
CASE NO. 11-CV-01846-LHK (PSG)
pa-1560004
4
1
2
validity test received two awards as the best paper in the marketing sciences literature for 2003
3
(awarded in 2004) and for the best paper based on a dissertation (awarded in June 2005).15
4
14.
Professor Wind’s own testimony and academic writings contradict his criticism.
5
At his deposition, Professor Wind admitted that in over 40 years of experience with conjoint
6
analyses, he can recall only one study in which consumers used actual dollars:
7
“Q: You can’t remember even one that you’ve ever done – out of
all the conjoint analyses that you’ve done, you can’t remember even
one, sitting here today, where the consumers used actual dollars?
8
9
A: Actually I can remember one.
10
Q: One. In how many years you’ve been doing this, 35, 40?
11
A: Since 1970.”16
12
“Q: And, in fact, you’re not alone in this. It’s not as though you’re
the only person out there who is not using actual dollars. In fact,
it’s extremely rare for anybody to use actual dollars in a conjoint
analysis, right?
13
14
15
16
A: Correct.”17
15.
Further, Professor Wind stated that the use of hypothetical dollars does not impact
the accuracy or reliability of a conjoint analysis.
17
18
“Q. Right. And the fact that real dollars are not used is not
something that impacts the accuracy or reliability of the study?
19
A. Correct. Real dollars is not the factor. The real factor is the
realism of the framing of the questions.” 18
20
21
22
23
16.
Notwithstanding the fact that they do not use actual dollars, conjoint analyses are
acknowledged as accurately reflecting consumer preferences, and have been relied upon for
making real-life marketing decisions for decades. Professor Wind acknowledged this in
testimony he gave to the Copyright Royalty Board of the Library of Congress:
24
[C]onjoint analysis is a fixture in the commercial world. Thousands
of conjoint studies have been administered in the 35 years since the
25
26
27
28
15
Olivier Toubia, Duncan I. Simester, John R. Hauser, and Ely Dahan, “Fast Polyhedral
Adaptive Conjoint Estimation,” Marketing Science, 22, 3, (Summer) 2003, pp. 273–303.
16
Exhibit C, at 55:6-13.
17
Exhibit C, at 56:8-13.
18
Exhibit C, at 56:23-57:3.
REPLY HAUSER DECL. ISO APPLE’S MOTION FOR PERMANENT INJUNCTION
CASE NO. 11-CV-01846-LHK (PSG)
pa-1560004
5
1
technique was first introduced to marketing. Conjoint analysis
underlies innumerable corporate decisions regarding product
design, pricing, positioning, and segmentation decisions where
millions and even billions of dollars are at stake.”19
2
3
4
…
5
At least as critical as the widespread use of the conjoint
methodology is its validation. The continued and repeated use of
conjoint analysis by industry is the best indication of its proven
validity. In addition, conjoint analysis has been validated by studies
that compare different research methods.20
6
7
8
…
9
Since its introduction, businesses and governments and numerous
academic researchers, consulting firms, and marketing research
firms have embraced conjoint analysis as a reliable and valid
method of analyzing consumer preferences when introducing new
products or studying markets. Indeed, businesses and governments
regularly make billions of dollars of decisions based on the results
of conjoint analyses.21
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
17.
Not surprisingly, the conjoint survey conducted by Dr. Sukumar that Samsung
submitted in this case was also a hypothetical survey that did not use real dollars.22
(3) My survey methods were appropriate and the results are valid.
18.
In my conjoint study, as set forth in my Report and in my deposition testimony, I
performed numerous sensitivity analyses and statistical tests. For example, I calculated market
premiums using two related methodologies, showing that they yielded similar results; I checked
the sensitivity of my results, finding them robust to a number of potential variations to the
20
model;23 I undertook multiple tests of internal validity;24 and I tested for demand artifacts and
21
consumer heuristics.25 These tests confirmed that it is appropriate to use the results to estimate
22
the price premiums of the patented features.
23
24
25
26
27
28
19
Wind Copyright Board Testimony, p. 13.
Wind Copyright Board Testimony, Appendix H at 2.
21
Wind Copyright Board Testimony, Appendix H at 3.
22
Sukumar Survey Report.
23
Exhibit A ¶¶ 96–109. See also Hauser Production April 25, 2012 for an analysis
showing that my results are robust to reweighting the survey data as suggested by Dr. Sukumar.
24
Exhibit A ¶¶ 82–90.
25
Exhibit A ¶¶ 19, 36, 42, 47; Hauser Production April 25, 2012; Deposition of John
Hauser, April 27, 2012 (“Exhibit D”), at 244:16–245:5.
20
REPLY HAUSER DECL. ISO APPLE’S MOTION FOR PERMANENT INJUNCTION
CASE NO. 11-CV-01846-LHK (PSG)
pa-1560004
6
1
(a) Professor Wind’s criticisms
2
3
19.
Professor Wind claims my conjoint surveys yield irrational results. More
4
specifically, he uses a statistical model to predict that when faced with two identical but
5
differently priced items, a number of consumers will choose the more expensive one; or that
6
when faced with two identically priced items in which one is objectively better than the other
7
(e.g., all their features are the same, but one has 16 GB of memory while the other has 32 GB of
8
memory), a number of consumers will choose the objectively less attractive item.26 These claims
9
are based on predictions that Professor Wind makes and not on any irrational choices actually
10
found in the surveys. Professor Wind admitted that his results were based on predictions rather
11
than actual choices and that he would have corrected his report to make that clear.27 Further, the
12
approach is flawed.
13
(1) Professor Wind’s criticism is based on his predictive model and not any
14
actual irrational answers in the survey.
15
20.
Importantly, Professor Wind’s claims are not based on any actual irrational
16
choices made by respondents. In fact, Professor Wind failed to identify a single nonsensical
17
choice by a respondent who took the survey:
18
19
“Q: Okay. So you’re reporting predictions that you think are
nonsensical, not actual results of the survey, not actual responses
from the people who took the survey?
20
A: Correct.”28
21
“Q: My question is, you’re not aware of any instance where even
one person made the choice that you’re predicting would occur in
actual fact?
22
23
A: I cannot answer it in terms of we were or not. We didn’t do the
analysis. There may be a lot of them. We did not do this
analysis.29
24
25
26
27
28
26
Wind Report ¶¶ 46-51.
Exhibit C, at 91:7-92:1.
28
Exhibit C, at 88:23-89:2.
29
Exhibit C, at 95:22-96:2.
27
REPLY HAUSER DECL. ISO APPLE’S MOTION FOR PERMANENT INJUNCTION
CASE NO. 11-CV-01846-LHK (PSG)
pa-1560004
7
1
2
All of the raw survey data from my Report was made available to Samsung shortly after I signed
3
my Report in March 2012. Professor Wind admits that these data were sufficient to have allowed
4
him to test for inconsistencies in the actual responses themselves but he did not do so.
(2) Professor Wind’s predictions are flawed.
5
6
21.
Instead of testing the actual data for inconsistencies, Professor Wind made
7
selective predictions based on a statistical model. Professor Wind’s makes hypothetical
8
predictions by exploiting statistical noise in the model I use; his predictions do not correspond to
9
the actual choices respondents made. By focusing on responses at the individual level (which
10
would emphasize statistical “noise”) rather than responses at the aggregate level (which would
11
emphasize accuracy), his predictions pick up too much statistical noise, which increases the
12
probability of irrational responses. 30 As I discussed in my report and deposition, the data as a
13
whole, which is made up of thousands of choices made by hundreds of respondents, allow for
14
very accurate estimations of market-level information, such as the average market premiums
15
consumers are willing to pay for certain features.31 Professor Wind’s focus on exploiting
16
individual-level noise has no bearing on whether the market-level information is accurately
17
measured.
18
22.
Even at the individual level, Professor Wind’s results are a statistical artifact. In
19
my report I calculated my market premium estimates using two different methodologies, which
20
are known as “first choice” and “randomized first choice,” that yielded largely similar results for
21
the question I was asking.32 In my survey, the two approaches agreed and thus reflect the robust
22
nature of the answers and the estimates.
23
24
25
26
27
28
30
For example, if I have a fair coin, and observe 1,000 flips of a coin from 500
consumers, the probability of heads is very likely close to 50%. If I try to make a prediction of
the fairness of the coin based only on observations from an individual consumer who flips the
coin twice, that prediction is not likely to be accurate since, for example, that individual consumer
has a 25% probability of getting heads twice. See Exhibit A ¶¶ 27–29.
31
Exhibit A ¶¶ 27–29; Exhibit D ¶¶ 234:12–15, 254:17–255:2.
32
Exhibit A ¶ 99 and fn. 67.
REPLY HAUSER DECL. ISO APPLE’S MOTION FOR PERMANENT INJUNCTION
CASE NO. 11-CV-01846-LHK (PSG)
pa-1560004
8
1
23.
2
Professor Wind uses only the second approach, known as “randomized first
3
choice,” for his predictions and ignores the “first choice” approach. In fact, for the question he
4
asks, it is “first choice” approach that is the justifiable approach. “Randomized First Choice”
5
begins with the individual-level information that the model has estimated (which as I explained
6
earlier, is inherently less imprecise than aggregate-level information) but then adds a random
7
error term. When used appropriately, the random error term accounts for imprecision and
8
enhances predictive accuracy. But when misused, as in Professor Wind’s analysis, the error term
9
forces a probability that any option, no matter how absurd, can be chosen as a respondent’s first
10
11
choice.
24.
Therefore, if a person wishes to look solely at whether the data predicts irrational
12
choices at the individual level, it is not appropriate to add this random element. Introducing the
13
random element artificially increases the likelihood of irrational choices at the individual level,
14
the level at which Professor Wind performs his analysis. In contrast, the alternate methodology,
15
known as “first choice,” does not introduce the random term described above and is more useful
16
to evaluate whether individuals are making irrational choices. Professor Wind testified at his
17
deposition that he was unable to say whether the irrational results he predicts would disappear if
18
he used the “first choice” analysis because he had not done the work.33 I have done that work and
19
it predicts that all respondents would choose the expected product, as reflected in Exhibit E to this
20
declaration. That is, using the “first choice” approach, the model does not predict irrational
21
choices.
22
25.
Professor Wind also criticizes the survey for coming up with willingness to pay
23
estimates in the smartphone survey that are “comparable to (or greater than) the average price
24
respondents actually paid for their Samsung smartphones.”34 This criticism is invalid. First, the
25
sum of the willingness to pay of the patented features associated with the three patents that were
26
tested is less than what respondents reported that they had paid for their phones. Second, the
27
28
33
34
Exhibit C, at 102:2–11.
Wind Report at ¶ 69.
REPLY HAUSER DECL. ISO APPLE’S MOTION FOR PERMANENT INJUNCTION
CASE NO. 11-CV-01846-LHK (PSG)
pa-1560004
9
1
2
retail price of the phone fails to account for the true cost of ownership, which often includes a
3
two-year service contract and can exceed $2,000. This was also discussed in my trial testimony.35
(b) Dr. Sukumar’s criticisms
4
5
26.
Dr. Sukumar’s assertion that my willingness to pay estimates for certain features
6
such as memory and number of apps are low and not realistic36 is conceptually flawed. It is
7
conceptually flawed because Dr. Sukumar did not take into account that the market premiums
8
calculated are averaged over all respondents. Thus, he asserts that Samsung charges $100 to
9
double the storage capacity of one of its tablets,37 but he misses the point that Samsung offers the
10
tablet both with and without the double capacity. Thus, some consumers who are willing to pay
11
the $100 and others are not. As a result, the average willingness to pay is likely to be below the
12
$100 price Samsung charges to double memory capacity.
13
27.
The survey data reflect these differences in individuals’ preferences. In the survey,
14
7% of smartphone respondents value going from 16 to 32 GB of memory by more than the $100
15
market price and 11% value going from 16 to 64 GB of memory by more than the $200 market
16
price.38 This supports the validity of my surveys’ findings.
17
28.
In addition to the conceptual flaw in Dr. Sukumar’s argument, he relies on a
18
selective reading of my analysis. He relies on a robustness check that I undertook and reported in
19
a footnote of the Hauser Report39 and ignores the central results that I discussed at length in my
20
report.40 The central results, referred to as the “market simulation approach,” provide different
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
35
Tr. at 1942:23-1943:9.
Sukumar Report ¶¶ 16–18.
37
Sukumar Report at ¶ 17.
38
Comparing two otherwise identical smartphones, one of which has 16 GB of memory
and costs $199 and another which has 32 GB and costs $299, 7% of consumers choose the latter
under a first choice simulation. Comparing two otherwise identical smartphones, one of which
has 16 GB of memory and costs $99 and another which has 64 GB and costs $299, 11% of
consumers choose the latter under a first choice simulation.
39
Exhibit A, fn. 72. This analysis tests whether my estimates of the market premiums
associated with the patented features are sensitive to how I aggregate the individual-level
information to calculate the market-level information within the data. I find that my touchscreen
results are not sensitive.
40
Exhibit A ¶¶ 96–105.
36
REPLY HAUSER DECL. ISO APPLE’S MOTION FOR PERMANENT INJUNCTION
CASE NO. 11-CV-01846-LHK (PSG)
pa-1560004
10
1
2
average willingness to pay estimates for the distraction features that are reasonable, even under
3
Dr. Sukumar’s construction.
4
29.
For example, Dr. Sukumar estimates price premiums for 16, 32, and 64 GB of
5
memory to range from $0.04 to $24 for smartphones and from $10 to $57 for tablets. Using the
6
primary methodology in my report instead, the average price premiums range from $16 to $28 for
7
smartphones and from $26 to $51 for tablets. These estimates are reasonable for the average
8
consumer, given that some consumers may value these features highly while others may not.
9
Similarly, Dr. Sukumar finds premiums below $0.05 for different levels of the number of apps
10
feature, but using the primary methodology in my report yields premiums of $6 to $13. These
11
estimates are reasonable in light of other information that reflects diminishing returns to the
12
number of apps.41
13
(4) There is no evidence that my survey design created survey bias.
14
30.
Professor Wind and Dr. Sukumar make a number of assertions regarding the
15
“design flaws” in my surveys and conclude that this may have resulted in survey bias. As a
16
threshold matter, these assertions are speculative. Neither Professor Wind nor Dr. Sukumar has
17
presented any results that show actual bias. If Samsung believed that my survey design caused
18
bias, it could have obtained evidence to support that claim by conducting a modified version of
19
my surveys to prove this. More than sufficient time existed to do so since March of 2012 when I
20
provided my data and report. In his deposition, Professor Wind acknowledged that it could have
21
been done in the two months after his engagement but he was personally too busy to do so:
22
“Q: You point out in your report that, in your opinion, there are a
number of design flaws with Dr. Hauser’s survey. Did you
consider doing another survey in revising some of those flaws to
see what would happen?
23
24
25
26
27
28
41
Randall Stross, “Microsoft + Nokia = a Challenge for Apple,” New York Times, 4/2/11
(“What is often missed is the diminishing returns after 1,000 applications,” says Thomas R.
Eisenmann, a professor at the Harvard Business School. “If a platform attracts the thousand-mostpopular apps, then it provides almost anything a reasonable person would want to do with a
smartphone.”) available at http://www.nytimes.com/2011/04/03/business/03digi.html.
REPLY HAUSER DECL. ISO APPLE’S MOTION FOR PERMANENT INJUNCTION
CASE NO. 11-CV-01846-LHK (PSG)
pa-1560004
11
1
A: No. We didn’t have time. This was very, you know, timecompressed. And there was no way I could have designed a survey
in this time period.”42
2
3
“Q: Okay. So if you didn’t have anything else on your plate, sounds
like you could have done it. It would have been tight, but you could
have done it?...In the time you were approached by Samsung.
4
5
A: Yeah. I was not asked to do the design, nor did I propose it
because I basically had many other commitments and could not
have done it.”43
6
7
8
(a) My survey included an appropriate number of features and distraction features.
9
31.
In addition to the patented features, my survey included several distraction features
10
to make the choice task more realistic and to avoid demand artifacts. My conjoint survey had five
11
distraction features, including features deemed important by Professor Wind, such as camera,
12
connectivity, and size and weight.44 Professor Wind nevertheless asserts that my conjoint survey
13
omits relevant features and thus may be biased.45 I do not agree with that assertion.
14
32.
At the outset, I note that Dr. Sukumar designed a conjoint survey in this litigation
15
where he included only four smartphone features, excluding price.46 He included no distraction
16
features and omitted essentially all of the smartphone and tablet features that Professor Wind
17
asserts are important.47
18
33.
An effort to include all features of a product, especially a complex product, would
19
render the results of a conjoint survey unreliable. Therefore, conjoint surveys typically include a
20
limited number of features, usually eight or fewer.48 Professor Wind has himself conducted
21
conjoint surveys where he has used a limited number of features. For example, in a conjoint
22
study of referral decisions of obstetricians, Professor Wind only included seven factors and
23
24
25
26
27
28
42
Exhibit C, at 27:16–23.
Exhibit C, at 28:8–18.
44
Wind Report ¶¶ 70–72.
45
Wind Report ¶¶ 70–72, Erdem Report ¶¶ 37–49.
46
Sukumar Survey Report, p. 3.
47
Wind Report ¶¶ 70–72.
48
Bryan K. Orme, Getting Started with Conjoint Analysis: Strategies for Product Design
and Pricing Research, Research Publishers, 2nd edition, 2010, p. 51. (“Typical full-profile
conjoint studies in practice involve about eight or fewer attributes….”).
43
REPLY HAUSER DECL. ISO APPLE’S MOTION FOR PERMANENT INJUNCTION
CASE NO. 11-CV-01846-LHK (PSG)
pa-1560004
12
1
2
excluded several others, although they were considered important.49 Similarly, in a litigation
3
study of dental lab technicians conducted by Professor Wind, he only included two factors – price
4
and distribution mode.50 Consistent with Professor Wind’s papers, I included six features in
5
addition to price in my conjoint survey of smartphone users.
6
34.
Although I excluded certain features from my conjoint survey, I instructed the
7
respondents to assume that all those excluded features are the same across all smartphones. This
8
instruction ensured that features that were not included would not affect respondents’ choices.
9
This is a standard assumption made by survey designers. Indeed, Dr. Sukumar made the same
10
assumption in his conjoint survey of smartphone users; he instructed respondents to “[a]ssume
11
that all other features of the iPhone 4 not shown to you are the same.”51
12
(b) I used animations where appropriate.
13
35.
Dr. Sukumar and Professor Wind each assert that the partworths of some of the
14
features (touchscreen, camera, and connectivity) may have been inflated because of the survey
15
design. I disagree.
16
36.
First, Professor Wind’s exhibits are not sufficient to demonstrate bias toward the
17
animated features as he claims. They are equally consistent with the conclusion that the features
18
that were animated – camera , connectivity and touchscreen – have higher willingness to pay
19
estimates because consumers, in fact, are willing to pay higher price premiums for them.
20
37.
Second, the estimated willingness to pay for the animated features is not uniformly
21
higher in my surveys than the willingness to pay for features that were not animated. In contrast
22
with Professor Wind’s Exhibit 21 for smartphones, Exhibit 26 provides a different picture for
23
tablets. Levels for certain features that were not animated such as storage/memory and
24
size/weight have greater partworths than some of the touchscreen feature levels that were
25
26
27
28
49
Douglas K. Richardson, Steven G. Gabbe, and Yoram Wind, “Decision Analysis of
High-Risk Patient Referral,” Obstetrics and Gynecology, Vol. 63, No. 4, April 1984, pp. 496-501.
50
Expert Report of Jerry Wind, United States of America v. Dentsply International, Inc.,
June 14, 2000.
51
Sukumar Survey Report, Exhibit G: Screen Capture from Online Survey.
REPLY HAUSER DECL. ISO APPLE’S MOTION FOR PERMANENT INJUNCTION
CASE NO. 11-CV-01846-LHK (PSG)
pa-1560004
13
1
2
animated. This is consistent with the conclusion that consumers taking the survey were valuing
3
the features themselves, not merely biased by the fact that some of the features were animated.
4
38.
Dr. Sukumar makes a separate assertion that the design of my survey differentiated
5
the touchscreen feature from other features in other ways. In particular, he asserts that the
6
touchscreen feature was differently depicted in the survey, among other ways, through the choice
7
of background colors and how touchscreen levels were crossed out when moving from one level
8
to another.52 Again, Dr. Sukumar does not provide any proof that this differentiation resulted in
9
bias. He also could have tested my survey for design bias in any of these areas but failed to do so.
10
39.
Further, such differentiation also applied to features other than the patented
11
features. My survey has six features in addition to price. The six features are not identical; the
12
descriptions were designed appropriately for the features. For example, the memory feature
13
shows images associated with memory and the apps features shows images associated with apps.
14
Rather than cherry-pick some differences, Dr. Sukumar could also have argued, albeit
15
erroneously, that there were biases because the memory feature is the only one with the color blue,
16
while the number of apps feature is the only one that shows a phone. Dr. Sukumar fails to explain
17
why small differences in the presentation of the patented features led to bias but similar
18
differences in the presentation of the other features did not. Finally, I pretested my survey for
19
such potential biases. None were found.53
20
(c) An “outside option” was not necessary and its inclusion may have created bias.
21
40.
Professor Wind asserts that not allowing respondents to choose an “outside option”
22
(that is, to choose not to purchase the phone or tablet at all) may lead to an inflated willingness to
23
pay for the features that are tested in the conjoint survey. As a threshold matter, the inclusion of
24
an outside option may be necessary when calculating “primary demand” – whether users would
25
purchase a smartphone as opposed to a basic phone. But inclusion of an outside option is
26
27
28
52
53
Sukumar Report ¶¶ 14–15.
Exhibit A ¶ 47.
REPLY HAUSER DECL. ISO APPLE’S MOTION FOR PERMANENT INJUNCTION
CASE NO. 11-CV-01846-LHK (PSG)
pa-1560004
14
1
2
unnecessary to determine the extent to which the patented features drive Samsung consumers’
3
demand for the accused Samsung products.
4
5
41.
At his deposition, Professor Wind admitted that the literature on the topic of the
“outside option” is split on whether it introduces its own bias.
6
“Q: Now, Professor Wind, you know that in the literature there are
many articles that debate whether including an outside option can
bias – including outside option can bias the survey and distort the
results in some circumstances, right?
7
8
A: I think there is mixed messages, if you want to, in the
literature.” 54
9
10
42.
Even the publication Professor Wind relies for the assertion that an “outside
11
option” enhances the realism of the survey acknowledges that inclusion of an “outside option”
12
raises concerns, including the creation of bias.55
13
43.
Professor Wind has himself designed conjoint studies without an “outside” option.
14
For example, in one study respondents were asked to allocate 100 points over various alternatives
15
and they could not choose 0 for all alternatives.56 In other words, an outside option of not
16
choosing any of the alternatives was not provided to respondents. In another litigation-based
17
study of travel agents conducted by Professor Wind, respondents were asked to choose from
18
American Airlines flights or Continental flights.57 Respondents could not select an outside option
19
of not choosing either of the airlines. Similarly, the conjoint survey of smartphone users designed
20
by Dr. Sukumar in this litigation does not offer an outside option to respondents. Dr. Sukumar’s
21
survey instructed respondents to “[a]ssume that the three products shown below are the only
22
iPhone 4 products you can choose from.”58
23
24
25
26
27
28
54
Exhibit C, at 130:5-12.
Jeff D. Brazell, Christopher G. Diener Ekaterina Karniouchina, William L.
Moore,Válerie Séverin and Pierre-Francois Uldry, “The no-choice option and dual response
choice designs,” Marketing Letters, Vol. 17, No. 4, December 2006, p. 256.
56
Expert Report of Jerry Wind, United States of America v. Dentsply International, Inc.,
June 14, 2000, Appendix E, Instructions for Responding to Materials in Envelope B.
57
Yoram (Jerry) Wind, Abba M. Krieger, and Paul E. Green, “Applying Conjoint
Analysis to Legal Disputes: A Case Study,” Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, January
2002, p. 5.
58
Sukumar Survey Report, Exhibit G: Screen Capture from Online Survey.
55
REPLY HAUSER DECL. ISO APPLE’S MOTION FOR PERMANENT INJUNCTION
CASE NO. 11-CV-01846-LHK (PSG)
pa-1560004
15
1
2
(d) My survey did include noninfringing alternatives.
3
44.
Professor Wind and Professor Erdem assert that my conjoint survey did not take
4
into account the noninfringing alternatives that Samsung had for each of the patented features.59
5
They claim that I compared the availability of a patented feature with the non-availability of the
6
patented feature, instead of comparing the patented feature with its noninfringing alternative. As
7
a result, they claim, my willingness to pay estimates are overstated. Their assertions are factually
8
incorrect.
9
45.
My survey included noninfringing alternatives for each of the three alternatives.
10
These non-infringing alternatives were animated and shown at the outset of the survey when the
11
different touchscreen choices were explained to the survey respondents. In his deposition,
12
Professor Wind admitted it was an “oversight” that his report did not acknowledge that the
13
noninfringing alternatives were presented in the animations.60 A copy of the touchscreen
14
animations that were included in the smartphone survey is attached to this declaration as Exhibit
15
F. Very similar animations were presented for the tablet survey, although using a tablet instead of
16
a smartphone. Thus, survey respondents were asked only to compare the relative value of the
17
patented features with noninfringing alternatives, not the value of the patented features with no
18
comparable feature at all.
19
46.
Although his declaration states to the contrary, Professor Wind acknowledged in
20
his deposition that my surveys did include these noninfringing alternatives and that they were
21
presented in animated form.61 While he now seeks to claim that a respondent may not have
22
understood the noninfringing alternative, this criticism rests on a fundamentally false premise. I
23
intentionally designed my surveys to present reasonable noninfringing alternatives, which were
24
chosen based on consultation with the technical experts in this case.
25
26
27
28
59
Wind Report ¶¶ 61–65, Erdem Report ¶¶ 59–62.
Exhibit C, at 80:7-81:8.
61
Exhibit C, at 76:14-77:2.
60
REPLY HAUSER DECL. ISO APPLE’S MOTION FOR PERMANENT INJUNCTION
CASE NO. 11-CV-01846-LHK (PSG)
pa-1560004
16
1
(5) Other criticisms by Samsung’s experts.
2
3
47.
Professor Erdem and Dr. Sukumar also assert that the patented features are
4
unlikely to be driving demand.62 Neither Professor Erdem nor Dr. Sukumar has provided any
5
sort of scientific analysis that would justify their conclusions. Professor Erdem admitted in her
6
deposition that she did not conduct any empirical research at all.63 She also testified that she
7
could not think of any patented feature that would drive smartphone demand.64 As Professor
8
Wind explained in his deposition, the decision to purchase any type of product is typically driven
9
by multiple factors, and it is rare that any one factor would be the sole determinant of demand.
10
“Q. But if the test for whether something were driving consumer
demand is whether that was the sole determinant of the reason to
purchase the product, that test could almost never be met in your
experience?
11
12
A. I would find it kind of strange to find a factor that is a sole
determinant. Perhaps with the exception I mentioned before of a
brand name, that a brand name represents a totality of images,
associations, perceptions of a consumer of the brand; and a
consumer may decide, you know, BMW is such a terrific
brand…;65
13
14
15
16
48.
Professor Erdem also asserts that consumers do not choose as they do in the
17
surveys I designed, but use heuristics.66 Accordingly, in the purchase of a smartphone or tablet,
18
consumers “do not separately evaluate each sub-feature.” Her assertions are problematic for a
19
number of reasons. First, Professor Erdem shows no actual evidence that smartphone or tablet
20
consumers use heuristics (and what sorts of heuristics) when making choices. Second, the use of
21
heuristics can be tested. Accordingly, it would have been entirely possible for Professor Erdem to
22
survey Samsung consumers to test whether they use heuristics. This, she has not done. Third,
23
unlike Professor Erdem, I actually tested for the presence of heuristic-based choices – in
24
25
26
27
28
62
Erdem Report ¶¶ 51–58, Sukumar Report ¶ 10.
Deposition of Tülin Erdem, November 7, 2012 (“Exhibit G”), at 22:4-10; 34:17-35:11;
76:3-8; 165:19-23.
64
Exhibit G, at 26:7-19.
63
65
66
Exhibit C, at 26:9-27:2; see also id. at 12:14-13:15.
Erdem Report ¶¶ 47–50.
REPLY HAUSER DECL. ISO APPLE’S MOTION FOR PERMANENT INJUNCTION
CASE NO. 11-CV-01846-LHK (PSG)
pa-1560004
17
1
2
particular, the lexicographic heuristic – and found that surveyed respondents did not exhibit such
3
behavior.67
4
5
I declare under penalty of perjury that the foregoing is true and correct and that this
Declaration was executed this 9th day of November 2012, at Cambridge, Massachusetts.
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
67
The lexicographic heuristic is one where, faced with varying levels of features A and B,
a consumer has an infinite preference for feature A. In other words, she would always choose
(even the smallest additional amount of) feature A regardless of the amount of feature B. See also
Exhibit D, at 244:16–245:12.
REPLY HAUSER DECL. ISO APPLE’S MOTION FOR PERMANENT INJUNCTION
CASE NO. 11-CV-01846-LHK (PSG)
pa-1560004
18
Disclaimer: Justia Dockets & Filings provides public litigation records from the federal appellate and district courts. These filings and docket sheets should not be considered findings of fact or liability, nor do they necessarily reflect the view of Justia.
Why Is My Information Online?